GLOBALISATION AND ITS LABOUR MARKET EFFECTS - WHAT DO WE KNOW AND WHAT SHOULD WE DO? by Tim Harcourt Research Officer ACTU Speech to: Globalisation, the Asian Crisis and the Future of Australian Industry - Jobs and Infrastructure Conference Tom Mann Theatre 136 Chalmers Street Surry Hills, Sydney 16 March, 1998 D No. 24/1998 Copies of this speech are available on request from the ACTU Library, LIN, 393 Swanston Street, Melbourne 3000 or on the ACTU Internet site: www.actu.asn.au. Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -1- CONTENTS 1. Introduction 1 2. 'Globalisation' and 'Globalphobia' 2 3. Globalisation and Labour Markets 9 4. Trade Union Strategies 15 5. Summary 17 References Attachments Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -i- 1. Introduction Thank you for the invitation to speak at this important conference. The Globalisation debate is something that the trade union movement should play an active part in and not just be on the fringes. We should also not accept that there is one form of 'globalisation' that dominates the world and that it is in some way, inevitable. The global economy is made up of both international and national economic institutions. The globalisation model that is preferred by international capital markets and promoted (naively) by neo-classical academic economists does not have to be the one accepted by the labour movement. It is important that we have a say in shaping the economic institutions of the global economy to ensure that there is a social and labour dimension. I want to do three things in my paper today: First, I will outline the globalisation phenomenon that is becoming the major public policy issue of the 1990s. Second, I will focus on the globalisation and labour market literature, to analyse what the research evidence says about the effects of globalisation on wages and employment. Third, I will highlight some of the strategies pursued by the labour movement in Australia and internationally in response to globalisation. 2. 'Globalisations' and 'Globalphobia' The phenomena of 'globalisation' or 'globalphobia' is the subject of furious public policy debate in the 1990s. Some of it relates to international financial market speculation (that has almost crippled financial institutions in the Asian region), some to the conduct of transnational companies and some to 'cultural globalisation' (eg alleged threats to national culture and language). This has led to some strange Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -1- political alliances forming into pro and anti-globalisation camps. For instance, the extreme Left, who oppose international capital and transnational company influence over sovereign governments, may find itself in alliance with the extreme Right (which opposes both 'foreign' capital and 'foreign' people) on many globalisation issues. The Multilateral Agreement on Investment (MAI) or the role of the WTO and APEC are examples of this. Similarly, some pro-globalisation advocates on the Right do not object to the influence of Geneva in the form of the WTO but they may object to the same Geneva influence in the form of the International Labour Organisation (ILO) over domestic labour laws. This has made for some strange political bedfellows in national political debates all over the world. The anti-globalisation mood in the 1990s (and the diverse groups attracted to it) has been well documented by Rodrik (1997). He sums up the causes of the globalisation in concise fashion when he notes: "The process that has come to be called "globalisation" is exposing a deep fault line between groups who have the skills and mobility to flourish in global markets and those who either don't have these advantages or perceive the expansion of unregulated markets as inimical to social stability and deeply held norms. The result is severe tension between market and social groups such as workers, pensioners, and environmentalists with governments stuck in the middle." [Rodrik (1997) p.2 ] I would agree with this except I would not describe the Australian Government as being 'stuck in the middle' particularly given the partisan role it has played in industrial relations (eg Rio Tinto, Waterfront). Rodrik notes three 'sources of tension' between the global markets and social strategy. Firstly, reduced barriers to trade and investment increase the opportunities for highly skilled groups (who can cross borders) but reduce the opportunities for the low and semi-skilled groups in the labour market (who cannot cross borders as easily). Secondly, globalisation can potentially conflict with domestic social preferences for goods and services. For instance, a country's preference for certain safety or health standards on goods may be no longer Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -2- enforceable under WTO processes which insists that goods be treated equally no matter what their national origin (or production process). Thirdly, globalisation has made it difficult for government to maintain social safety nets and provide social insurance. This has occurred even though (as Rodrik (1997) points out, p.4-6) the countries with the most open economies, spend the most on social insurance and provide the most social protection. The globalisation debate can involve a number of social and economic issues. For instance, environmental groups have been concerned about trade liberalisation undermining environmental standards and protections. It has been argued, for example that health standards on food have been jeopardised as importers have claimed that quarantine regulations are a 'disguised' form of protectionism. The latter issue has been quite prominent in the NAFTA debate for instance, where antiNAFTA campaigners have claimed that health standards have fallen because imported Mexican foods have not been subject to the same health regulations that are required in the USA and Canada. This is an example of where globalisation conflicts with domestic social 'norms' or values. However, it is the effect of globalisation on labour markets which is of most direct concern to trade unions. This may come in various guises. For example, the most common way is the opening up of national economies to traded goods and services. Whilst there has always been an element of openness in all industrialised economies (particularly in Australia) the increased volume in trade in recent decades as a result of the GATT and other trade reforms has heightened awareness of the impact of trade. Investment flows are also important, with international capital becoming more mobile and the labour market behaviour of transnationals is also a key influence. Many labour market problems are blamed on 'globalisation' for popular appeal, especially at election time. For instance, the US Republican Presidential candidate Patrick Buchanan, in 1996, was quick to blame globalisation and the United States' trade deficit with Japan for real wage Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -3- deterioration and job loss for American workers in manufacturing. However, the same candidate did not put forward such pro-worker views on minimum wage legislation, trade unions, collective bargaining and labour laws. Globalisation (and Japan in particular) were more convenient targets. Ross Perot spoke of "great sucking sounds" (ie Mexico sucking away American jobs) in terms of NAFTA, but he too, is not know for being a friend of labour. The candidates of the American Right also tend to complain of trade problems with Asian countries (eg Japan or China) or Latin American countries (eg Mexico) but never complain about, say, Canada, or England. Now, what does this mean for us in Australia? First of all its important that we don't get tied up with the 'fortress Australia' mentality. We can't isolate ourselves from the world. Believe me the North Korean or Albanian road to economic development is not a winner. Second, we must be careful because some economic nationalism and isolationism can be associated with anti-immigration (and often racist) sentiments. The Australian union movement has been built on immigration. Immigrants have always made up a large proportion of our ranks. Statistical Evidence from the ABS shows that immigrants (especially of non-English speaking background) are more likely to join a union than the Australian born. (see Australian Bureau of Statistics (1997)). In addition, much of the anti-immigration sentiment coincides with attacks on indigenous Australians too. The union movement should keep our distance from these groups and maintain our support for the anti-racist coalition in Australian society. However, this does not mean we need to support the free market orthodoxy on globalisation and international trade. The same orthodoxy, we must remember opposes labour market regulation too. In fact, we Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -4- should use the debate to promote our traditional labour market institutions as being more necessary in the face of globalisation. As Rodrik's study shows economies with comprehensive social protections - such as social safety nets and labour market regulation tend to be open economies and successful ones at that. Globalisation is a reason for more comprehensive labour market protection not less. [See charts from ILO World Labour Report 1997-98 in Attachment 1]. Furthermore, there is no logical reason why deregulation of financial markets and product markets should be accompanied by labour market deregulation. The labour market is fundamentally a different institutions because it involves human factors. As Nobel Laureate and Emeritus Professor of Economics from MIT, Robert M. Solow says: ".....the labour market is a social as much as an economic institution - and the interaction between human beings cannot be interpreted in the same way as the supply and demand for dead fish." [Solow (1990)] The view put by free market economists that labour market deregulation should follow globalisation is not based on empirical evidence nor is it founded on an understanding of history. The worst explanation of this misconception was provided by a neoclassical academic economist turned politician, Dr John Hewson. When giving the Alfred Deakin Lecture in Melbourne in 1992, in the midst of his effort to lose the unlosable election, Hewson said: "It is the historic destiny of the Liberal Party to send industrial arbitration and protective tariffs to join white Australia in history's dustbin." I am not convinced that there is a policy link that says "both started at this point in history, therefore both should go". For instance as women Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -5- got the vote at the same time as tariff protection and arbitration should that go as well? The union should also not have to accept there is only one model of the global economy. For example, we do not have to accept the terms of such treaties as the MAI being negotiated in the OECD. The MAI (as currently proposed) gives multinational companies the right to sue national governments (even if those governments take action in the national public interest). The MAI reverses the onus on exemptions in terms of the 'roll back' provisions too - making national government justify their own measures. The MAI is a bill of rights for international capital in a world that does not provide an enforceable workers' bill of rights. The union movement does not have to accept the MAI nor should it accept a WTO without provision for the inclusion of core labour standards. Now, if I can turn to the labour market literature. 3. Globalisation and the Labour Market The advance of the globalisation has lead to a vigorous debate in economics about the effect of trade liberalisation on labour markets. As the literature is vast, I want to concentrate today on the debate about the effects of trade liberalisation on wages and employment. The advocates of trade liberalisation and globalisation usually argue about the "efficiency gains", "gains from trade", "comparative advantage" and the elimination of "dead weight losses". However, there is little reference made to the income distribution consequences of policy advice based on the international trade models, nor is there much attention paid to the adjustment process in labour markets resulting from trade policy. Much of the theoretical debate has focussed on the effects of trade on developed country wages. Economic theory has offered several competing theories on this link. These include the 'Heckscher-Ohlin', 'Stolper-Samuelson', and '"Factor-price equalisation' models. The Heckscher-Ohlin model of international trade and the Stolper-Samuelson theorem on protection and real wages came to prominence in the 1940s Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -6- whilst the "factor price" equalisation model has been revived in recent debates, particularly in the arguments between Adrian Wood and others on the impact of international trade on the wages of 'first-world' unskilled workers. The debate is basically about whether trade is a 'large' or 'small' factor in the decline of the wages of the unskilled relative to the skilled in 'firstworld' economies. A summary of the studies is provided in the attachment [Attachment 2]. This debate between 'large effects' and 'small effects' has been extended to other issues. For instance, Richard Freeman is sceptical about trade being the main culprit in the plight of unskilled workers. Freeman (1995) sees other forces at play such as technological advances or political events (such as the reunification of Germany and its effect on German labour markets). Whilst noting Woods' distinction between past and future trade liberalisation, and modestly noting that "Economists do not have a good record as soothsayers", Freeman is not convinced that future liberalisation will hurt unskilled workers in developed countries. He notes that domestic labour market conditions play an important role. For instance, nurses, teachers, retail workers and other in service industries all have their pay determined by domestic (not global) conditions. Accordingly, Freeman is sceptical that trade agreements (such as NAFTA, or the EU arrangements) will have a large effect on wages and employment as he notes: "Wildly heralded trade agreements such as the US-Canadian Agreement, the Common Market, and NAFTA have not dominated our wages and employment in the way their advocates or opponents forecast." [Freeman (1995), pp.31-32] From a non free market neo-classical perspective, Ajit Singh points out the flaws in the Wood analysis in setting up a "North-South" division between the developed and developing world. Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -7- Singh (1997) believes in a pro-growth strategy in the industrialised world to assist developing world trade. He rejects the post-1980 labour market flexibility doctrine as the policy solution to the labour market problems of both the developed and developing economies which he argues is implicit in the economic models of both sides of the trade and wages debate. This is also the argument of James K. Galbraith (1996) who disagree with conventional economists attempts to cause division between the "north and south" of the global economy. Notably, all the neo-classical economists do not advocate trade protection, even if they do believe that trade hurts unskilled workers. Wood, for instance supports employment subsidies to assist unskilled workers in the industrialised world rather than trade tariffs or subsidies. Belman and Lee of the Economic Policy Institute (EPI) in Washington DC, in their survey, have concentrated on the trade effects on employment. In terms of US manufacturing employment, Belman and Lee noted three effects: First, the major impact on US manufacturing employment rather than wages in the last two decades. Second, the greater impact that trade had in the 1970s and 1980s (and presumably the 1990s). Third, the important role of intersectoral labour mobility, where workers may lose jobs in manufacturing but be employed in the service sector (typically at lower wages). The authors also note the spillover effects of the "loss of wage leadership"' from the manufacturing sector which may also be a source of poor wage performance throughout the US economy. This, however does not consider other reasons for real wage deterioration - such as the erosion of US labour market institutions. Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -8- This is where the difference between US and Australian labour market institutions is important. Our stronger unions and stronger wage fixing institutions are especially important in the face of large changes in trade volumes. Much of the literature focus just on trade flows, however, the OECD (1997) has surveyed the trade and 'other' effects including the role of technology in the globalisation process. The OECD notes several globalisation effects. 1. The substitution of labour for capital and technology in industrialised countries (which helps skilled workers but not the unskilled). 2. The effect of 'outsourcing' to low wage countries. 3. Re-location of firms from high wage to low wage countries. This approach by the OECD, takes into account the broader effects of the globalisation, not just the effect of trade prices on labour markets. The OECD survey finds it difficult to distinguish between the effects of trade from technology on the labour market but still notes that the majority of the studies surveyed conclude that ".....trade has played a small role in labour market outcomes, especially shifts in relative employment and wages for unskilled labour in OECD countries." [OECD (1997) p.113]. Notably, one study mentioned by the OECD [Machin, Ryan, and VanReenan] noted the importance of labour market institutions in lessening the impact of trade on workers. The study notes: "No impact of industry import and export intensities is found, but labour market institutions seem to play an important role: in the UK and the US, industries with higher unionisation levels experienced less downgrading of the relative wages and employment of unskilled workers." [OECD (1997), p.116] Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -9- This shows why workers gain from being a union member, especially in the face of increased trade liberalisation. In conclusion, we can only say that the evidence on trade and labour markets is mixed. A major problem is that the globalisation advocates have been narrow in their focus and have asserted that trade liberalisation will ultimately benefit workers and the community but have rarely shown how. On the OECD's own admission, distributional issues have not been at the forefront of the analysis. Of those who do admit that there are winners and losers from trade liberalisation most are not sure how to 'compensate' the losers. Furthermore, some globalisation advocates, in domestic economic debates, are attacking the very social protections that are designed to assist the losers (eg the Industry Commission). This has caused a crisis for the trade liberalisation advocates who are trying desperately to re-package their public relations message (eg see DFAT's "Trade Liberalisation: Opportunities for Australia" leaflet). Alternatively, those opposing globalisation have not always identified whether it is globalisation or other phenomena that are causing workers and the community harm. Furthermore, many globalisation sceptics are unable to show why the "closed economy" counterfactual would have been more beneficial. 4 Trade Union Strategies No matter what the effects of globalisation on workers it is important that the trade union movement put in a number of strategies at both international and local level. These include: 1. The provision of labour standards in international trade agreements and fora (eg the 'social clause' in the WTO, and similar provisions in APEC, regional trade agreements, and the MAI). 2. Advocacy of workers-rights and labour standards in World Bank and IMF programs. Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -10- 3. Codes of Conduct for multinational companies on labour standards (eg Reebok, Levi Strauss, FIFA). 4. International labour co-operation. For example: - International union action against mining giant Rio Tinto, led by former Australian Prime Minister Bob Hawke (the union group met in Johannesburg in February 1998 at a meeting hosted by South African President Nelson Mandela). 5. Industrial campaigns on globalisation issues. For example: the very successful 'fair wear campaign' by the TCFUA on outwork. It has been argued that the tariff reductions in the TCF industry has forced local companies to use outworkers. The 'fair wear campaign' has seen a number of retailers agree to sign the TCFUA's code of conduct on outwork. Campaigns that highlight the social, economic and regional consequences of poor trade policy can be effective. 6. Recruitment campaigns on globalisation (why unions are needed now more than ever). 7. Continued involvement in trade and industry policy and labour market and training programs. Not all strategies on globalisation are confined to "trade" and "international" issues. For example, education and training reform of the 1980s and award restructuring have done much to lessen the impact on low skilled workers of globalisation in Australia. This high-skill, highwage, high-productivity approach contrasts favourably with the "concession bargaining" approach of US unions in the late 1970s and early 1980s. Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -11- 5 Summary In this paper, I have attempted to outline the current debate on the effects of 'globalisation' on the labour market and the positive trade union strategies to deal with those effects. The survey of the evidence shows that the advocates of trade liberalisation have not been able to convince opinion makers that benefits will automatically flow to workers and the community from trade liberalisation. Some have ignored distributional effects, some have argued that we all will be winners, whilst other have argued that there will be "winners" and "losers" but the "losers" will be compensated. There is plenty of evidence out there that gives reason for us to be sceptical about their claims. However, similar suspicion should also apply to those who advocate isolationism (which is simply not an option). The appropriate response I believe consists of the following elements: 1. We should not accept or reject globalisation outright but make our presence felt in how it should be shaped and formed. After all, Bretton Woods in the 1940s and the Asia Crisis now shows that international institutions do matter and are there for the influencing. Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -12- 2. We should not underestimate the role of Australian's labour market and social institutions in partly absorbing the effects of globalisation. 3. We should take a hard-headed view of the analysis of globalisation and labour markets and always put the onus on the globalisation advocates to show evidence of its benefits in terms of living standards. 4. We should not underestimate traditional trade union industrial campaigns. The Australian union campaigns on globalisation can be effective as evidenced by the recent TCFUA Fairwear Campaign and similar efforts by the AMWU in the car industry. Globalisation can be an effective recruiting tool especially if there is a perception that globalisation gives increased bargaining power to employers. Evidence from the OECD (as cited) showed that a trade union presence in a workplace has a positive effect on wages and employment, even in the face of trade liberalisation. In summary, globalisation is not a trend or fashion, but is part of the bargaining challenge that trade unions face in advancing our members' interests. It should not be treated as the end of the world, but as another opportunity in terms of union recruitment and organising. Afterall, we've got nothing to lose...but a world to win. References ACTU (1994) Trade in the Asia Pacific Region: An ACTU Guide ACTU (1995) APEC - What Should Unions Do? Melbourne. ACTU (1997) Trade Unions and APEC, Melbourne. ACTU (1997) Australia in Relation to APEC: Senate Inquiry into APEC, Melbourne. ACTU Submission to Australian Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -13- ACTU (1998) Living Wage 1997/98 ACTU Written Submission, Melbourne AFL-CIO (1997) NAFTA Expansion: Off the fast track, on the right track, AFL-CIO Public Policy Department, Washington DC. Australian Bureau of Statistics (1997) Trade Union Members, ABS Cat. No. 6325.0 (various). Belman, D and Lee, T (1997) "International Trade and the Performance of US Labor Markets" in Blecker, R (ed.) US Trade Policy and Global Growth - New Directions in the International Economy, Economic Policy Institute, ME Sharpe, New York. Bhagwati J. and Kosters M. (1994) Trade and Wages: Levelling Wages Down?, Washington DC, AEI Press. Bronfenbrenner, K (1997) "The Effects of Plant Closing or Threat of Plant Closing on the Right Of Workers to Organise" Submitted to the Labor Secretariat of the North American Commission For Labor Co-operation, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York. Burtless G (1995), "International Trade and the Rise in Earnings Equality", Journal of Economic Literature, Vol XXXIII, June, pp.800-816. Canadian Labour Congress (CLC) (1996) The Social Dimensions of North American Economic Integration. CLC Ottawa, Canada. Commonwealth of Australia (1995) Report of Labour Standards in the Asia Pacific Region, Report of the Tripartite Working Party on Labour Standards. (Also referred to as 'The Duffy Report'). Commonwealth of Australia (1997) Trade Liberalisation: Australia, Canberra. Opportunities for Deery,S and Mitchell (1993) Labour Law & Industrial Relations in Asia Longman Cheshire, Melbourne. Fahrer,J and Pease,A (1994) "International Trade and the Australian Labour Market" in International Integration of the Australian Economy Reserve Bank of Australia Conference proceedings, Sydney. Freeman, R (1995) "Are Your Wages Set in Beijing?" Journal of Economic Perspectives Vol 9, No 3, Summer. Frenkel, S (ed.) (1993) Organised Labor in the Asia-Pacific Region ILR Press, Ithaca, New York. Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -14- Galbraith, James K. (1996) "Uneven Development and the Destabilisation of the North : a Keynesian view." International Review of Applied Economics, Vol 10. No.1. Harcourt T. (1997) Labour Issues in APEC, A Paper for the Australian APEC Study Centre, Melbourne. ICFTU-APRO (1997) International Trade, Investment and Competitiveness: Trade Union Strategies in a Globalising Economy, ICFTU-APRO Singapore. Martin, H-P. and Schumann, H (1997) The Global trap: Globalisation and the Assault on Democracy and Prosperity. Zed Books, UK Mishel, Lawrence and Voos (1992) (ed) Unions and Economic Competitiveness, M.E. Sharpe, New York. Public Services International (1997) "International Trade Agreements and Trade Unions: Briefing Notes", PSI, France. OECD (1995) Trade and Labour Standards: Paris. A Review of the Issues, OECD, OECD (1997) Employment Outlook - July 1997, OECD, Paris. Lawrence, Robert Z. (1994) "Trade, Multinationals and Labour." in International Integration of the Australian Economy Reserve Bank of Australia Conference proceedings, Sydney. Rodrik, Dani (1997) Has Globalisation Gone Too Far ? Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C. Sengberger W. and Wilkinson F (1995) "Globalisation and Labour Standards" in Michie J, and Grieve Smith J., Managing the Global Economy, Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK. Solow, R (1990) The Labor Market as a Social Institution, Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Singh, Ajit (1997)" Expanding employment in the global economy: the high road or the low road? in Markets ,Unemployment and Economic Policy, Routledge, London. Wood,A (1995) "How Trade Hurt Unskilled Workers"Journal of Economic Perspectives Vol 9, No 3, Summer. World Bank (1995) Workers in an Integrating World - World Development Report 1995. Oxford UP, World Bank, Washington D.C. Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -15- Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -16- ATTACHMENT 1 Charts from ILO World Labour Report 1997-98 Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -17- Study A. Wood (1994) and (1995) Issues Factor content analysis - measures impact of trade with 'south' on the wages of unskilled workers in the 'north'. R. Freeman (1995) Tests whether "Your wages are set in Beijing" by reviewng conceptual linkages between trade and the labour market. A. Singh (1997) Tests the Wood analysis in terms of economic strategies for both 'North and South' (industrialised and developing world). James K. Galbraith (1996) Tests Keynesian theory on question of North-South trade in manufacturing, industrial location from North to South, rising wage inequality and unemployment in the North. Tests the impact of trade and structured change on workers' wages bill and employment share. Machin, Ryan and Van Reenan (1996) cited in OECD (1997) Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -18- Results Finds the impact of trade to be 10 times the magnitude of previous 'small effects' studies. Makes the assumption that all manufactures' imports are non-competing (other than processed primary products) and that productivity in the 'south' is the same as in the 'north'. Believes that the impact of trade on wage inequality is exaggerated. Argues that much of the labour market has wages not according to domestic conditions. Regards other factors technology and political events as more important than trade flows. Rejects 'North-south' division inherent in Wood analysis. Questions Wood's assumptions and argues that any study that assumes a neoclassical labour market in North and South economies is deficient. Argues that a pro-growth strategy for the 'North' is ultimately beneficial for the 'South'. Argues that Keynesian theory best captures the dynamics of the North-South relationship and especially the influence of Northern macroeconomic policy and North business cycles on industrial trading patterns. Found in the UK and USA that industries with higher unionisation levels experienced less downgrading of the relative wages and employment of unskilled workers. Belman and Lee (1997) Surveys empirical tests of the effect of trade on manufacturing employment in the US. Globalisation, the Asian Crisis & the Future of Australia Conference - 16 March, 1998 I:\DOCS\SPEECH\JHTHMARB.SPE -19- Four main conclusions are drawn: 1. Employment effects greater than wage effects. 2. Negative consequences of imports for wages increased in 1970s and 1980s. 3. The large employment effects of trade suggest considerable job mobility (often from manufacturing to the service sector). 4. Loss of wage leadership in manufacturing has affected wage bargaining throughout the economy.