CHAPTER 5 THEORIES ON THE OUTCOME OF ECONOMIC SANCTIONS Some people think of economic leverage as the punitive use of economic sanctions, with highly publicized conditions set for their removal. This is highly ineffective, and sometimes counterproductive. - Richard Nixon, U.S. President, 19821 Since the estimated cost of economic sanctions to Iraq – 48 percent of the gross national product – is so far beyond that observed in other cases, the initial results [of our model of economic sanctions] placed the probability of success [of economic sanctions against Iraq] at nearly 100 percent. - Economists Gary Hufbauer and Kimberly Elliott January 14, 1991, two days before the Gulf war started2 The conventional theory of how sanctions are supposed to work assumes that political change is directly proportional to economic hardship. The greater the economic pain caused by sanctions, the higher the probability of political compliance. The theory assumes that the population in the target state will redirect the pain of sanctions onto political leaders and force a change in policy. This theory has been criticized by many theorists, who argue that economic factors do not explain the success or failure of economic sanctions but that domestic and international political 1 2 M. S. Daoudi and M. S. Dajani, Economic Sanctions: Ideals and Experience (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983), p. 187. Gary C. Hufbauer and Kimberly A. Elliott, “Sanctions Will Bite – and Soon,” New York Times, January 14, 1991, A 17. 160 factors are key to deciding outcomes. Johan Galtung has termed this the “naïve theory” of sanctions. The economic effects of sanctions do not necessarily translate into political impact because there is no direct transmission mechanism.3 Baghdad’s continued resistance in face of the U.S.-led economic sanctions provides an especially dramatic contradiction to the conventional expectation. Iraq has suffered tremendously under the West’s sanctions during the 1990s, but Saddam Hussein remains in charge and has not shelved plans to develop weapons of mass destruction. Iraq has been imposed sanctions by the United Nations (UN) since August 6, 1990. As of late 1999, infant mortality rates had increased sevenfold, annual inflation had risen to over 4000 percent, and per capita income had fallen to less than half of the 1990 level. In the face of continued economic losses and bellicose U.S. rhetoric, the Iraqi regime has only acquiesced to UN demands when additional military threats have been made. In every issue area, when the only pressure is economic sanctions, Iraq has not conceded. Domestically, Hussein’s regime shows no signs of falling; if anything, the sanctions have strengthened it. Despite the most potent sanctions ever in human history, economic sanctions have failed to produce any significant Iraqi concessions.4 To test whether increased punishment against the target makes the target more likely to concede, Robert Pape stratifies the HSE database, excluding trade disputes, economic warfare, and double-counting, into high and low economic impact categories, setting the dividing line at a 4.6 percent reduction in the target’s GNP. If each overdetermined and indeterminate case challenged by Pape in the original HSE database is counted as a full success, then the success ratio in the high category is 2 to 3 4 David Cortright and George A. Lopez, “Sanctions and Incentives as Tools of Economic Statecraft,” in Raimo Vayrynen (ed.), Globalization and Global Governance (Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc., 1999), pp. 111-116. Chantal de Jonge Oudraat, “Making Economic Sanctions Work,” Survival, vol. 42, no. 3 (Autumn 2000), pp. 106-111. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and 161 8 cases, or 25 percent; in the low category, it is 5 to 77 cases, or 6 percent. This appears to provide at least some support for the proposition that sanctions success is correlated with economic loss. However, the only two arguable successes in the high category are the two lowest in economic punishment. If the boundary line between the low and high categories were moved only from 4.6 to 5.2 percent, the high category would contain no successes at all. Furthermore, ordinary least squares regression confirms that there is no statistically significant relationship between the target’s GNP loss and sanctions success.5 Therefore, economic sanctions do not necessarily succeed by imposing more economic pain upon the target. Economic asymmetries do not tell us anything about the target’s relative valuation of the political concessions being sought or the net worth of the sender-target economic relationship. A dominant or inferior position of the target in the bilateral economic relationship can be subject to the countervailing influences of differential discount rates of economic benefits and the costs of political concessions. To understand the target’s calculation, economics alone is not enough. The following are four comprehensive approaches to account for the outcome of economic sanctions. 5 International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 1-2. Of HSE’s entire database of 115 cases, 30 inappropriately included 10 cases of economic disruption in war; 15 cases of trade disputes or strategic embargoes; and 5 cases counted twice. This leaves a total of 85 valid cases, including 5 successes, or an overall success rate of 6 percent (9 percent if we include the overdetermined and indeterminate cases) versus the 34 percent HSE report. Robert A. Pape, “Why Economic Sanctions Do Not Work,” International Security, vol. 22, no. 2 (Fall 1997), pp. 107-109. 162 I. The Hufbauer-Schott-Elliot Approach The first approach is called the Gary Hufbauer, Jeffery Schott, and Kimberly Elliot (HSE) approach. HSE has been collecting the most comprehensive database of economic sanctions cases and the database is used broadly by many theorists. The HSE approach is induced from economic sanctions cases studies. According to Gary Hufbauer, Jeffery Schott, Kimberly Elliot, George Lopez, David Cortright, Joseph Collins, and Gabrielle Bowdoin, a survey of the analytical and historical literature on sanctions suggests that sanctions – and the threat of sanctions – are most effective under the following conditions: I. The goal of economic sanctions is relatively modest. Sanctions are seldom effective in bringing about major changes in the policies of the target country; II. The target is economically weak and political unstable. Although the average sender’s economy was 187 times larger than that of the average target in the HSE database, the relative size between the sender’s and target’s economy is not very helpful in predicting success in the majority of cases; III. The target suffers high costs from sanctions while the sender endures low, sustainable costs. The costs of sanctions to the target exceeds 2 percent of its GNP while the sender suffers minimal costs; IV. The sender and target are friendly toward one another. Economic sanctions seem most effective when aimed against erstwhile friends. By contrast, sanctions directed against target countries that have long been adversaries of the sender country are generally less successful; V. There exists a high total trade concentration for the target with the sender. It is generally greater than 25 percent of target’s total trade; VI. Economic sanctions are imposed quickly, with maximum harshness and without 163 significant international assistance of the target’s trading partners who otherwise might circumvent such restrictions. Time affords the target the opportunity to adjust -- to find alternative suppliers, to build new alliances, and to mobilize domestic opinion in support of its policies. VII. In most instances, multilateral sanctions are not associated with success. On average, the degree of international cooperation is actually somewhat less in successful cases than in failed cases. That is, unilateral sanctions will be more effective than multilateral sanctions, which will entail significant coordination costs for the sender; and VIII. The sanctions, when possible, are financial sanctions, not trade sanctions. The financial sanctions are less costly (even beneficial) to the sender and more effective than trade control.6 II. The Domestic Politics/Symbolic Approach The domestic politics/symbolic approach focuses on the politics within the sender and target countries. Outcomes are largely determined by the domestic political economy of the target country. Domestic politics/symbolic explanations provide three factors working against the effectiveness of economic sanctions: (1) few cases with damaging sanctions; (2) the rally-around-the-flag effect reinforced by nationalism; and (3) manipulated redistribution effects of sanctions. By contrast, this approach provides two factors contributing to the effectiveness of sanctions: (1) the 6 Reference includes Gary Clyde Hufbauer, Jeffery J. Schott, and Kimberly Ann Elliot, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, 2nd ed. (Washington, D.C.: Institute of International Economics, 1990), pp. 49-115; George A. Lopez and David Cortright, “Economic Sanctions in Contemporary Global Relations,” and Kimberly Ann Elliot, “Factors Affecting the Success of Sanctions,” in David Cortright and George A. Lopez (eds.), Economic Sanctions: Panacea or Peacebuilding in a Post-Cold War World? (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 1995), pp. 9, 53; Joseph J. Collins and Gabrielle D. Bowdoin, Beyond Unilateral Economic Sanctions (Washington, DC: Center for Strategic and International Studies, 1999), pp. 15-6. 164 fifth-column effect; and (2) political instability of the target. First, public choice analysis suggests that damaging sanctions will be infrequently used. Sanctions are often imposed half-heartedly by the sender government, out of a need to satiate domestic political pressure of the public and interest groups to do something in response to the target’s disputed behavior. Hence, sanctions are symbols; their effectiveness is of secondary concern. In addition, the sanctions costs will hurt some interest groups and even the public at large, who will oppose severe sanctions measures. Thus, it is not surprising that the sanctions actually adopted often appear ineffectual and the target country may face insufficient coercive pressure to consider acquiescing.7 Second, even if the sanctions are potent, target governments can use the specter of economic sanctions to create a rally-around-the-flag effect. Johan Galtung used the term “rally-around-the-flag” effect to argue that leaders in target nations could use the economic pain caused by foreign nations to rally their population in opposition to “foreign meddling.” Sanctions may give the target leaders a pretext to demonstrate their ability to share the plight of the people. In such cases, rather than creating disintegration in the target state, sanctions would invoke political integration within the target state and solidify the leader’s resistance to economic pressure.8 7 8 William H. Kaempfer and Anton D. Lowenberg, “A Public Choice Analysis of the Political Economy of International Sanctions,” in Steve Chan and A. Cooper Drury (eds.), Sanctions as Economic Statecraft: Theory and Practice (New York: St. Martin’s, 2000), pp. 159-161. Johan Galtung, “On the Effects of International Economic Sanctions,” World Politics, vol. 19 (October 1966- July 1967), pp. 388-399. See also Miroslav Nincic and Peter Wallensteen, “Economic Coercion and Foreign Policy,” in Miroslav Nincic and Peter Wallensteen (eds.), Dilemmas of Economic Coercion: Sanctions in World Politics (New York: Praeger, 1983), p. 6; Makio Miyagawa, Do Economic Sanctions Work? (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1992), pp. 84-6; David M. Rowe, The Domestic Political Economy of International Economic Sanctions, working paper no. 93-1, (Cambridge, MA: The Center for International Affairs, Harvard University, 1993), p. 30; David Cortright and George A. Lopez, “Sanctions and Incentives as Tools of Economic Statecraft,” in Raimo Vayrynen (ed.), Globalization and Global Governance (Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc., 1999), pp. 114-5; Kaplowitz, Anatomy of a Failed Embargo, pp. 52-54; Zachary Selden, Economic Sanctions as Instruments of American Foreign Policy (Westport, Connecticut: Praeger, 1999), p. 22. George E. Shambaugh, States, Firms, and Power: Successful Sanctions in United States Foreign Policy (Albany, New York: State University of New York Press, 1999), p. 12. 165 Zachary Selden further explains that the “rally-around-the-flag” effect is based on the idea that sanctions provide a common external enemy to unite the population of the target country and increase the popularity of the current leadership. Nothing brings together diverse social elements as quickly as the perception that they have been set upon by a common enemy, and sanctions can provide this common object of opprobrium. The experience of states at war is analogous. No matter what disagreement exists in the society as a whole, war against a common enemy provides a focal point to rally the population and direct their attention away from domestic issues.9 In addition, Klaus Knorr, Joseph Nye, Ernest Preeg, Robert Pape, David Cortright, George Lopez, and Makio Miyagawa all point out that modern states are not fragile because of rising nationalism. The political leader of the target state can excite the nationalistic sentiment of the entire population by stigmatizing the sanctions as a humiliating affront to the nation, and thereby promote national unity in the face of outside pressure. Nationalism provoked by economic sanctions tends to foster political integration.10 Particularly, economic sanctions that do not discriminate between the “guilty” and “innocent” in the target may actually encourage the formation of a unified front in the target. In other words, sanctions, in practice, are an application of the principle of collective guilt, or at least collective punishment. Sanctions may be invoked to punish 9 Zachary Selden, Economic Sanctions as Instruments of American Foreign Policy (Westport, Connecticut: Praeger, 1999), pp. 4-5, 20-23. 10 Klaus Knorr, The Power of Nations: The Political Economy of International Relations (New York: Basic Books, 1975), pp. 111-2. Ernest H. Preeg, Feeling Good or Doing Good with Sanctions: Unilateral Economic Sanctions and the U.S. National Interest (Washington, D.C.: Center for Strategic and International Studies, 1999), p. 9. Robert A. Pape, Bombing to Win: Air Power and Coercion in War (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1996), pp. 21-27. David Cortright and George A. Lopez, The Sanctions Decade: Assessing UN Strategies in the 1990s (Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner, 2000), p. 20. Makio Miyagawa, Do Economic Sanctions Work? (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1992), pp. 84-86. See also Lewis A. Coser, The Functions of Social Conflict (New York: The Free Press of Glencoe, 1964), pp. 87-95. 166 a government for a particular policy choice, but sanctions will have more of a negative impact on the innocent. Economic sanctions tend to seriously affect those who are not responsible for making the policy – the public and business groups – while those elites that are responsible – decisionmakers and their associates – remain largely unaffected given their ability to skirt the sanctions, particularly in authoritarian countries. This indiscriminant impact will significantly reduce the effectiveness of economic sanctions.11 Robert Pape argues, “Pervasive nationalism often makes states and societies willing to endure considerable punishment rather than abandon what are seen as the interests of the nation, make even weak or disorganized states unwilling to bend to the demands of foreigners….Even in the weakest and most fractured states, external pressure is more likely to enhance the nationalist legitimacy of rulers than to undermine it.”12 For example, in the past, strategic bombing by Western countries badly damaged the economies of North Korea, North Vietnam, and Iraq without causing their populations to rise up against their own regimes. In addition, Joseph Nye asserts that Western countries did not go in and colonize the countries of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries during the 1973 oil crisis only because they realized the costliness of using force against nationalistically awakened people in the oil producing states.13 This in part happened with respect to Iraq in 1991. Furthermore, both Daniel Drezner and Margaret Doxey contend that the target 11 12 13 Robin Renwick, Economic Sanctions (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Center for International Affairs, Harvard University, 1981), pp. 88-89. Richard N. Haass, “Conclusion: Lessons and Recommendations,” in Richard N. Haass (ed.), Economic Sanctions and American Diplomacy (New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1998), pp. 201-203. Ernest H. Preeg, Feeling Good or Doing Good with Sanctions: Unilateral Economic Sanctions and the U.S. National Interest (Washington, D.C.: Center for Strategic and International Studies, 1999), pp. 194-195. Robert A. Pape, “Why Economic Sanctions Do Not Work,” International Security, vol. 22, no. 2 (Fall 1997), pp. 93, 107. Joseph S. Nye, Jr., Understanding International Conflicts: An Introduction to Theory and History (New York: Longman, 2000), p. 190. 167 governments will present themselves as defenders of the countries and their interests from enemies. Leaders in the target governments will always use external threats as a means of building up domestic support for the governing regime. By contrast, opposition groups will risk being dubbed unpatriotic or disloyal if they do not rally around the flag.14 For example, in Cuba, western economic sanctions were depicted as an attack by a rich imperialist regime, not against Fidel Castro, but against the entire nation and its aspirations. This gave Castro a scapegoat to divert attention from internal problems and the errors of his regime. In Rhodesia, the enforcement of sanctions created internal cohesion, particularly among the European minority. Resistance became synonymous with patriotism, while dissent became treason. The sanctions reduced the influence of racial moderates and those most loyal to the Crown in the white population and encouraged consolidation of opinion against the externally imposed economic sanctions. Pakistan has been facing different forms of U.S. sanctions for the last 25 years. However, the result is that the people of Pakistan are gradually turning the United States into their enemy.15 Third, target governments may prefer to be sanctioned because they can distribute economic rent of the trade restriction to their supporters and weaken their domestic opponents – it often is the “liberals” and “reformers” in authoritarian societies who are most vulnerable to external sanctions. While in the long run sanctions hurt the trade-oriented sectors of the target economy by depriving them of 14 15 Margaret P. Doxey, International Sanctions in Contemporary Perspective, 2nd ed. (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1996), p. 104. Daniel W. Drezner, “The Complex Causation of Sanction Outcomes,” in Steve Chan and A. Cooper Drury (eds.), Sanctions as Economic Statecraft: Theory and Practice (New York: St. Martin’s, 2000), p. 214. Makio Miyagawa, Do Economic Sanctions Work? (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1992), pp. 84-86. Donald L. Losman, International Economic Sanctions: The Cases of Cuba, Israel, and Rhodesia (Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, 1979), pp. 127-131. “New American Sanctions Against Pakistan,” Rawalpindi Nawa-I-Waqt (in Urdu), November 23, 2000, trans. FBIS-CHI-2000-1124. 168 income, in the short run a sender’s embargo strengthens the target’s import-substitution sectors by giving them rent-seeking opportunities in the target. In addition, the target government may redirect external pressure onto isolated or repressed social groups while insulating and protecting itself. As a result, sanctions may end up strengthening the target government, and hence its ability to resist the coercive attempts of the sender government.16 For example, when the coalition led by the United Kingdom imposed sanctions against white Rhodesia, household incomes for black families fell and white income rose. Despite extremely desperate circumstances, the military government of Haiti did not feel compelled to accede to the demands of the international community and return control of the country to its democratically elected leadership because some of the Haitian elites benefited from the black market trading that was created by sanctions. Despite being sanctioned by one of the world’s toughest embargoes led by the United States since 1990, Saddam Hussein actually rewarded those associated with the Iraqi government, the military, or the ruling Baath party, with luxury cars and other goods. In the case of the UN sanctions against Yugoslavia, Serbian leader Slobodan Milosevic similarly used the UN embargo to reward crony enterprises with scarce goods and used the UN aid to reward his inner elite, while punishing his political rivals. Therefore, leaders in these countries have an incentive to see these sanctions remain in place.17 16 17 Robert A. Pape, “Why Economic Sanctions Do Not Work,” International Security, vol. 22, no. 2 (Fall 1997), p. 107. Paul D. Taylor, “Clausewitz on Economic Sanctions: The Case of Iraq,” Strategic Review, vol. 23, no. 3 (Summer 1995), pp. 50-56. David M. Rowe, The Domestic Political Economy of International Economic Sanctions, working paper no. 93-1, (Cambridge, MA: The Center for International Affairs, Harvard University, 1993), p. 31. Zachary Selden, Economic Sanctions as Instruments of American Foreign Policy (Westport, Connecticut: Praeger, 1999), pp. 4-5, 102-103. Gideon Rose, “Haiti,” in Richard N. Haass (ed.), Economic Sanctions and American Diplomacy (New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1998), pp. 67-68. Daniel W. Drezner, “The Complex Causation of Sanction Outcomes,” in Steve Chan and A. Cooper Drury (eds.), Sanctions as Economic Statecraft: Theory and Practice (New York: St. Martin’s, 2000), p. 215. Howard Schneider, “10 Years On, Iraqis Shrug Off Embargo,” Washington Post, February 24, 2001, p. A1. 169 However, under certain circumstance, economic sanctions can be effective. According to the public choice perspective, sanctions will be effective if they are designed to hurt specific groups (the ruling coalition or the “guilty”) selectively within the target polity. David Cortright and George Lopez argue that economic sanctions may empower internal political forces and render their opposition more effective to a regime’s objectionable policies, thus generating an ‘internal opposition effect’. In other words, targeted sanctions work, over time, by reducing the influence of the proponents of a given policy. Zachary Selden calls this effect the “fifth-column” effect.18 Jonathan Kirshner argues further that by disaggregating the target, the emphasis needs to shift from “how much does a state suffer” to “who suffers.” The more the sanction hurts the target central government directly, the greater the chance is that it will influence its policy. Beyond this, the success of sanctions depends on whether or not core support groups are affected and therefore put pressure on the target government. Further, and most subtly, Kirshner argues that sanctions can have differential effects within the central government and across core groups themselves, shifting the balance of political power within the government and altering its preferences.19 Therefore, Jonathan Kirshner suggests the central questions governing the outcome of economic sanctions are: (1) under what circumstances will the sanction 18 19 Kaempfer and Lowenberg, “The Problems and Promise of Sanctions,” pp. 65-9. Kaempfer and Lowenberg, International Economic Sanctions, p. 8. William H. Kaempfer and Anton D. Lowenberg, “A Public Choice Analysis of the Political Economy of International Sanctions,” in Steve Chan and A. Cooper Drury (eds.), Sanctions as Economic Statecraft: Theory and Practice (New York: St. Martin’s, 2000), pp. 164, 186. See also Jonathan Kirshner, “The Microfoundations of Economic Sanctions,” Security Studies, vol. 6, no. 3 (Spring 1997), pp. 32-64. A. Cooper Drury, “Revisiting Economic Sanctions Reconsidered,” Journal of Peace Research, vol. 35, no. 4 (1998), p. 499. David Cortright and George A. Lopez, The Sanctions Decade: Assessing UN Strategies in the 1990s (Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner, 2000), pp. 20-22. Zachary Selden, Economic Sanctions as Instruments of American Foreign Policy (Westport, Connecticut: Praeger, 1999), pp. 20-23. Jonathan Kirshner, “The Microfoundations of Economic Sanctions,” Security Studies, vol. 6, no. 3 (Spring 1997), pp. 41-50. 170 affect the target government (or elements within the ruling coalition) directly?; and (2) which private groups are likely to be affected by a given sanction? The effectiveness of sanctions will depend on how sanctions assist or hinder the work of opposition groups in the targeted country.20 For instance, in the case of the U.S. extending China’s MFN status in the 1990s, both James Lilley and David Lampton argue that a denial of MFN status would actually work against the U.S. goals by reducing the bargaining power of the more liberal leaders and reinforcing that of the more conservative elements in China. Should MFN status have been denied China, those groups and sectors in coastal provinces and urban areas that are more dependent on foreign trade would have been the most direct and immediate casualties. But these areas represent the most cosmopolitan segments of the Chinese elite, who have been the strongest advocates of economic and political reforms. Further, a denial of MFN status would have entailed a return to more central control and bureaucratic discretion, which would have worked to the advantage of the interior regions of China, the large state-owned enterprises, and political and economic cadres in charge of ideological indoctrination and industrial planning. Therefore, Lilley and Lampton argue, the U.S. sanctions would actually have weaken the position of the Chinese reformers, who advocate compromise with the United States, and have provided a political windfall for the Chinese hardliners, who would not support any concession to the United States.21 In order to reinforce the fifth-column effect while minimizing the prospect of the rally-around-the-flag effect, David Cortright and George Lopez suggest a greater use of targeted financial sanctions. By avoiding harmful impacts on vulnerable population, 20 21 Jonathan Kirshner, “The Microfoundations of Economic Sanctions,” Security Studies, vol. 6, no. 3 (Spring 1997), pp. 46-50. James R. Lilley, “Trade and the Waking Giant – China, Asia, and American Engagement,” in James R. Lilley and Wendell L. Willkie II (eds.), Beyond MFN: Trade with China and American Interests (Washington, D.C.: AEI Press, 1994), pp. 48-53. David M. Lampton, “A Better Approach in Waging 171 targeted financial measures deny political elites the opportunity to rally broad political support. Instead of punishing the general population, asset freezes and similar measures apply pressure primarily on the political and military elites responsible for wrongdoing. By contrast, income and term-of-trade effects of trade are often widespread within the target economy, and are difficult to aim accurately at some groups and not others. Although limiting imports and exports can devastate the local economy (and thus inflict severe punishment on the target), such costs often affect ordinary citizens far more than the elites who actually make policy decisions.22 In their analysis of international economic sanctions against South Africa, Xavier Carim, Audie Klotz, and Olivier Lebleu conclude that bans on immediate financing the short-term debt of South Africa offered the United States direct bargaining leverage. According to their study, financial sanctions sharpened divisions within the white oligarchy and strained the alliance between business and the Afrikaner-dominated National Party, which governed South Africa until 1994. Financial sanctions have improved the effectiveness of sanctions.23 Finally, the domestic politics/symbolic approach argues that domestic political and economic instability reinforces the effectiveness of economic sanctions, particularly when the target government faces heavy costs. If the target government has suffered from recent instability, it will be more vulnerable to sanctions. Thus, under this circumstance, the target will be more likely to make concessions to avoid sanctions. By contrast, it is very plausible to argue that if the sender suffers from domestic economic and political instability, it will be less likely for the sender to 22 23 the Next MFN Battle,” Topics, vol. 27, no. 6 (August 1997), p. 45. David Cortright and George A. Lopez, “Sanctions and Incentives as Tools of Economic Statecraft,” in Raimo Vayrynen (ed.), Globalization and Global Governance (Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc., 1999), pp. 114-116. Xavier Carim, Audie Klotz, and Olivier Lebleu, “The Political Economy of Financial Sanctions,” in Neta C. Crawford and Audie Klotz (eds.), How Sanctions Work: Lessons from South Africa (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1999), pp. 159-177. 172 maintain sanctions and the target to concede because economic sanctions are double-edged.24 Statistical Evidence There is virtually no statistical exercise on the rally-around-the-flag effect, nationalism, or the fifth-column effect stemming from economic sanctions. It is very difficult to quantify these effects. Nevertheless, there are a few statistical tests on the effectiveness of financial sanctions and the issue of economic health and political stability in addition to the HSE study. Regarding the effectiveness of financial sanctions, according to his 126 cases studies involving 59 countries from 1948 to 1972, James Blessing argues that the suspension of aid does not appear to have been a very effective means of inducing change in target behavior. However, he argues that this finding is not statistically significant and should only be viewed as a hypothesis.25 HSE reach a more affirmative conclusion that financial sanctions among 115 cases between 1914 to 1989 have been more effective than trade sanctions alone. Financial sanctions used alone contributed partially to the achievement of foreign policy goals in 41 percent of the cases, compared to only 24 percent for trade sanctions alone. In addition, the declining use of financial sanctions matches the declining success rate of economic sanctions in the HSE database. Financial sanctions were part of sanctions packages in more than 90 percent of episodes prior to 1973, while they were present in only two-thirds of the cases between 1974 to 1989. Coincidentally, almost half the 24 25 Gary Clyde Hufbauer, Jeffery J. Schott, and Kimberly Ann Elliot, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, 2nd ed. (Washington, D.C.: Institute of International Economics, 1990), pp. 97-98. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 114, 122. James A. Blessing, “The Suspension of Foreign Aid: A Macro-Analysis,” Polity, vol. 13, no. 3 173 sanctions episodes in the pre-1973 period succeeded, whereas the success rate among the cases between 1974 to 1989 was just under 25 percent.26 Regarding the issue of economic health and political instability, using a probit model to analyze 98 cases based on the 1985 HSE database, 27 excluding double-countings and the episodes where sanctions were threatened but not imposed, San Ling Lam finds that the target country’s overall economic health and political stability is significant at the 10 percent level. In addition, Kimberly Elliot and Peter Uimonen use the same method to test the HSE cases, excluding sanctions threat cases and cases in which military action was pursued concurrently with economic sanctions. Elliot and Uimonen find that the target country’s overall economic health and political stability is significant at the 1 percent level.28 Using ordered logit estimation based on the HSE database, A. Cooper Drury finds that distressed targets tended to succumb to sanctions more often than strong, healthy targets, but their relationship was marginally significant at best. 29 Using probit regression based on the HSE-Drezner database, Daniel Drezner finds that health of the target regime is significant at the 5 percent level. The variable, health of the target regime, is negatively correlated with concession size.30 Further, Drezner uses Boolean analysis of 39 cases of economic sanctions imposed by Russia between 1992 and 1997. 26 27 28 29 30 (Spring 1981), pp. 524-535. Gary Clyde Hufbauer, Jeffery J. Schott, and Kimberly Ann Elliot, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, 2nd ed. (Washington, D.C.: Institute of International Economics, 1990), pp. 102-111. Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, and Barbara Oegg, “Targeted Sanctions: A Policy Alternative?,” presented at Georgetown Journal of Law and Policy in International Business and Georgetown Asia Forum Symposium on Sanctions Reforms? Evaluating the Economic Weapon in Asia & the World, February 23, 2000, http://www.iie.com/TESTMONY/targsanc.htm, accessed November 27, 2000, p. 3 of 6. Gary Clyde Hufbauer and Jeffery J. Schott, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, (Washington, D.C.: Institute of International Economics, 1985). San Ling Lam, “Economic Sanctions and the Success of Foreign Policy Goals,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 2 (1990), pp. 239-247. Kimberly Ann Elliott and Peter P. Uimonen, “The Effectiveness of Economic Sanctions with Application to the Case of Iraq,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 5 (1993), pp. 403-409. A. Cooper Drury, “Revisiting Economic Sanctions Reconsidered,” Journal of Peace Research, vol. 35, no. 4 (1998), pp. 507-508. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New 174 He finds that if the sanctions impose significant costs on the target regime, then that regime’s domestic stability is a crucial factor in determining the outcome.31 Democracy vs. Authoritarism According to the above analysis, the domestic politics/symbolic approach emphasizes that the effectiveness of economic sanctions will depend upon the dynamic balance between the rally-around-the-flag effect and the fifth-column effect in the target. Since the public and interest groups play a critical role in these two effects by pressuring the target government to sustain or abandon its objectionable policy, it is plausible to hypothesize that sanctions are more likely to be effective in societies where there is some degree of democratic freedom than in rigidly totalitarian states. The rally-around-the-flag effect might dominate in authoritarian countries while the fifth-column effect might prevail in the democratic countries. It is expected that authoritarian countries usually have stronger domestic political systems than democratic ones and thus authoritarian rulers are more able to manipulate their own societies in comparison with leaders of democratic states.32 Ivan Eland contends, “In cases where the target government has absolute totalitarian control over society, especially over the media and the formation of political opposition, the rally-around-the-flag effect will dominate and no 31 32 York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 121-125. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 131-247. Daniel W. Drezner, “The Complex Causation of Sanction Outcomes,” in Steve Chan and A. Cooper Drury (eds.), Sanctions as Economic Statecraft: Theory and Practice (New York: St. Martin’s, 2000), pp. 212-233. David Cortright and George A. Lopez, The Sanctions Decade: Assessing UN Strategies in the 1990s (Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner, 2000), p. 22. Brian Walsh, Economic Sanctions and International Power: The Emergence of Defensive and Co-optive Power, Ph.D. dissertation, the University of Maryland, College Park, 1998, p. 288. Stephen D. Krasner, “Domestic Constraints on International Leverage,” in Klaus Knorr and Frank N. Trager (eds.), Economic Issues and National Security (Lawrence, Kansas: University Press of Kansas, 1977), p. 178. 175 [fifth-column] effect will arise to pressure the government to comply with the [sender] nation’s wishes.”33 Coincidentally, authoritarian countries are often able to back down and withstand the effects of economic sanctions. Richard Haass points out three possible reasons: (1) sanctions sometimes trigger a rally-around-the-flag, nationalist reaction; (2) by creating scarcity, they enable governments to better control the distribution of goods; and, (3) they create a general sense of siege that governments can exploit to maintain political control.34 However, Robert Pape disagrees, arguing, “Democratization further imbues individual citizens with a personal attachment to national goals. Even in the weakest and most fractured states, external pressure is more likely to enhance the nationalist legitimacy of rulers than to undermine it. In some situations, advances in communication further improve the ability of governments to enhance the legitimacy of the state and its policies.”35 There are times when a target with a functioning electoral system will resist international efforts to sanction it quite successfully. Indeed, HSE report at least eleven cases where sanctions against liberal democracies failed.36 Michael Mastanduno also agrees with Robert Pape. He contends that democratic states can also respond to sanctions, as they typically do to war, with political integration rather than disintegration. Formal political structures are less important than the interests and influence of domestic political actors, and the relationships 33 34 35 36 Ivan Eland, “Economic Sanctions as Tools of Foreign Policy,” in David Cortright and George A. Lopez (eds.), Economic Sanctions: Panacea or Peacebuilding in a Post-Cold War World? (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 1995), p. 35. Richard N. Haass, “Sanctioning Madness,” Foreign Affairs, vol. 76, no. 6 (November/December 1997), p. 80. Robert A. Pape, “Why Economic Sanctions Do Not Work,” International Security, vol. 22, no. 2 (Fall 1997), pp. 106-107. Eleven cases refer to cases 48-3, 54-1, 54-3, 56-1, 57-1, 63-5, 71-1, 74-1, 74-2, 78-4, and 83-1 in the HSE database. 176 between those actors and the state. He concludes that the key is the ability of domestic actors to act as “transmission belts”, carrying the economic effects of sanctions into the political process of the target state. Therefore, he suggests that the research strategy be to get “underneath” the formal political structure to assess the impact of sanctions on particular domestic actors and on the relationships among the state, its supporters, and its opponents.37 Statistical Evidence Kim Nossal observes that the overwhelming majority (twelve of fourteen) of sanctions successes since 1945 occurred in cases where the target political system was a liberal democracy. He also notes that authoritarian regimes generally find it easy to resist the punitive impact by simply passing the costs of the sanctions to the governed. By contrast, Robert Pape, examining HSE cases, excluding economic warfare and trade disputes, finds that there are four sanctions successes for democratic targets as well as four for authoritarian targets if sanctions successes include indeterminate cases. (Regarding the debate on sanctions success, see Chapter 3.) This is in sharp contrast to Nossal’s finding.38 Although sometimes a correlation between sanctions success and political form seems to exist, it is by no means clear or self-evident how or why sanctions seem to 37 38 Michael Mastanduno, “Economic Statecraft, Interdependence, and National Security: Agenda for Research,” Jean-Marc F. Blanchard, Edward D. Mansfield, and Norrin M. Ripsman, Power and the Purse: Economic Statecraft, Interdependence, and National Security (Portland, OR: Frank Cass, 2000), pp. 297-298. For Robert Pape, four sanctions successes for democratic targets refer to cases 48-1, 77-4, 79-3, and 87-3 in the HSE database; four sanctions successes for authoritarian targets refer to cases 33-1, 75-1, 82-3, and 89-1 in the HSE database. Kim Nossal argues that among the many sanctions episodes since 1945, only fourteen stand out as unequivocally successful, in the sense that the target state was prompted to alter its behavior by the use of sanctions. Kim Richard Nossal, “Liberal Democratic Regimes, International Sanctions, and Global Governance,” in Raimo Vayrynen (ed.), Globalization and Global Governance (Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc., 1999), pp. 134-135. Robert A. Pape, “Why Economic Sanctions Do Not Work,” International Security, vol. 22, 177 work so well in countries that are either liberal democracies or have some of the structures, forms, and practices associated with liberal democratic politics. For example, despite finding a strong link between sanctions success and the target’s political system, Kim Nossal concludes that economic sanctions will be effective only when the target has a democratic form and is weak, vulnerable, and dependent.39 However, the conclusions reached by Nossal and Pape are biased because they do not take the cases of failed sanctions against the democratic targets into account. It would be useful to know whether sanctions against democratic targets are more likely to succeed among all sanctions cases against democratic targets rather than simply whether the democratic targets will dominate among all sanctions successes of both democratic and authoritarian targets. In addition, we need to compare this success rate for the democratic targets with that for the authoritarian targets. Based on the HSE database, 8 cases of economic sanctions against liberal democracies succeeded while 11 cases failed. The success ratio is 42 percent for the democratic targets. By comparison, 32 cases of economic sanctions against authoritarian regimes succeeded while 64 cases failed, a success ratio of 33 percent. Although the success rate for the democratic targets is higher than that for the authoritarian targets, chi square tests show that there is no statistically significant correlation between regime types and the outcome of economic sanctions. (See Table 5.1.) Table 5.1. Sanctions Result against Democratic and Authoritarian Countries Success (case) 39 Democratic targets Authoritarian targets 8 32 no. 2 (Fall 1997), pp. 98-106. Kim Richard Nossal, “Liberal Democratic Regimes, International Sanctions, and Global Governance,” in Raimo Vayrynen (ed.), Globalization and Global Governance (Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc., 1999), pp. 147-148. 178 Failure (case) 11 64 Success rate 42% 33% Note: a: Sanctions successes on democratic targets include cases 48-1, 56-3, 58-1, 65-2, 73-1, 77-4, 79-3, and 87-3 in the HSE database. b: Sanctions failure on democratic targets include cases 48-3, 54-1, 54-3, 56-1, 57-1, 63-5, 71-1, 74-1, 74-2, 78-4, and 83-1 in the HSE database. c: Whether a target is a democratic regime or an authoritarian society mostly depends upon the comparative measures of freedom annually published by the Freedom House. If the measure of political rights indicates below or equivalent to 3 with 1 representing the most free and 7 the least free category, the target is treated as a democratic country. If the measure indicates above 3, the target is considered as an authoritarian country. Source: Gary Clyde Hufbauer, Jeffery J. Schott, and Kimberly Ann Elliot, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, 2nd ed. (Washington, D.C.: Institute of International Economics, 1990). Freedom House Survey Team, Freedom in the World (New York: Freedom House, 1980-1999). III. The Signaling Approach The signaling approach argues that in a world of imperfect information, substantial costs incurred by the sender can signal the intent that threats will be carried out. As long as the sender bears the significant cost of economic sanctions and these sanctions are coupled with substantial military threats, the target will tend to make concessions. In this regard, sanctions are only useful in acting as a signal of resolve, and economic sanctions cannot work alone. The casual argument in this school of thought is that what appears to be a sanctions success is actually the product of an implicit military threat. Economic sanctions are not the genuine cause of concessions, but merely an observable signal of military power or threat. For example, almost half of the cases deemed successes by HSE are really examples of the successful application of force. This would appear to be evidence that economic sanctions are 179 really a signal for more coercive measures.40 James Lindsay elaborates that sanctions will succeed as signals only if four conditions are met. First, it must be clear the sender objects to the target’s behavior and will try to change it. Second, the potential target must perceive that the sender can inflict economic pain. Third, the sender must not perceive that the potential target can resort to adequate counterpressures. And, fourth, the potential target must not place a higher value on the disputed behavior than on the costs expected to be incurred. Lindsay concludes that given the stringency of these conditions, it is likely that sanctions have a limited signaling value.41 Furthermore, David Baldwin, David Leyton-Brown, and Lisa Martin argue that substantial sender costs are crucial in order for sanctions to send the desired signal. A sender is less likely to bluff if it incurs a high price in imposing sanctions. Their values as a signal comes not from the damage inflicted on the target, but the cost to the sender. By contrast, if the sender imposes economic sanctions because of the domestic need of “doing something” and reluctance to use the force, low-cost sanctions may indeed signal a lack of resolve.42 However, Valerie Schwebach argues that irresolute actors would sometimes have an incentive to bluff by imposing sanctions. The very potential of sanctions to be good signals of resolve could undermine their effectiveness as signals since irresolute actors are tempted to use them. Thus this bluffing behavior would blur the connection 40 41 42 Daniel W. Drezner, “The Complex Causation of Sanction Outcomes,” in Steve Chan and A. Cooper Drury (eds.), Sanctions as Economic Statecraft: Theory and Practice (New York: St. Martin’s, 2000), pp. 215-216. Robert A. Pape, “Why Economic Sanctions Do Not Work,” International Security, vol. 22, no. 2 (Fall 1997), pp. 98-106. James M. Lindsay, “Trade Sanctions as Policy Instruments: A Re-examination,” International Studies Quarterly, no. 30 (1986), pp. 164-170. David Baldwin, Economic Statecraft (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1985), p. 372. David Leyton-Brown, “Lessons and Policy Considerations about Economic Sanctions,” David Leyton-Brown (ed.), The Utility of International Economic Sanctions (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1987), pp. 305-6. Lisa L. Martin, Coercive Cooperation: Explaining Multilateral Economic Sanctions (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1992), pp. 5, 36-38. 180 between sanctions and resolve, and decrease the usefulness of sanctions as signals. For example, HSE report only six cases in which the threat of sanctions alone was sufficient to induce target compliance.43 To sum up, the signaling approach makes two predictions about the pattern of economic sanctions outcomes. First, the sender should incur greater costs and should couple sanctions with a threat to use force; by doing this, the sender communicates a more credible signal to the target. Therefore, the sender’s costs should be positively correlated with concession size. Second, the threat to use force, or the differences in aggregate power, should be positively correlated with concession size. Accordingly, the causal mechanism that determines sanctions success is the prospect of military conflict, not the use of economic sanctions.44 Statistical Evidence Regarding sender costs, using probit techniques based on the 1985 HSE database, San Ling Lam finds that the sender’s costs are negatively correlated with sanctions success, and results are significant at the 5 percent level. Using logistic regression based on the HSE database, excluding the cases of economic warfare, T. Clifton Morgan and Valerie Schwebach find the sender’s costs to be negatively correlated with sanctions success and significant at the 1 percent level of significance.45 43 44 45 Valerie L. Schwebach, “Sanctions as Signals: A Line in the Sand or a Lack of Resolve?,” in Steve Chan and A. Cooper Drury (eds.), Sanctions as Economic Statecraft: Theory and Practice (New York: St. Martin’s, 2000), pp. 188-203. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 113, 122. San Ling Lam, “Economic Sanctions and the Success of Foreign Policy Goals,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 2 (1990), pp. 244-246. T. Clifton Morgan, and Valerie L. Schwebach, “Fools Suffer Gladly: The Use of Economic Sanctions in International Crises,” International Studies Quarterly, no. 41 (1997), pp. 38-47. 181 Regarding the correlation between the use of military action and concession size, San Ling Lam finds that both covert and overt military action has no statistically significant effect on the outcome of sanctions. Using probit regression based on the HSE database, excluding sanctions threats cases and cases with military action, Kimberly Elliot and Peter Uimonen find that the use of quasi-military force has a negative effect on the chances of success and is significant at the 5 percent level. Looking at ratios of sender to target gross national product, both studies by Lam, as well as the one by Elliot and Uimonen, show that economic sanctions are less likely to succeed if the sender is significantly more powerful than the target. This result is significant at the 5 percent level in Lam’s study and at the 1 percent level in Elliot and Uimonen’s. In addition, T. Clifton Morgan and Valerie Schwebach find that the relative military capabilities between the sender and the target has a negative effect on the outcome of the economic sanctions and is significant at the 1 percent level. That is, as the sender’s relative capabilities increase, the target is less likely to make concessions.46 Using ordered-probit measures to test the HSE-Drezner database, Daniel Drezner finds that the signaling approach is not supported by evidence. The military statecraft variable is statistically insignificant. The aggregate power measure is significant at the 5 percent level, according to Drezner, but it takes a negative coefficient. As the sender acquires more power, it is less likely to generate significant concessions. In another estimation of Drezner, neither the military statecraft nor the aggregate power hypotheses has statistical significance.47 46 47 San Ling Lam, “Economic Sanctions and the Success of Foreign Policy Goals,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 2 (1990), pp. 244-246. Elliott, Kimberly Ann and Peter P. Uimonen, “The Effectiveness of Economic Sanctions with Application to the Case of Iraq,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 5 (1993), pp. 403-409. T. Clifton Morgan and Valerie L. Schwebach, “Fools Suffer Gladly: The Use of Economic Sanctions in International Crises,” International Studies Quarterly, no. 41 (1997), pp. 38-47. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 122-125. 182 Moreover, Daniel Drezner uses Boolean analysis of 39 cases of economic sanctions imposed by Russia between 1992 and 1997. He concludes that the threat of military force is neither a necessary nor sufficient condition for economic sanctions to produce significant or moderate concessions. Indeed, the absence of military statecraft is a sufficient condition for producing concessions. In an overwhelming majority of the cases, military force either played no role or only a negative one.48 IV. The Conflict Expectations Model Daniel Drezner uses his conflict expectations model to argue that if the sender and the target are adversaries, the target will be more reluctant to acquiesce under the pressure of economic sanctions because its concessions represent a transfer of political leverage to the sender, magnifying the long-term impact of the concession in the target’s eyes. An adversarial relationship with the sender would cause the target to consider two political concerns: relative gains and reputation. When relative gains concerns are prominent, a concession represents a gain for the sender and a loss for the target. When reputation is important, acquiescence bolsters the sender’s credibility as a tough negotiator while weakening the target’s reputation.49 For example, given the escalating demands from the U.S. Congress after the Tiananmen incident, Beijing could not be assured that concessions to the United States would not simply produce further demands and thus did not make concessions.50 According to Peter Liberman and other neo-realists, a state’s sensitivity to 48 49 50 Daniel W. Drezner, “The Complex Causation of Sanction Outcomes,” in Steve Chan and A. Cooper Drury (eds.), Sanctions as Economic Statecraft: Theory and Practice (New York: St. Martin’s, 2000), pp. 221-229. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 27-35. David M. Lampton, Same Bed, Different Dreams: Managing U.S.-China Relations, 1989-2000 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2001), p. 305. 183 relative gains depends on the degree and duration of the security threat posed by specific adversaries. States will fear the relative gains of near-by, powerful, offensively armed, and hostile nations more than those of distant, weak, defensively armed, and friendly ones. For example, East-West trade during the Cold War provides a clear demonstration of security-motivated relative-gains policy. Believing that trade would provide a great benefit to the smaller and more backward Soviet economy, U.S. officials halted trade with the Soviet bloc during the 1950s and 1960s, and continued to embargo high-tech exports thereafter.51 If the target is an ally, relative gains and reputation concerns are less prominent because the target anticipates fewer zero-sum conflicts in the future. Between allies, the target will care more about the immediate costs and benefits of a stalemate than about the long-run implications of any transfer of leverage. Therefore, the target will concede more to avoid the costs of deadlock. Ceteris paribus, the target’s concessions will increase when the target and the sender are more closely aligned. In addition, Daniel Drezner argues that the absence of conflict expectations is a necessary condition for economic sanctions to produce significant concessions. If the target-sender relationship is adversarial, there must be a large gap in costs for sanctions to generate even moderate concessions.52 (See Figure 5.1.) Figure 5.1. The Effect of Conflict Expectations on Concession Size Peter Liberman, “Trading with the Enemy: Security and Relative Economic Gains,” International Security, High vol. 21, no. 1 (Summer 1996), pp. 150-155. Duncan Snidal, “Relative Gains and the Pattern Concession of International Cooperation,” in David A. Baldwin (ed.), Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The condition Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993), pp. 170-233. John C. Matthews III, “Current Gains and Future Outcomes: When Cumulative Relative Gains Matter,” International Security, vol. 21, no. 1 (Summer 1996), pp. 112-146. Beverly Crawford, Economic Concession Vulnerability in International Relations: The Case of East-West Trade, Investment, and Finance (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993). size 52 Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 27-35, 43-47, 244-245. Daniel W. Drezner, “Allies, Adversaries, and Economic Coercion: Russian Foreign Economic Policy Since 1991,” Security Studies, vol. 6, no. 3 (Spring 1997), pp. 66-71. 51 Low 184 Low High Conflict expectations The conflict expectations model also argues that the target’s concession will increase as the difference between the target’s and the sender’s costs of deadlock increases. According to Daniel Drezner’s model, the expected costs of sanctions have a monotonic effect on the outcome. As the target’s costs of deadlock increase, ceteris paribus, the sender’s gains from the equilibrium outcome increase. As the sender’s costs of deadlock decrease, ceteris paribus, the sender’s gains increase as well. That is, only sufficient asymmetrical interdependence between the sender and the target would result in enough pressure on the target to produce concessions to the sender through imposing economic sanctions.53 Table 5.2 shows how the cost and alignment variables interact. As can be seen in this table, the gap in costs has a consistent effect on the outcome, while alignment has 53 Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 45-46. Miroslav Nincic and Peter Wallensteen, “Economic Coercion and Foreign Policy,” in Miroslav Nincic and Peter Wallensteen (eds.), Dilemmas of Economic Coercion: Sanctions in World Politics (New York: Praeger, 1983), pp. 2-3, 12. 185 a contradictory effect.54 Table 5.2. The Predicted Pattern of Economic Sanctions Costs gap Ally Adversary Large gap in costs Significant concessions Moderate concessions Small gap in costs No sanctions attempt Minor concessions Source: Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), p. 54. Reprinted with the permission of Cambridge University Press. To sum up, the conflict expectations model makes two major predictions about the pattern of sanctions success. First, the sender will win more substantial concessions by imposing economic sanctions against the target when the gap in the costs of deadlock between the sender and the target is greater. Ceteris paribus, as the sender’s costs of deadlock increase, the sender is less likely to impose sanctions against the target. If it does choose to employ sanctions, it will obtain less significant concessions. An increase in the sender’s costs makes economic sanctions less viable and less profitable. By contrast, an increase in the target’s costs makes economic sanctions more viable and more profitable. Second, the target will concede more if conflict expectations between the target and sender are low. By contrast, as conflict expectations increase, the target will be more resistant to concessions. Even with a large gap of costs between the sender and the target, the target would make at most moderate concessions. However, if the sender’s demand is greater than the optimum possible concession and cannot be compromised, the equilibrium outcome is deadlock and the sender could not extract any concession from the target. 54 Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 47, 53-54. 186 Statistical Evidence Regarding the gap in costs, HSE’s results provide moderate support for the notion that when the costs gap between the sender and the target is greater, sanctions are more likely to be successful in attaining the desired response from the target. Specifically, their analysis indicates that for successful cases the average ratio of the costs of sanctions to GNP is 2.4 percent for the target country and the average cost-to-sender index (scored from 1 to 4, with 1 representing a net gain and 4 a major loss to the sender) is 1.8 point for the sender. In failed cases the ratio was 1.0 for the target and the index 2.0 for the sender.55 Using a probit model based on the 1985 HSE database, San Ling Lam finds the target’s costs to be significant at the 5 percent level. Using probit regression based on the HSE database, excluding sanctions threats cases and cases with military action, Kimberly Elliot and Peter Uimonen find the target’s costs to be significant at the 1 percent level. A. Cooper Drury uses logistic regression to analyze the HSE database. He finds a positive correlation between the target’s costs and a successful outcome at the 5 percent level. Using logistic regression based on the HSE database, T. Clifford Morgan and Valerie Schwebach also find the target’s costs to be significant at 1 percent. On the whole, these results suggest a clear link between the target’s costs and the outcome of a sanctions event.56 55 56 Gary Clyde Hufbauer, Jeffery J. Schott, and Kimberly Ann Elliot, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, 2nd ed. (Washington, D.C.: Institute of International Economics, 1990), pp. 102-103. San Ling Lam, “Economic Sanctions and the Success of Foreign Policy Goals,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 2 (1990), pp. 244-246. Kimberly Ann Elliott and Peter P. Uimonen, “The Effectiveness of Economic Sanctions with Application to the Case of Iraq,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 5 (1993), pp. 403-409. T. Clifton Morgan and Valerie L. Schwebach, “Fools Suffer Gladly: The Use of Economic Sanctions in International Crises,” International Studies Quarterly, no. 41 (1997), pp. 43-45. 187 San Ling Lam, and T. Clifford Morgan and Valerie Schwebach include a measure of the sender’s cost in their studies. Using a probit model based on the 1985 HSE database, Lam finds the sender’s costs to be negatively correlated with sanctions success and significant at the 5 percent level. In addition, Lam also finds that the logarithm of the ratio of sender’s GNP to target’s GNP is significant at the 5 percent level. Using logistic regression based on the HSE database, Morgan and Schwebach find the same correlation at the 1 percent level of significance. High sender costs are found to be negatively correlated with sanctions success. However, Morgan and Schwebach point out that sanctions do not seem to result in great changes in expected outcomes, regardless of the costs. Extreme costs are required to produce relatively small changes in outcomes.57 Makio Miyagawa analyzes in detail 31 cases of economic sanctions between 1933 and 1990. Miyagawa finds that the cost to the sender will reduce the effectiveness of a sanction.58 Using ordered-probit measures to test the HSE-Drezner database, Daniel Drezner finds the gap in costs takes a positive sign; the greater the gap in costs, the more the target will concede. The cost term is significant at the 1 percent level in both of his regressions.59 Regarding the conflict expectations effect, the U.S. General Accounting Office studies 27 sanctions episodes beginning after the World War I and concludes in a 1992 report to the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, “Economic sanctions are most effective when they are applied multilaterally or against otherwise friendly nations with economic and political ties to the [sender] country.”60 57 58 59 60 San Ling Lam, “Economic Sanctions and the Success of Foreign Policy Goals,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 2 (1990), pp. 239-247. T. Clifton Morgan and Valerie L. Schwebach, “Fools Suffer Gladly: The Use of Economic Sanctions in International Crises,” International Studies Quarterly, no. 41 (1997), pp. 43-45. Makio Miyagawa, Do Economic Sanctions Work? (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1992), pp. 61-88. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 122-124. United States General Accounting Office, Economic Sanctions: Effectiveness as Tools of Foreign 188 Using a probit model based on the 1985 HSE database, San Ling Lam finds that the prior relationship (alignment) is statistically significant at the 10 percent level.61 Using ordered-probit measures to analyze the HSE-Drezner database, Daniel Drezner finds the alignment term takes a positive sign. Drezner’s results are significant at the 1 percent level in his first regression and at the 5 percent level in his second regression. This means that as the expectations of future conflict between the two countries declines, the target will make a larger concession. In addition, if an ally and an adversary face the same costs of deadlock, the ally target will still concede more. 62 Further, Daniel Drezner applies the Boolean method to analyze 39 episodes of economic sanctions imposed by Russia between 1992 and 1997 and concludes that economic sanctions will produce significant concessions if the target is a close ally and the sender does not threaten military force. The absence of conflict expectations is a necessary condition for the sender to extract significant concessions. The presence of a military threat or domestic instability in the target country is neither necessary nor sufficient conditions. In the presence of conflict expectations, there must be a significant gap in costs of sanctions to lead to a successful outcome.63 V. Conclusion First of all, it should be emphasized that economic sanctions are generally ineffective and the rate of success in terms of target compliance has been declining over time, particular from 1975 to 1990. The success rate of economic sanctions, 61 62 63 Policy, Report to the Chairman, Committee on Foreign Relations, U.S. Senate, GAO/NSIAD-92-106, February 1992, p. 3. San Ling Lam, “Economic Sanctions and the Success of Foreign Policy Goals,” Japan and the World Economy, vol. 2 (1990), pp. 239-247. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 122-124. Daniel W. Drezner, The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 131-247. 189 excluding economic warfare and trade disputes, is as low as 4.6 to 10.4 percent. The HSE approach suggests that sanctions are most effective under the following conditions: modest sender goals, a weak and unstable target, high costs to the target, low costs to the sender, friendly relationship between the sender and the target, a high trade concentration for the target with the sender, quick and harsh unilateral sanctions, no assistance to the target by third countries, and, finally, sanctions that are primarily financial rather than trade-oriented. Although the HSE database is blamed for sample bias by including trade disputes and economic warfare, most of the above variables have been further confirmed by the other three approaches mentioned in this chapter. The domestic politics/symbolic approach focuses on the political economy within the sender and target countries. This approach provides three factors working against the effectiveness of economic sanctions: (1) few cases with damaging sanctions; (2) the rally-around-the-flag effect reinforced by nationalism; and (3) manipulated redistribution effects of sanctions in the target. Furthermore, it is very plausible that if the sender suffers from domestic economic and political instability, it will be less likely for the target to concede because the sender will have more concerns about the costs of sanctions. Economic sanctions might be treated as a humiliating affront to the target and thus trigger a rally-around-the-flag effect. Pervasive nationalism and a lack of discrimination between the “guilty” and the “innocent” will significantly reinforce the rally-around-the-flag effect. The sender might become the common enemy for the target. The resistance of domestic groups and the public to economic sanctions becomes synonymous with patriotism, while dissent would trigger accusations of disloyalty or treason. These effects will facilitate political integration in the target and cause the sanctions to fail. By contrast, this approach cites two factors as contributing to the effectiveness of 190 sanctions: (1) the fifth-column effect; and, (2) political and economic instability in the target. The fifth-column effect is seen when some particular groups in the target country hurt by the sanctions petition their government to comply with the sender’s demands. The more the sanction hurts the target central government directly, the greater the chance to influence its policy. In addition, core support groups of the target regime negatively affected by sanctions will put pressure on their government. As a matter of fact, China’s political strategies toward Taiwan, yi min bi guan (utilizing the public to urge the official) and yi shang wei zheng (exploiting business to press politics), are based on the expectations of a fifth-column effect. Furthermore, the target government with domestic political and economic instability will tend to concede to the sender’s demand. Nevertheless, economic sanctions can generate both the rally-around-the-flag effect and the fifth-column effect at the same time. In order to bring about alteration of an objectionable policy, the fifth-column effect must overwhelm the rally-around-the-flag effect. In other words, sanctions must reduce the political effectiveness of pro-regime groups more than they reduce the effectiveness of opposition groups. In particular, financial sanctions tend to reinforce the fifth-column effect while minimizing the rally-around-the-flag effect. By contrast, trade sanctions cannot be aimed accurately at any particular group, thus they are more likely to trigger a rally-around-the-flag effect. There are several statistical tests of financial sanctions and political instability in the target country, although there is no exercise on the rally-around-the-flag effect, nationalism, and the fifth-column effect. Overall, the argument that financial sanctions are more effective is based on moderate statistical evidence and the argument that the target with unstable political and economic conditions tends to make concessions to the sender has strong statistical support. 191 There is no sufficient statistical evidence, however, to confirm that the democracy of a target country is a necessary or sufficient condition for sanctions successes. In general, a democratic regime may provide more space for the public and interest groups to influence the target government. But an authoritarian regime also needs to respond to pressure from interest groups or the members of the regime itself, such as factions or competing leaders, bureaucratic sectors, local leaders, core business groups, or sometimes even the public. The signaling approach argues that sanctions could be useful as a signal for more coercive measures. This approach makes two predictions about the pattern of sanctions outcome. First, the sender’s costs should be positively correlated with concession size. Second, a threat to use force, or difference in aggregate power, should be positively correlated with concession size. However, statistical results provide no support for the signaling approach. The statistical evidence available categorically rejects the argument that high sender costs can effectively signal resolve and thus lead to a successful outcome. High sender costs are found to be negatively correlated with sanctions success. In addition, neither military power nor military threats affect the outcome of a sanctions attempt. Therefore, economic sanctions are not a stalking horse for military threats or relative capabilities. The conflict expectations model makes two major predictions. First, the greater the gap between the sender’s and target’s costs, the greater the target’s concessions. An increase in the sender’s costs makes economic sanctions less viable and less profitable. By contrast, an increase in the target’s costs makes economic sanctions more viable and more profitable. Second, if the sender and the target are adversaries, the target will be more reluctant to acquiesce under the pressure of economic sanctions because of relative gains and reputation concerns. As the target and sender 192 anticipate few political conflicts in the future, the magnitude of the target’s concessions will increase. For economic sanctions to produce significant concessions, the absence of conflict expectations is a necessary condition. If the target-sender relationship is adversarial, there must be a large gap in costs for sanctions to generate even moderate concessions. The statistical results provide solid empirical support for this model. Regarding the implication for cross-Strait economic relations, in theory, China’s sanctions against Taiwan generally tend to be ineffective. The probability of success of Chinese economic sanctions is only 4.6 to 10.4 percent. In addition, the necessary condition for China’s successful sanctions with Taiwan’s moderate concessions is: China enjoys a large gap of costs. The following conditions will contribute to the effectiveness of economic sanctions: (1) China enjoys a significant costs gap of economic sanctions between Taiwan and China; (2) China’s sanctions trigger a fifth-column effect; (3) China imposes financial sanctions against Taiwan instead of trade sanctions, but financial flows now favor Taiwan’s leverage; (4) Taiwan is unstable; and (5) China imposes sanctions against Taiwan quickly, with maximum harshness, and without significant international assistance to Taiwan. By contrast, the following conditions will contribute to the ineffectiveness of China’s sanctions: (1) China’s sanctions trigger nationalism and a rally-around-the-flag effect in Taiwan; (2) China suffers from domestic instability; (3) Taiwan’s government can manipulate redistribution effects of sanctions to favor the ruling coalition; and (4) Taiwan’s decision-makers have strong concerns of relative gains and reputation in the cross-Strait conflict. It is impossible to predict the domestic situation for both Taiwan and China, whether Beijing could impose sanctions against Taiwan quickly, with maximum 193 harshness, and whether the Taiwanese government could manipulate redistribution effects of sanctions to favor the ruling coalition when Beijing were to impose economic sanctions against Taiwan. However, these are not the most important variables to influence the effectiveness of economic sanctions. They are secondary to the following variables: costs gap of sanctions between Beijing and Taipei (including the reaction of the international community toward China’s sanctions), rally-around-the-flag effects, fifth-column effects, and perception of decision-makers in Taiwan. As a result, this research focuses on the last four variables to assess Taiwan’s vulnerability with respect to cross-Strait economic relations. Chapter 8 will assess the possible costs of China’s possible economic sanctions against Taiwan. By examining two cases of the 1995-96 Taiwan Strait missile tensions and the 1999-2000 Taiwan Strait incident, Chapter 11 will further test the following hypotheses on the outcome of China’s possible sanctions against Taiwan: 1. As China’s military threats increased, Taiwan experienced rising nationalism and a strong “rally-around-the-flag” effect, with a moderate fifth-column effect, in terms of the reaction of Taiwan’s public, elites, and interest groups. 2. Taiwan’s decision-makers emphasized (credibility) in the cross-Strait conflict. 194 relative gains and reputation