Central European University Department economics The roles of fiscal, monetary and exchange rate policies in preventing currency crises and overcoming the consequences Term paper for the course ‘Comparative macroeconomic policy’ Professor: Jacek Rostowski Authors: Gregor Langus and Willen Lipatov Budapest, 2000 CONTENT Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 3 Definitions and the role of government ................................................................................. 3 Propagation of crisis .............................................................................................................. 6 Buildup of the crisis in East Asia .......................................................................................... 7 Causes................................................................................................................................. 7 Crisis outbreak.................................................................................................................... 8 Policy responses .................................................................................................................... 9 The roles of macroeconomic policies in overcoming the consequences ............................. 10 Fiscal policy ..................................................................................................................... 10 Monetary policy ............................................................................................................... 11 Exchange rate policy ........................................................................................................ 12 Other crisis management policies ........................................................................................ 13 The role of IMF ................................................................................................................ 13 Prevention issues ................................................................................................................. 14 Conclusion ........................................................................................................................... 17 2 Introduction The problem of currency crises has been an issue since the introduction of money in national economies. With globalization of financial markets the frequency of crises and their impact on the real economy dramatically increased. This raised interest in crisis prevention and overcoming its consequences. The latest advances of economic theory give a better understanding of crisis mechanism and provide better tools for prevention and post-crisis stabilization. The availability of modern techniques in dealing with crises puts a greater responsibility on the government's shoulders. However, the literature on currency crises is huge, and this review summarizes the main recommendations for pursuing various government policies. This paper aims to show basic relations between macroeconomic variables that cause crises and those variables that governments can control by adopting proper policies. Firstly, we define the crisis as an extreme point of instability. We further underline the relevance of official intervention in order to preserve stability. Following that, we discuss what forms official policy responses took in recent Asian crises, and summarize what advantages and disadvantages official measures may have. Next, we turn to the problem of preventing crises, and conclude by stressing importance of maintaining healthy financial system and macroeconomic conditions. Definitions and the role of government First of all, there is no commonly accepted definition of financial instability. Obviously, it’s a lack of financial stability, which usually implies, according to A. Crockett (1997), two principal features: key institutions are stable, that is meet their contractual obligations key markets are stable, that is prices reflect fundamental forces driving them There is a couple of problems with this definition. First, it’s not clear what institutions are key ones, and what are not. Second, price stability is not equivalent to market stability, so there is no good measure for the latter. Moreover, it is difficult to distinguish between inability of institutions to meet obligations leading to problems for the whole market system and healthy failures of institutions, which are necessary for functioning of this system. Similarly, it is not simple to determine a degree of price instability that could be considered to be a threshold value between healthy price flexibility (again necessary for the functioning of the markets) and market instability. 3 Because of these problems another, rather ‘functional’ definition of a crisis is accepted. According to it, absence of financial stability (crisis) causes wide economic damage. Already from this property it is obvious that one should worry about crises, as it is necessary to minimize economic damage caused by them. This is where there can be scope for government activities in overcoming consequences of crises. Moreover, it certainly makes sense to try to prevent crises, as long as prevention measures do not hinder growth potential. There are some reasons why official intervention is not only possible, but also necessary for crisis management. First of all, financial and asset markets have broad linkages to saving and investment decisions, so instability on these markets has greater potential impact on the economy in general, than instability on markets for goods and services. Second, there are some immanent characteristics of financial institutions that make them vulnerable to crises: losses are exacerbated due to bank runs, so government can protect potentially solvent institutions and provide pooled monitoring (because of the economies of scale) there is high probability of contagion and spillover, so financial stability can be considered to be a public good which only government can provide efficiently Third, there are following major types of costs of financial instability: budgetary costs to protect depositors and bail out institutions, in other words costs of resolving a crisis widespread macroeconomic consequences, eventually leading to GDP growth reduction loss of confidence raises problems of asymmetric information (moral hazard and adverse selection) Therefore relevance of government intervention for preserving stability of financial institutions is widely accepted. The situation around preserving stability of financial markets is not so clear. Markets also have instability bias in a sense that any disturbance causes moves in the same direction. The costs of instability of markets include difficulties to formulate macroeconomic policy, as it is not clear whether a change in a market situation will not bring about obsolescence of current policy undermining the stability of financial institutions real economic costs if measures to fight crisis are taken 4 So, there is no strong reason for direct regulation of markets, as long as government can concentrate on institutions in order to correct market failures. In general, however, official intervention in dealing with crises is desirable. Let’s consider how a crisis can occur even in presence of such an intervention. 5 Propagation of crisis In the framework of asymmetric information (analyzed by F. Mishkin (1997)) all crises have four basic reasons: 1. 2. 3. 4. Increases in interest rates. Deterioration of bank balance sheets. Negative shocks to non-bank balance sheets as stock market declines. Increase in uncertainty. All these factors are interrelated and can cause each other. For example, an increase in interest rates leads to deterioration of balance sheets for both banks (because of maturity mismatch the value of assets is lowered more than the value of liabilities) and non-banks (credit servicing becomes more expensive). Deterioration of non-bank balance sheets also leads to deterioration of bank balance sheets, as non-bank firms are less likely to repay their loans. The most important thing, however, is that all the four factors worsen the problems of moral hazard and adverse selection. In an emerging-market country that leads to a currency crisis, as speculators realize that defense of domestic country is too costly for the central bank (it can raise the interest rate, but danger of being involved in a vicious circle is very high). A crisis is associated with substantial depreciation or devaluation of the domestic currency. This, taking into account short duration of debt, large foreign currency denominated debt, and lack of inflation-fighting credibility leads to a large-scale financial crisis (Mexico 1994, East Asia 1997, Russia 1998). Interest rate can be raised once more to fight inflation, that deteriorates balance sheets more, and vicious circle appears once again. Apart from devaluation, decline in economic activity caused by moral hazard and adverse selection problems makes paying-off debts less likely, thus worsening banking crisis in both industrialized and emerging-market countries. This leads to further worsening of problems connected with asymmetric information, and suppresses economic activity more. The aftermath of a crisis consists in sorting out healthy firms from insolvent ones. This reduces uncertainty, stock market recovers, interest rate goes down, so adverse selection and moral hazard become weaker, and the economy gets conditions to grow. On this stage it is very important to provide efficient mechanism of sorting out solvent institutions, as without it there is no reason to overcome the crisis. 6 However, in developed economies, as there are no problems with currency devaluation and high inflation, economic downturn can lead to a decline in prices. Then a phenomenon called ‘debt deflation’ can occur: unanticipated deflation leads to deterioration of firms’ net worth and through it to increasing of moral hazard and adverse selection problems. This, in turn, brings about downturn in economic activity, as it happened in the USA in 1873, 1907, during the Great depression, and in Japan in 90s. So, that’s the way how a crisis evolves in the theoretical framework of asymmetric information. Now let’s see how it happened in reality using the example of East Asian countries. Buildup of the crisis in East Asia Causes Opinions on the causes for the East Asian crisis in 1997 differ, we can, however, identify some agreement between authors (for example: Dornbusch, 1998; BIS 1998; Fischer, 1998) on the following main categories of causes: 1. 2. 3. 4. Financial sector weaknesses and inadequately supervised banking systems Excessive credit growth and over-expansion of the capital stock. The bubble economy. Rigid exchange rate regimes. All the stated causes are complementary. Financial sectors in the East Asian countries were unable to efficiently transform massive inflows of foreign funds in 1995 and 1996. This was combined with weak supervision and improper prudential regulation of financial institutions. In an increased competition banks made risky, uncollateralised loans, kept offshore dollar borrowings unhedged and exposed themselves to maturity mismatches. Following the credit expansion, with foreign funds being channeled into equity investment, stock market values increased and this created asset bubbles. Dowling and Lloyd (2000), also allege increasing inflation as a consequence of capital inflows, partly because of the upward pressures on asset and property prices, but mainly through increased money supply. To this list of causes for the crisis we could also add external influences of changes in international markets (increased competition on export markets, saturation with consumer electronics, drop in price of chips) and some systemic changes, especially in the pattern of financial intermediation with formation of non-bank institutional investors. 7 However clear the case for the currency crisis in East Asia seems now, it was not so prior to the outbreak. Since 1980 these economies have been growing at an average annual growth rates around 8%, while keeping inflation at moderate levels. There was no sign of worsening fundamentals and macroeconomic policies were kept on a prudent course. Budget deficit was broadly balanced and the monetary policies seemed to have been cautious, judging from substantial stability of prices. Except for the widening current account deficit there was no obvious sign of the upcoming events. How come then, did the crisis occur? Crockett (BIS 1998, page 35) argues, that the system of governance in all sectors of Asian economies failed to keep pace with the rapid expansion. In a fast growing business environment with high saving rates, investment strategies encompassed risky projects with low returns, consequently leading to overinvestment. Overinvestment in turn led to conditions of oversupply and the exports started to shrink; additionally the rates of return on investments in new capital were eroding. Moreover, dollar appreciation had negative effects on competitiveness, since real appreciation was transmitted through a pegged exchange rate to Asia. Because of commitments to maintaining exchange rate, monetary policy makers have had less scope to focus on the domestic liquidity requirements and failed to dampen overheating by raising interest rates. Fixed exchange rate policies also gave economic agents a false perception of low exchange rate risk, and as a result they had incentives to take large unhedged exposures in foreign currency. Crisis outbreak The first stage of the crises unfolded in Thailand. Investors confidence eroded mainly because of the large and growing current account deficit (8% in 1996). Even though there were no apparent fundamental problems (negligible inflation and conservative fiscal policy with budget surpluses), except for a moderate appreciation over previous few years, the fact that Thailand was vulnerable was enough to face currency attacks and capital flow reversals. As Dornbusch (1998) argues, this vulnerability emerges from the combination of a weak banking system, dollar debts held by its clients, short term structure of debt and lack of transparency with a pervasive overlay of corruption. On the 2nd July 1997 the Thai baht was let to float. Even though the monetary policy was tightened and interest rates were raised significantly the baht continued its downward path and lost 45% of its value against the dollar, by the end of 1997. Current account deficit narrowed to 2% of GDP in 1997, mainly due to collapse of domestic demand and drop in imports. 8 Investors sentiments quickly spread over the region, focusing on similar vulnerabilities as in the case of Thailand. The Philippines, Indonesia and Malaysia as well as Taiwan, faced strong pressures and the governments first widened exchange rate bands, but had to let the currencies float by October 1997. Policy responses First and direct response to currency attacks in the Asian countries was the adoption of the floating exchange rate regime, followed by tightening of monetary policy. Moreover, fiscal restraints were imposed to tackle with the budget imbalances, but fiscal stances were eased after the depth of the crisis became clearer. Crockett (BIS 1998, page 135) also argues that the degree to which interest rate were raised was not enough to counter attacks. In addition the rates were allowed to fall back after the immediate pressures had subsided. This kind of wavering monetary policy leads to high dependence on heavy intervention. Financial response to crisis included official liquidity assistance in the form of IMF standby credits and substantial additional multilateral and bilateral assistance. These packages aimed at restoring investors confidence, but this can only be achieved if financial packages are combined with credible policy measures, which was not the case at the outset of stabilization in Asia. At the core of the South-East Asian crisis was a fragile financial sector and other structural weaknesses and this was the reason that adjustment programs also included institutional and structural reforms, mainly of the banking sector, but also of enterprises. Meanwhile in the case of Latin America the conventional policy mix – tight monetary and fiscal policy worked well, it was not so in East Asia. The difference is mainly due to the reason, that Latin-American countries have been running lax fiscal policy prior to the crisis, whereas Asia had maintained conservative fiscal policies, hence it did not have so much scope for fiscal maneuvering. 9 The roles of consequences macroeconomic policies in overcoming the Because of the high costs of currency crises per se, and costly stabilization policies, the prevention is important and should not be substituted by "fire fighting". On the brim of the currency collapse, however, different macroeconomic policies should be carefully considered in the context of the nature of crisis and the nature of economy. Every adopted measure will namely have both positive and negative effects in the stabilization, depending on the specific relations between macroeconomic and microeconomic variables in the economy. In what follows we will discus the theoretical framework of macroeconomic policies and relate it to the case of East-Asian crisis. Fiscal policy Conventional economic theory prescribes tightening of fiscal policy after the crisis hits the country. Lower government spending accounts for a fiscal adjustment that would cover the carrying costs of financial sector restructuring and helps restore a sustainable balance of payments. One strong argument in favor of tight fiscal policy is, as Fischer (1998) argues, limited access to borrowing in turbulent times. Another argument for fiscal prudence is prevention of subsequent crises. Namely, with a budget surplus or low deficit the probability of speculative attacks is lower. It is however not excluded, as a recent experience in Asia shows. On the other hand, one could argue that tighter fiscal policy will further depress aggregate domestic demand and expectations, and increase the cost in terms of drop in output growth. Even more worrying is deterioration of infrastructure that could result from tight fiscal policy. This would in turn constrain the export sector, which will be the main motor of growth in the period after stabilization. This consideration was particularly important for the Asian economies. Since they were already running balanced fiscal policies, they did not have much room for tightening. In addition, the role of government in provision of infrastructure and promotion of exports was big in these countries. Big budget cuts in these circumstances were not considered a solution. 10 Monetary policy Higher interest rate should act as an incentive for increased holdings of home currency denominated assets, thereby countering speculative pressures. That is the most obvious reason why tight monetary policy should be adopted. In times of plummeting value of currencies and previously low foreign reserves it is important to restore confidence in the currency. As Fisher (1998) argues, the lessons of the "tequila crisis" as well as of those in Brazil, Hong Kong and the Czech Republic show that a timely and forceful tightening of monetary policy combined with other supporting measures can successfully fend off speculative attacks. Crockett (BIS 1998, page 137) underlines the importance of expectations in limiting currency depreciation by tightening interest rates. He claims that only substantial increases in interest rates can support the currency under attack. Investors faced with moderate increases in interest rate expect further upward movement, and delay moving into assets denominated in domestic currency until the interest rate has reached a subjective peak value. In this line, if the initial rise in interest rate is not high enough, this creates unfavorable expectations and the government loses credibility. Other side of the coin, tightening of interest rates will worsen the situation of the already weak banks and corporations through credit contraction and increase in the debt servicing burden. That way tightening monetary policy could depress aggregate demand and expectation. Apart from direct effect of interest rate on credit availability, there are also other mechanisms at work. An example of one is what happened in East Asian currency crisis. After tightening monetary policy, higher interest rate (through discount factor) resulted in property and other assets price decreases, and this decrease was even furthered when speculators were selling their assets to repay the costly debt. As a result the value of collateral dropped, hence accentuated credit contraction. Despite these ambiguous effects of monetary policy on the economy, the prevailing opinion is that the confidence in the currency and stabilization are crucial factors in overcoming the currency crisis and therefore the monetary policy should be tightened. 11 Exchange rate policy Once again there are different views on how to lead exchange rate policy. The most extreme is not to fight currency attacks at all, but let the rate flow from the beginning. Dornbusch (1998) argues that the central bank has no chance of succeeding in fighting off speculators. Because of limited reserves, and adverse effects of high interest rates on the economy, combined with political considerations, finally the government fill have to devalue the currency or let it float. And this drop will have to be larger the more depleted reserves are and the higher the external debt is. In other words, the longer the government postpones adoption of floating exchange rate regime. Conventional economic theory predicts that devaluation or depreciation in countries highly reliant on trade will generally result in an expansion of output through stimulation of export and import competing industries, particularly if inflation is relatively low. In addition, purely flexible exchange rate will lead to continuous adjustment to relative price movements and will thereby release speculative attacks and price bubbles. Besides these, additional argument for flexible exchange rate in times of crisis is that it provides a clear signal of the effects of government policies; an issue which is important for restoration of investor confidence. Adoption of flexible exchange rate in times of volatile movements and inflationary pressures can also have adverse effects on the economy. The level of uncertainty that economic agents face is higher and enterprises are reluctant to make long run commitments. In addition, deep currency depreciation is particularly undesirable in the economies where corporations or the governments hold substantial foreign currency denominated debts (as for example East Asian corporations) as this would significantly increase their debt servicing burden. Not least, exchange rate depreciation can translate into inflation and further into inflationary expectations. In the case of Asian crisis a lack of responsiveness of output growth to currency depreciation was observed. Crockett (BIS 1998, page 44-48) gives results of empirical studies on output growth projections and movements of real effective exchange rate. It turns out, that in reality exchange rate depreciation and the level of activity often reveal a contractionary effect. Despite high openness to trade this was the case for East-Asian countries. As possible explanations for this fact Crockett identifies several reasons: 1. Importance of intraregional trade: because the depression in the whole region there was a sharp drop in demand for intermediate and final products. 12 2. Exchange rate uncertainty: enterprises do not want to make a long run commitments; resulting in coordination failures, increase in production uncertainty and drop in investment demand. 3. Financial fragility: due to high levels of debt denominated in foreign currency, enterprises were facing increased costs of debt servicing. This was further aggravated by banks curtailing credits. Other crisis management policies Obviously implementing tight monetary and fiscal policy with a more flexible exchange rate regime is not enough, especially in cases like East Asian. Besides ambiguous effects on economy, these policies do not do away the causes of crises. They must therefore be combined with reforms in trade policies, in the area of foreign direct investment incentives, in changed of the role of the government in economy and the reform of financial markets. As the experience in Asian crisis shows, financial intermediation and capital markets played the key role in crisis propagation. This is also true in theory in the framework of asymmetric information (analyzed by F. Mishkin (1997)), which was already mentioned. Of the four basic reasons that Mishkin identifies, deterioration of bank balance sheets and negative shocks to non-bank balance sheets as stock market declines, are directly related to financial intermediation as well as capital markets. Increase in uncertainty and increases in interest rates are again related to this issue – markets are highly sensitive to uncertainty, and interest rate enters discount factor. Therefore regulation of financial markets should be put high on authorities agendas. In this context tight controls and transparency with higher standards of disclosure are required. This will decrease the level of uncertainty and vulnerability of the financial systems. In the stabilization period financial markets regulation will speed up investors confidence restoration. The role of IMF A subject to many debates in the context of currency crises, it seems that the IMF does play an important role in the post crisis stabilization. . Its role is primarily in the provision of loans and restoration of investors confidence. As proponents of the IMF claim, its role is also in the expertise that it can offer (Fischer, 1998). Without being cynical, we claim, that it is more about the international resources that it helps to mobilize and the credibility that it brings about. As Dornbusch says: "It's not over till the fat lady sings." (Dornbusch, 1998, page 8), meaning by that, that the stabilization is not to be expected before IMF is "called in" and its 13 traditional program is implemented. It consists of budget balancing, flexibilization of the currency, banking sector reform and monetary program. Experience in many crises, but especially in the case of "tequila" and Asian currency collapse , show, that this is true, as it is a strong support to government credibility and investors confidence build-up. Prevention issues We presented the main ways of fighting crises, but it’s obviously better to prevent them. Government can use a number of policies to achieve this goal, and we shall discuss them one by one. First, it is not even arguable that fiscal policy should be tight, as it lowers probability of a speculative attack. Moreover, though it depresses economic activity in the short run, it does not undermine growth potential in the long run. So running a balanced budget is a preferable strategy for crisis prevention, as far as fiscal policy is concerned. The empirical evidence from Asia-pacific countries over the period 1980-1994 (Moreno 1995) supports the view that larger budget deficit is associated with speculative attacks, and also with depreciation. However, the Asia in 1997 shows that tight fiscal policy does not insure countries against currency crises, but rather reduces their probability, other things being equal. As far as monetary policy is concerned, the classical recommendation is once again tight policy, and namely (Herrero 2001) monetary targeting. But it is very hard to pursue in emerging economies as monetary-inflation relation in these countries is not stable. Instead inflation targeting may be used that includes announcement of medium-term numerical targets for inflation with commitment. The big advantage of such policy is its transparency to public, and in this sense it can substitute pegged exchange rate. On the other hand, the credibility problem arises if the inflation target is not hit. This is more likely to happen with higher inflation, as it is more difficult just to predict inflation rate correctly in such circumstances. The empirical evidence from the mentioned sample suggests that speculative attacks are positively correlated with growth in Central bank domestic credit, and depreciation may result from faster money growth. A stochastic model of currency crisis with misaligned central parity (Corrado, Holly 2000) also predicts a speculative attack for big enough increase in domestic credit. However, tight monetary policy and associated with it high interest rates may lead to worsening of moral hazard and adverse selection problems, and ultimately to provoke a crisis. So, the difficult task is to keep interest rate high enough to 14 prevent ‘running’ from the domestic currency and low enough to prevent big troubles arising from asymmetric information problems. The choice of exchange rate policy is not so straightforward. One should be aware of many dangers the fixed exchange rate poses. Apart from loss of monetary policy independence, it provides automatic transmission of shocks from the anchor country. Moreover, pegged exchange rate encourages capital inflows, as it creates a false sense of security (no risk of depreciation of the domestic currency). In case of negative market situation the defense of the peg leads to high interest rates and – with very high probability – to a currency crisis. Developed countries, however, can even gain from such kind of a crisis, as they usually do not have large foreign currency denominated debt, and devaluation increases their competitiveness. Indeed, the United Kingdom after crisis in 1992 experienced economic revival, caused by devaluation. This is obviously not the case with emerging market countries, as large foreign currency denominated debt brings about sharp deterioration of net worth of financial and non-financial institutions. That leads to riskier behavior and moral hazard. Firms have less collateral, therefore they can get less credit. All these factors accompanied by renewed inflation expectations and raised burden of foreign debt lead to slowdown of economic growth. Fixed exchange rate or crawling peg is particularly dangerous if the banking system is fragile, debt contracts are of short duration, and foreign debt is large. In such circumstances (common for emerging markets) devaluation leads to a full-fledged financial crisis. Loss of confidence in Central Bank in this case leads to further rise of interest rates and slowdown of economic activity (vicious circle). So, in order to prevent crises fixed exchange rate policy should be avoided, especially if the situation is similar to described above. It can be probably substituted by inflation targeting. At the same time, if inflation is very high, pegged rate is probably unavoidable, and gains from overcoming inflation exceed expected costs of currency crisis. But even in such situation fixed rate should be used only as a temporary measure to fight inflation. The free floating is preferable for crisis prevention, since flexible rate makes it clear to firms that there is a risk involved in issuing liabilities in foreign currency. Moreover, it provides early warning signals to policymakers. But it does not eliminate the possibility of a crisis to occur, and it does not help to fight with inflation, so that usually only developed countries can allow it. It is well known that capital inflows may provoke currency crisis if the flow is suddenly reversed or even just stopped. One possible way to fight with it is by means of monetary policy, namely by sterilization. But it leads to an increase of interest rates that stimulates 15 capital inflows even more and results in the vicious circle with moral hazard and adverse selection problems already discussed. So, there is an alternative way to regulate capital inflows, and that is capital controls. Capital controls are measures taken by the government to prevent capital from flowing into the country by constructing some barriers for its mobility. It can be very useful in attaining a desired structure of capital inflows, namely long term inflows are usually welcomed. Capital controls helped Malaysia in 1997 to reduce its short-term borrowing. Still, they also may worsen the allocation of resources and dampen economic growth, failing to help to prevent devaluation, as it happened to Venezuela in 1994. So, capital controls should in general be only temporary (when the threat of a crisis is significant) and not influence direct investment, since the latter are considered to be irreversible. Problems with direct investment, in turn, usually stem from worsening investment climate rather than from inappropriate monetary policy. Since capital controls are costly in terms of efficiency losses, they can be substituted by tightening of monetary policy. It is possible to do without big negative consequences if there is a well-functioning money market and floating exchange rate regime, allowing appreciation. The other substitution is the tightening of fiscal policy that leads to decrease in domestic demand and increase in savings. One of the most important tasks of currency crisis prevention is the maintaining of a healthy banking system. It is accepted in literature (Crockett 1997, Mishkin 1997, Herrero 2001), that liberalization of financial system should be carried out only together with strengthening the regulation and supervision. Strong bank regulatory/supervisory system should include: adequate resources available accounting and disclosure requirements prompt corrective action (stop and punish) independence of political process supervisors accountable Moreover, liberalization should be pursued gradually in order to keep a lending boom (and arising from it moral hazard problem that raises probability of crisis) at hand. There are also some remedies for vulnerability of financial system in general. One is reliance on market forces that leads to more prudent behavior, as there is no moral hazard of official intervention. But such policy lacks credibility as there is always some political pressure that makes government to act as a lender-of-last resort. Moreover, full reliance on market forces 16 depresses economic activity, as banks have to keep too much reserves taking into account risk of unexpected political, economic event or a natural disaster. The other remedy is two kinds of safety nets, namely deposit insurance and lender-of–last resort role of Central Bank. Both increase confidence in financial institutions, thus lowering the probability of bank runs. But deposit insurance eliminates market discipline, as depositors don’t look for less risky banks. To avoid this moral hazard problem, deposit insurance schemes should be explicitly defined in law, adequately funded, and premiums should be charged independently according to the risk of any given bank. Lender-of-last resort function of Central Bank consists in lending freely during the panics at a penalty rate. It should be provided not only for banks, but for all other institutions as well. But it also endangered by moral hazard, as banks are in a sense insured against liquidity problems during crises, especially big ones, raising the problem of ‘too big to fail’. So, there is a trade-off between cost of moral hazard and benefit of preventing crises, that is why lender-of-last resort function should be used very infrequently, but very quickly. Finally, empirical evidence supports the view that if output is sluggish, inflation is relatively high, or the current account is unbalanced, it is costly to defend the exchange rate, and that triggers speculative pressures. It’s natural to conclude that the policy mix chosen to prevent currency crises depends greatly on the circumstances in which these policies are implemented. There is no uniform approach, moreover, macroeconomic conditions rather than macroeconomic policy usually contributes to evolving of crises. So, prevention policy should be first of all aimed at establishing healthy macroeconomic environment in general, and healthy financial system in particular. Conclusion In this paper we showed that it is important to prevent currency crises because of the high costs they impose in terms of potential growth reduction. The nature and propagation mechanisms of currency crises point out the relevance of government intervention in crisis management. The experience of the East Asian crisis shows that the adoption of the classical mix of macroeconomic policies is not sufficient to restore investors’ confidence, as it doesn’t eliminate its real causes. We argue that financial sector weaknesses typically play the key role in crisis propagation, therefore, reforms of financial sector should be put high on authorities’ agendas. The failure to prevent crisis usually also stems from the weakness of financial system, that is why we reach the conclusion that proper measures for prevention and management of crises are basically the same. 17 REFERENCE: 1. Corrado L., Holly S. A currency crisis model with a misaligned central parity: a stochastic analysis. Economics Letters 67 (2000) 2. Crockett A.: Why Is Financial Stability a Goal of Public Policy, Maintaining Financial Stability in a Global Economy, The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 1997 3. Dornbusch R.: Asian Crisis Themes, MIT, 1998 4. Dornbusch R. A Primer on Emerging Market Crises. MIT, 2001 5. Dowling M. and Lloyd P.: The Asian Currency and Economic Crisis: Dimensions, Explanation, Outlook and Lessons, Asian Economics Centre, The University of Melbourne, (2000) 6. Fischer S : The Asian Crisis: A View from the IMF, Midwinter Conference of the Bankers' Association for Foreign Trade Washington, D.C., 1998 7. Herrero A. G. Differential Characteristics of Financial Crises in Emerging Economies: Lessons for Crisis Prevention and Crisis Management. European central Bank, 2001. 8. Horvath J.. The May 1997 Currency Crisis in the Czech Republic. Post-Communist Economies, Vol.11, No.3, 1999 9. Mishkin F.: The Causes and Propagation of Financial Instability: Lessons for Policymakers, Maintaining Financial Stability in a Global Economy, The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 1997 10. Moreno R.: Macroeconomic Behavior During Periods of Speculative Pressures or Realignment: Evidence from Pacific Basin Economies, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review, no. 3, 1995 18 11. Rodrik D.: Getting Interventions Right: How South Korea and Taiwan Grew Rich., Economic Policy, No.:____ (1995) 12. Stiglitz J. E. : Some Lessons From the East Asian Miracle, World Bank Research Observer, 1996/11. 13. 68th Annual Report, Bank for International Settlements, Basle 1998 19