ECONOMICS OF RELIGION: THE ROLE OF RELIGION ON ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE A Review of Literature Davood Manzoor, Assistant Professor, Imam Sadiq University ' It will not perhaps surprise people that economists have something to say about the economics of religion, since economists believe they have something to say about everything; what is surprising is that religion has something to say about economics.’ Deirdre N. McCloskey, University of Illinois, Chicago Introduction Can belief in heaven or hell be a competitive advantage for nations? It's not the sort of question that many economists ask. With exceptions like Adam Smith, the giants of economic theory have had little to say on matters of faith. Most of economists have tended to accept the secularization thesis advanced by Max Weber in "The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism,"- as economies become more advanced and as technology progresses, religion will decline as a force. But the wall separating religion and economics is being breached. In the past 5 to 20 years, more and more scholars have been using conventional economic methods to understand the way in which religion relates to the rest of society and to the economy in particular. Douglass North (1971, 1991) has proposed—and a steadily growing body of empirical literature has confirmed—that institutions, more than any other factor, determine economic performance. For a long time, economists were of the opinion that institutions were at best peripheral to economic performance for most of the twentieth century, but the failure of more conventional models to account for economic performance through time has induced many economists to look to more non- traditional explanations of economic performance. In other words, physical capital accumulation, human capital accumulation, and technological change as such only account for a fraction of economic growth through time. Something more elusive must be responsible for the earth-shattering economic growth of the last two and a half centuries. Standing on the shoulders of North, many economists have re-oriented their focus away from the material forces of production and toward the “rules of the economic game” embodied in institutions. Institutions are the formal rules, informal norms, and enforcement mechanisms that comprise the “rules of the game” and determine the incentives to which people respond. Institutions should give people an incentive to produce and exchange which in turn results to “economic success”. It is the incentive structures that determine whether or not an economy will stagnate or succeed, and it is changes in these incentive structures that determine whether or not stagnation or success will persist over time. A country’s institutional constellation has its foundation in the beliefs and ideologies of the polity, beliefs and preferences shape the performance of economies through time. Religions share a body of common ethical propositions that govern human behavior. It is uncontroversial to assert that we are to help those who cannot help themselves, that we are to love our neighbors as ourselves, and that we are to refrain from theft, murder, adultery, covetousness, and false witness. Economic theory teaches us that people do not act in a vacuum. The fundamental lesson of economics is that people respond to incentives, and a change in formal 1 institutions (such as redistributive intervention) necessarily changes the structure of incentives in the long run and may, in fact, work to frustrate the entrepreneurial mechanisms. Theoretical Approaches Regarding the conceptual or theoretical approaches to the connection between religion and economy, there are two causal directions that analysts tend to think about. This work has appeared especially in the literature on the sociology of religion. One important line of research posits that religion (or measures of religiosity) is dependent upon developments in the economic and political aspects of contemporary life. This research suggests that events in an economy—levels and standard of living or governmental market interference—influence such things as attendance at religious services or religious beliefs. The second theoretical approach looks at the connection between religion and economic and social life from the other direction. Religion is thought of as being the independent variable, influencing something about outcome on the economic, political, and social side. For example, Max Weber’s famous theory about capitalism is in that line: Religiosity influences economic performance, and perhaps political institutions. Secularization Hypothesis Going back to the first type of model, in which religion is seen as being dependent on social and economic factors. There are two important sociological theories about how religion responds to these factors. One approach is called the “Secularization Hypothesis.” It’s a part of what is often called “Modernization Theory,” which looks at how the economies of developing countries develop institutional capabilities to alleviate poverty and rationalize markets. The Modernization theory posits that as an economy develops and gets richer, certain societal institutions and features change in a regular way. The "Secularization Hypothesis" applies this theory to religiosity: As economies develop and get richer, people supposedly become less religious. “Less religious” is measured either by participation in organized religion or by certain indicators of religious belief. The “Secularization Hypothesis” is widely held among analysts. Religion Market Model The second important approach in the sociology of religion literature is often called the “Religion Market Model.” It speaks about the way government interacts with religion and influences the extent of participation in religion—or even the extent of religious beliefs. Thus, sometimes the government regulates the market, possibly promoting a monopoly religion or making it difficult for other religions to flourish. Under this theory, the government might make it difficult for people to practice their religion by going to services. On the other hand, it might subsidize religious activity. Yet, in one way or another, the government will be influencing the amount of formal religious activity. One example of this influence is the establishment of an official religion in a country. There are, however, different views in the literature about whether such governmental action will promote religiosity or detract from it. The argument that it might detract from religiosity is as follows: If you have an established religion, you tend to have a monopoly, and monopolies tend to function inefficiently. For example, it is thought that a monopoly church— such as the Catholic Church in predominantly Catholic countries or the Anglican Church in England— doesn’t 2 perform efficiently and is not attractive to practitioners. In response, people are thought to participate less. On the other hand, established religion tends to go along with government funding of religious activities. The government might be paying for religious buildings or religious personnel. In this case, one might predict that subsidizing something might result in greater religious participation. In general, this Religion Market Model argues that the way state and church interact is quite central. Extreme examples are communist regimes, including the Soviet Union and China. But many Eastern European countries also tried very hard to eradicate organized religion and apparently had some degree of success. Adam Smith In Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith argued that participation in religious sects could potentially convey two economic advantages to adherents (Anderson 1988). The first could be as a reputational signal: membership in a “good” sect could convey a reduction in risk associated with the particular individual and ultimately improve the efficient allocation of resources. Second, sects could also provide for extra-legal means of establishing trust and sanctioning miscreants in intragroup transactions, again reducing uncertainty and improving efficiency, especially where civil remedies for failure to uphold contracts were weak. A variant of this notion offered by modernization theorists such as Hoselitz (1960), McClelland (1961), and Hagen (1962) is that traditional societies resist change, and innovative groups can be important in the process of modernization. Religious affiliation could serve as the base for group cohesion necessary to successfully challenge established institutions and practices. For example, according to Lal (1998), Buddhism and Jainism played just this sort of role in ancient India. Max Weber In a second line of argumentation, most prominently associated with Max Weber, it is the content of religious belief that is essential. In The Protestant Ethic and the ‘Spirit’ of Capitalism, Weber (1905/2002) contended that the Protestant Reformation was critical to the rise of capitalism through its impact on belief systems. Weber argued that the Calvinist doctrine of predestination and the associated notion of the “calling” were essential for transforming attitudes toward economic activity and wealth accumulation. In John Calvin’s view, individuals were predestined to salvation or damnation, and “good works” were a means of self-assurance and demonstration to others of one’s fate. Each had a “calling,” and the successful completion of this religious mission on a daily basis was pleasing to God and a mark of His blessing. In contrast to Catholicism’s glorification of monasticism (self-denial and active selfrestraint), this conception projected economic activity into the center of religious life and replaced the Catholic cycle of sin, repentance, atonement, and release, followed by more sin. The result was a “this-worldly asceticism,” which focused adherents on diligent, efficient economic activity, thrift, and non-ostentatious accumulation of wealth, which he saw as the bedrock of modern capitalism. This development was not predetermined—Weber was explicit that the development of ideas and institutions congenial to capitalism was endogenous, path-dependent, and not determined by any iron laws of history. Such an extraordinary thesis was sure to attract critics, and it did. Weber stands accused of mischaracterizing Protestant theology, misinterpreting Catholicism, ignoring nonreligious sources of intellectual ferment, misunderstanding the economic antecedents of industrial capitalism, thoroughly confusing the historical 3 record with respect to the rise of capitalism in Catholic and Protestant communities in Western Europe, and even mishandling the statistical data he had at his disposal. Blum and Dudley (2001) provide another version of the Weber thesis, arguing that the Calvinist doctrine of predestination (in contrast to the Catholic practice of ritual penance), in game-theoretic terms, increased the cost of contractual defection (i.e., breaking contracts was a bigger deal for Protestants). This Protestant reluctance to break contracts contributed to greater trust and willingness to honor contracts with strangers and thereby contributed to the spread of more extensive information networks in the Protestant lands of Northern Europe, and it was these network externalities that promoted growth and the rise of industrial capitalism. Arthur Lewis Until recently, economists have paid little attention to this issue; Nobel Laureate W. Arthur Lewis, is one of the few who expressed skepticism that religious beliefs had any significant impact on economic behavior and indeed argued that the causality probably ran the other direction: Despite religion’s claim to be the ultimate primal, changes in economic circumstances spurred theological adaptation (Lewis 1955). In this regard, Lewis, in asserting the primacy of economics over religion, followed the common practice of elevating one’s own scholastic specialty to the primal. Hofstede (1997), a sociologist, also wrote “If we trace the religious histories of countries, we find that the religion a population has embraced seem to have been a result of previously existing cultural value patterns”. This puzzles —how to sort out the pattern of causality among economics, culture, and religious belief—is a central challenge. Robert J. Barro and Rachel M. McCleary The scholars now include Robert J. Barro and Rachel M. McCleary, a husband-andwife team based at Harvard. Professor Barro is a prolific economist who has long been interested in studying how and why economic growth rates differ among countries. Professor McCleary, who directs the Project on Religion, Political Economy, and Society at Harvard's Weatherhead Center for International Affairs, gained an appreciation of the importance of religion in economic life while studying in Guatemala. In order to get a broad cross-country sample of the extent of religiosity, the things they are measuring come from six important international surveys of values and other activities. These were carried out from the early 1980s through 1999. Three of these surveys are waves of the so-called World Value Survey: 1981, 1990, and 1995. The World Value Survey now covers around 50 countries and surveys 1,000 to 2,000 individuals in each country to get an idea of their values in various respects. They use data about attendance at formal religious services in addition to a number of specific religious beliefs. The data they are looking at concern beliefs—related, for example, to an afterlife or whether people believe in heaven/hell. There are some more general questions, such as belief in God, and there are also questions that are more robust across religions: for example, whether or not you consider yourself to be a religious person. There exist these three waves from the World Value Survey, and there are two waves from the International Social Survey program in the 1990s.In a paper published last year in the American Sociological Review, the couple set out to investigate the correlation between variables like church attendance and belief in heaven and hell and comparative economic growth rates from 1965 to 1995. "We thought there might be a 4 positive relationship between certain religious beliefs and economic performance," Professor Barro said. Investigating such a hypothesis can be difficult, in part because different religious systems have starkly different practices when it comes to their mode of participation and belief in the afterlife. But over all, the study confirmed the assumption that greater economic development is associated with less religiosity. In their results, which Dr. McCleary notes are preliminary and need further investigation, the two also reached some counterintuitive conclusions. First, in two countries where religious service attendance is essentially the same, the one whose people have a greater belief in heaven and hell would experience faster economic growth. Second, in two countries where the populations have similar rates of belief in heaven and hell, the one in which church attendance is greater would have slower growth. Why? This "quantitative approach to the study of religion," as Professor McCleary calls it, rests on the assumption that religion can affect economics by fostering beliefs that influence productivity-enhancing traits like thrift, hard work and honesty. A widespread feeling that such behavior may ultimately be rewarded (a belief in heaven), or that a lack of such behavior may be punished (a belief in hell) may therefore spur economic growth. And if more people and resources are devoted to holding religious services without producing the desired output (a higher level of belief), that would tend to lessen productivity in an economy. In other words, countries' economies may perform best when people have relatively higher levels of religious belief than religious participation. Among the nations falling into this category are Japan, South Korea, Singapore and some Scandinavian countries - all of which performed well economically in the period studied. Countries in which belief was low compared with religious participation included India and many in Latin America. Another finding was that belief in hell proved to be a more significant economic factor than belief in heaven. "The stick of punishment may be more powerful compared with the carrot," Professor Barro said. INDEED, while Adam Smith's "Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations" has been the bible for generations of economists, signs indicate that some older sacred texts matter to them as well. In December 2002, when Vernon L. Smith, a pioneer in experimental economics, accepted the Nobel in economic science, he noted that "the strictures against stealing or coveting a neighbor's possessions provide the property-right foundations for markets. And the prohibition against murder, adultery and bearing false witness provide the foundations for cohesive social exchange". Larry Iannaccone Iannaccone, an economics professor at George Mason University who studied at Chicago under Becker and who heads a new academic group, the "Association for the Study of Religion, Economics & Culture" says that while academics ignored religion in part out of a belief that it would fade under the onslaught of secularization we finally figured out that religion remains a very powerful force in contemporary society. While noting that "we need a lot more and better data before we can be confident about the results" of such studies, Professor Iannaccone says economists should pay more attention to the intersection of religion and economics. According to him "It's almost impossible to live in the 21st century and look around and say that religion has no impact anymore". Abundant evidence affirms that religious belief 5 affects a wide range of behavioral outcomes and religious activity can affect economic performance at the level of the individual, group, or nation through at least two channels. Marcus Noland He is a senior fellow at the Institute for International Economics. In his paper (2004)"Religion, Culture, and Economic Performance"he tries to test the hypothesis that religious attitudes affect national economic performance. For some time, economists have been troubled by the fact that the actual growth trajectories of national economies seem to contradict both implications of the model. Romer (1986), Lucas (1988), Robelo (1991), and others launched the endogenous growth literature that sought to explain the first empirical anomaly through various mechanisms that would temper the tendency of declining marginal returns to slow the growth rate of rich economies; Barro (1991), Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992, 1995), and Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992) set off the now vast literature on the determinants of long-run growth across countries. In addition to the accumulation of physical and human capital, attention has focused on indicators of macroeconomic stability, trade openness, political institutions, and geography. Solow (2001) questioned the role of the many right-hand-side variables that have been included in the long-run growth literature and instead argued for focusing on national differences in the level and growth of total factor productivity or TFP across countries as the left-hand-side variable to be explained. The problem, of course, is that empirical estimates of TFP are themselves derived as the residuals from growth-accounting exercises, and can be very sensitive to assumptions about the underlying aggregate production function (Pack 2001) and the measurement of inputs (Hsieh 2002). Setting aside these operational issues, Solow (2001) argues that nontechnological phenomena including “the security of contracts, the intensity of competition, and the respect for instrumental rationality as a mode of behavior” could have a major impact on resource allocation and hence TFP. He has concluded that the theoretical literature on the subject is indeterminate. Empirically, he has found correlations between religious affiliation, the intensity of religious belief, and indicators of cultural tendencies. However, the national cultural measures have no explanatory power with respect to national economic performance once conventional economic fundamentals are taken into account. In contrast, in both cross-country and within-country regressions, the null hypothesis that religious affiliation is uncorrelated with performance can frequently be rejected, though the regressions do not yield a robust pattern of coefficients with respect to particular religions. Some commentators have claimed that Islam is inimical to growth. He has found that in general this is not borne out by the econometric analysis either at the cross-country or within-country level. He has also found that predominately Muslim countries are seldom outliers (either positively or negatively) in the cross-country regressions. In most cases, the coefficient on the Muslim population share is statistically insignificant. With one exception, where it is significant, it is always positive. The only case of a statistically significant negative coefficient is in the sub-national regression for Malaysia. Islam does not appear to be a drag on growth or an anchor on development as alleged. If anything, the opposite appears to be true. If one is concerned about economic performance in predominately Muslim regions or countries, conventional economic analysis may yield greater insight than the sociology of religion. 6 REFERENCES Anderson, Gary M. 1988. “Mr. Smith and the Preachers: The Economics of Religion in the Wealth of Nations,” Journal of Political Economy 96, no. 5: 1066–88. Barro, Robert J. 1991. “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, no. 2: 407–43. Barro, Robert J. 1999. “Determinants of Democracy,” Journal of Political Economy 107, no. 6: S158–83. Barro, Robert J., and Rachel M. McCleary. 2002. “Religion and Political Economy in an International Panel,” NBER Working Paper 8931. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. Barro, Robert J., and Rachel M. McCleary. 2003. “Religion and Economic Growth,” NBER Working Paper 9682. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1992. “Convergence,” Journal of Political Economy 100, no. 2: 223–51. Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1995. Economic Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill. Bhalla, Surjit S. 2002. Imagine There’s No Country: Poverty, Inequality, and Growth in the Era of Globalization. Washington: Institute for International Economics. Blum, Ulrich and Leonard Dudley. 2001. “Religion and Economic Growth: Was Weber Right?” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 11, no. 2: 207–30. Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 2001. “It’s Not Factor Accumulation,” World Bank Economic Review 15, no. 2: 177–219. Gellner, Ernest. 1992. Postmodernism, Reason, and Religion. London: Routledge. Greif, Avner. 1994. “Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individual Societies,” Journal of Political Economy 102, no. 5: 912–50. Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2002. “People’s Opium? Religion and Economic Activities,” NBER Working Paper 9237. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Hofstede, Geert. 2001. Culture’s Consequences: Comparing Values, Behaviors, Institutions, and Organizations Across Nations (second edition). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Hofstede, Geert and Michael Harris Bond. 1988. “The Confucius Connection: From Cultural Roots to Economic Growth,” Organizational Dynamics 16, no. 4: 4–21. Iannaccone, Laurence R. 1998. “Introduction to the Economics of Religion,” Journal of Economic Literature 36, no. 3: 1465–96. Kuran, Timur. 1992. “The Economic System in Contemporary Islamic Thought,” in K.S. Jomo ed., Islamic Economic Alternatives. London: Macmillan. Kuran, Timur. 1993. “The Economic Impact of Islamic Fundamentalism,” in M.E. Marty and R.S. Appleby, eds., Fundamentalisms and the State: Remaking Polities, Economies, and Militance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Kuran, Timur. 1997. “Islam and Underdevelopment: An Old Puzzle Revisited,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 153: 41–71. Kuran, Timur. 2002. “The Islamic Commercial Crisis: Institutional Roots of Economic Underdevelopment in the Middle East,” Los Angeles: USC Center for Law, Economics, and Organization Research Paper No. C01-12. Lal, Deepak. 1998. Unintended Consequences: The Impact of Factor Endowments, Culture, and Politics on Long-Run Economic Performance. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. 7 LaPorta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1997. “Trust in Large Organizations,” American Economic Review 87, no. 2: 333–38. Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. 1992. “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions,” American Economic Review 82, no. 4: 942–63. Lewis, Bernard. 1982. The Muslim Discovery of Europe. New York: W.W. Norton. Lewis, Bernard. 1993. Islam in History (second edition). Chicago: Open Court. Lewis, W. Arthur. 1955. The Theory of Economic Growth. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin. Lucas, Robert E. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics 21, no. 1: 3–42. McClelland, David C. 1961. The Achieving Society. New York: The Free Press. McClelland, David C. 1976. “New Introduction,” in The Achieving Society. New York: Wiley. Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, no. 2: 407–37. Martin, David. 1978. A General Theory of Secularization. New York: Harper and Row. Martin, David. 1999. “The Evangelical Protestant Upsurge and Its Political Implications,” in Peter L. Berger, The Desecularization of the World: Resurgent Religion and World Politics. Grand Rapids, MI: William B. Eerdmans Publishing Company. Metcalf, Barbara D. 1999. “Weber and Islamic Reform,” in Toby E. Huff and Wolfgang Schluchter eds., Max Weber and Islam. London: Transaction Publishers. Pack, Howard. 1994. “Endogenous Growth Theory: Intellectual Appeal and Empirical Shortcomings,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, no. 1: 55–72. Pack, Howard. 2001. “Technological Change and Growth in East Asia: Macro versus Micro Perspectives,” in Joseph E. Stiglitz and Shahid Yusuf, eds., Rethinking the East Asian Miracle. New York: Oxford University Press. Robelo, Sergio. 1991. “Long-run Policy analysis and Long-run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 99, no. 3: 500–21. Rodinson, Maxime. 1973. Islam and Capitalism. New York: Pantheon Books. Rodrik, Dani. 1999. “The New Global Economy and Developing Countries: Making Openness Work,” Policy Essay No. 24. Washington: Overseas Development Council. Romer, Paul M. 1986. “Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 94, no. 5: 1002–37. Solow, Robert M. 2001. “Applying Growth Theory across Countries,” World Bank Economic Review 15, no. 2: 283–88. Turner, Bryan S. 1974. Weber and Islam: A Critical Study. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. Verweij, Johan, Peter Ester, and Rein Nauta. 1997. “Secularization as an Economic and Cultural Phenomenon,” Journal of the Scientific Study of Religion. 36:2 309-24. Weber, Max. 1905/2002. The Protestant Ethic and the “Spirit” of Capitalism and Other Writings, New York: Penguin Books. 8