Productivity and Proximity Don J. Webber1 and Paul White2 1 Department of Economics, Auckland University of Technology, New Zealand 2 Department of Statistics, University of the West of England, Bristol, UK Labour productivity is known to be higher in the presence of agglomeration economies. This paper presents an analysis of the shape of the relationship between labour productivity and the distance between the firm and the region’s central business district. Based on plant-level data across England our empirical estimates indicate that this relationship is non-linear. Keywords: Labour productivity; Distance; CBD. JEL classifications: C21; R32 Acknowledgements: This work contains statistical data from the Office for National Statistics which is Crown copyright and reproduced with the permission of the controller of HMSO and Queen’s Printer for Scotland. The use of the ONS statistical data in this work does not imply the endorsement of the ONS in relation to the interpretation or analysis of the statistical data. This work uses research datasets which may not exactly reproduce National Statistics aggregates. Any errors are the authors’ responsibility. 1 1. Introduction Empirical analyses of within country spatial labour productivity variations typically focus on either agglomeration economies present within and between conurbations, or the variation in and evolution of average labour productivity at an aggregate geographical level, such as the county, state or prefecture. This may be due to a chosen focus on administrative regions or restrictive availability of data at a more disaggregated level. Both of these approaches avoid the explicit calibration of the tradeoff between labour productivity and distance from the core of the market, and the importance of this relationship has been alluded to in the theoretical contributions of Hoover (1937), Smithies (1941), Anderson et al (1989), Hsu (2006) and many others who emphasise the important of location. Evidence of such a trade-off, essentially linking productivity to proximity, has repercussions for economic theory (Bivand, 2008). For instance, theories of monopolistic competition often cite space as an insulating factor that allows spatially segregated firms to charge higher prices. The frequently cited example is the petrol/gas station where greater distances 2 between forecourts mean drivers often pay higher petrol/gas prices in rural areas rather than paying the additional cost of travelling to a cheaper forecourt. As such spatially segregated firms typically produce low quantities but charge high prices it may appear that their marginal productivity is high. This points to the possibility of a U-shaped relationship between productivity and proximity. Nevertheless the ability of a range of firms to compete on price in a region’s core city’s central business district (CBD) reduces with greater transportation costs, which suggests the presence of a negative relationship as value added per worker would be squeezed to compensate for transportation costs. These relationships could have changed over time (Glaeser and Kohlhase, 2004) but the death of the importance of distance may well be premature (Reitveld and Vickerman, 2004). Although area based studies, such as Harris (1954), Clarke et al. (1969), Keeble et al. (1982) and Overman et al. (2003), often examine market-potential by weighting purchasing-power by transportation costs, few studies consider the microeconomic foundations of productivity for geographically defined economies. Despite generalisations there is a lack of 3 evidence supporting the presence of a productivity-proximity trade-off at the plant-level. This paper fills this gap in the literature by presenting an empirical investigation into the influence of distance on labour productivity. We employ data for 16,410 plants within England which we match at the district level to data relating to the distance between the district and the region’s core city’s CBD. 2. Model Plant-level data for labour productivity is modelled below using OLS regression. Potential explanatory variables include the number of workers, capital stock per worker, distance to the CBD and a dummy variable to indicate plant status. Here ‘plant status’ refers to whether there is more than one plant within an establishment (firm). For instance, plants can be location-specific outlets for identical goods produced by the establishment (e.g. different outlets of a supermarket chain) or plants could specialise in a different stage of the production process within an establishment (e.g. where a firm’s R&D/product design takes place in one plant and its product 4 manufacture occurs in another plant). If the plant status is equal to 0, then there is only one plant within the establishment; if the plant status is equal to 1, then there is more than one plant within the establishment and this could be associated with either scale or diseconomies of scale, which again would depend on the nature of the establishment. The modelling strategy is to extend the regression model by including a quadratic term for the distance to the region’s CBD, and to further extend it by including a cubic term for the distance to the region’s CBD. The inclusion of the quadratic and cubic terms has the potential to induce a high degree of undesirable correlation between explanatory variables. For this reason we isolate the unique quadratic and cubic effects using an orthogonal quadratic and orthogonal cubic term using the GramSchmidt orthogonalisation process (see Draper and Smith, 1981). The model is further extended through the inclusion of interaction terms between the multi-plant dummy variable and all other explanatory variables so as to ascertain whether the rate of change of labour productivity varies differentially with the explanatory variables according to plant status. 5 3. Data Analyzing business performance at the plant-level overcomes the shortcomings of working with aggregate data, in particular by providing an unambiguous association between output and the workforce responsible for generating it. In this analysis we use data held by the UK’s Office for National Statistics in their Annual Respondents Database (ARD2) (ONS, 2002), which includes data on the number of employees, gross value added and the amount of capital stock which relates to individual business units. Data on firm-specific capital stock is obtainable from the ONS and is matched with plant-specific data within the ARD2. Factors affecting labour productivity ultimately act by influencing the operational performance of firms. Our sample is comprised of all firms across all industrial sectors of England, and is therefore of interest to policy makers associated with infrastructure and local economic development.1 The district in which the plant is located is identifiable from the ARD2. For simplicity, UK districts are sub-divisions of counties, and 1 An analysis that disaggregates by sector could be carried out if the policy maker were only interested in firms from that specific sector. 6 counties are subdivisions of regions – the UK has 9 administrative regions. We calculate the distance between each plant’s district location and the region’s core city’s CBD. Distance data is sourced separately from the AA website (www.theAA.com). Essentially this distance reflects the level of past infrastructural investments and is responsive to long term policy initiatives to improve transport infrastructure. The longer the period of time it takes to move goods to the location of consumption or intermediate productive use then the greater will be the incurred transportation costs and the less competitive the firm will be in the region’s core market place. Table 1 provides mean and median values for labour productivity and for all potential explanatory variables. The average distance from a plant’s district to a region’s core city’s CBD is 34 miles, but this distance varies from zero (where the plant is located in the region’s core city’s CBD) to 195 (where the plant is located in the Isles of Scilly). {Table 1 about here} 7 4. Results Table 2 summarises the regression models without consideration of interaction terms involving plant status. In Model 1a there is a statistically significant average increase in (the logarithm of) labour productivity with labour productivity increasing by a factor of 1.06 for multi-plant organisations compared with single-plant organisations (p<0.001). In regression Model 1a a doubling of capital stock per worker is associated with labour productivity increasing by a factor of 1.2 (p<0.001). Also note that there is evidence of decreasing returns to scale from the employment variable. These effects are essentially constant irrespective of whether quadratic or cubic terms for the Euclidean distance to the CBD are included in the model (see Model 1a to 5a, Table 2). {Table 2 about here} In the fitted model (Model 1a, Table 2) there is a statistically significant negative linear association between distance and labour 8 productivity (p<0.001), with a ten mile decrease in distance being associated with labour productivity increasing by a factor of 1.03. The square of distance produces an additional statistically significant unique effect (see Model 2a and Model 4a, Table 2) and the same can be seen for the cube of distance (see Model 3a and Model 5a, Table 2). A graphical summary of the cubic model (for single- and multi-plant firms) is given in Figure 1, where this graphic is based on the logarithm of capital stock per worker and the logarithm of employment held at mean values. The graph illustrates that there is neither a simple linear nor a simple quadratic relationship between labour productivity and distance; instead it appears that there is a combination of these two effects suggesting that the relationship between distance and labour productivity is complex. Further it indicates that a simple one-size-fits-all model may be systematically biased and it questions whether scale economies are uniform across locations, as the gap between single- and multi-plants become very small in very peripheral locations. {Figure 1 about here} 9 Table 3 summarises the regression models which include interaction effects with plant status and all other explanatory variables. All models in Table 3 capture a statistically significant interaction between plant status and capital stock per worker on labour productivity with a doubling of capital stock per worker being associated with labour productivity increasing by a factor of 1.19 for single-plant firms and increasing by a factor of 1.24 for multi-plant firms; this difference in effects is statistically significant (p<0.001). Interestingly there is evidence from the interaction between plant status and logarithm of employment that single-plant firms do not suffer from diseconomies of scale and that this is a characteristics of multi-plant firms in general. Nevertheless in all models in Table 3 there is no differential effect between linear (p=0.245), quadratic (p=0.527) and cubic (p=0.614) distance with productivity and plant status. {Table 3 about here} A repercussion of these results is that technological improvements that have facilitated declines in distance costs have not resulted in an 10 eradication of the spatial labour productivity divide across English regions, and therefore are in line with Reitveld and Vickerman (2004). 5. Conclusion Accessibility to the core of the market is known to affect pricing decisions and is embedded in much of the literature on location theory. However most empirical analyses that address spatial variations in labour productivity typically focus on either agglomeration economies or the variation in and evolution of average labour productivity at an aggregate geographical level. This paper presents an empirical investigation which sought to identify the shape of the relationship between labour productivity and the distance to the core of a region’s central business district using plant-level data across England. The results from our regression analyses suggest that a plant’s labour productivity is negatively and non-linearly related to its distance to its region’s core city’s central business district. 11 References Anderson, S. P., de Palma, A. and Thisse, J.-F. 1989. Spatial price policies reconsidered. Journal of Industrial Economics 38(1), 1-18 Bivand, R. 2008. Implementing representations of space in economic geography. Journal of Regional Science 48, 1-27 Clarke, C., Wilson, F. And Bradley, J. (1969) “Industrial location and economic potential in Western Europe”, Regional Studies 3, 197-212 Draper, N. and Smith, H. 1981. Applied regression analysis, John Wiley and Sons, New York Glaeser, E. L. and Kohlhase, J. E. 2004. Cities, regions and the decline of transport costs. Papers in Regional Science 83, 197-228 Harris, C. (1954) “The market as a factor in the localisation of industry in the United States”, Annals of the Association of American Geographers 64, 315-48 Hoover, E. M. 1937. Spatial price discrimination. Review of Economic Studies 4(3), 182191 Hsu, S.-K. 2006. Simple monopoly price theory in a spatial market. Annals of Regional Science 40, 531-544 Keeble, D., Owens, P. L. And Thompson, C. (1982) “Regional accessibility and economic potential in the European Community”, Regional Studies 16, 416-432 Overman, H. G., Redding, S. And Venables, A. J. (2003) “The economic geography of trade, production and income: A survey of empirics” in Handbook of International Trade (eds.) Kwan-Choi, E. And Harrigan, J. Basil Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 353-387 Reitveld, P. and Vickerman, R. 2004. Transport in regional science: The “death of distance” is premature. Papers in Regional Science 83, 229-248 Smithies, A. 1941. Optimal location in spatial competition. Journal of Political Economy 49(3), 423-439 12 Table 1: Descriptive statistics Mean Median Log of labour productivity 3.289 3.342 Log of capital stock per worker 3.297 3.373 Log of employment 3.804 4.025 Distance in miles 34.290 28.000 2 Distance in miles 2111.991 784.000 Distance in miles3 176844 21952 Log of capital stock per worker * multi-plant dummy 1.254 0 Log of employment * multi-plant dummy 1.974 0 Distance in miles * multi-plant dummy 11.649 0 2 Distance in miles * multi-plant dummy 711.675 0 Distance in miles3 * multi-plant dummy 59445.36 0 n=16,410 13 Table 2: Regression Models Distance in miles 1a 0.275** (0.005) -0.015** (0.004) -0.003** (2.35e-04) Distance in miles2 – Distance in miles3 – – Orthogonal distance2 – – – Orthogonal distance3 – – – Log (capital stock per worker) Log (employment) 2a 0.275** (0.005) -0.015** (0.004) -0.004** (0.001) 1.33e-05** (4.55e-06) 3a 0.275** (0.005) -0.015** (0.004) -0.008** (0.001) 9.37e-05** (2.07e-05) -3.66e-07** (9.19e-08) 4a 0.275** (0.005) -0.015** (0.004) -0.003** (2.35e-04) 5a 0.275** (0.005) -0.015** (0.004) -0.003** (2.35-e04) – – – – 1.33e-05** (4.55e-06) 1.34e-05** (4.54e-06) -3.66e-07** (9.19e-08) 0.057** (0.019) 2.517* (0.022) 636.22** (<0.001) 0.189 0.058** 0.058** 0.057** 0.058** (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) 2.513** 2.538** 2.574** 2.515** Constant (0.022) (0.024) (0.025) (0.022) 946.95** 759.61** 636.22** 759.61** F (prob.) (<0.001) (<0.001) (<0.001) (<0.001) R2 0.188 0.188 0.189 0.188 Notes: n=16,410. ** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level. Multi-plant dummy 14 Table 3: Regressions with compound variables Distance in miles 1b 0.257** (0.005) -0.005 (0.005) -0.003** (2.87e-04) Distance in miles2 – Distance in miles3 – – Orthogonal distance2 – – – 1.57e-05** (5.63e-06) Orthogonal distance3 – – – – 0.055** (0.008) -0.031** (0.006) 5.41e-04 (4.66e-04) 0.054** (0.009) -0.032** (0.007) 0.001 (0.001) -5.81e-06 (9.19e-06) 0.053** (0.009) -0.034** (0.007) 0.002 (0.002) -2.81e-05 (4.12e-05) 9.45e-08 (1.87e-07) 0.055** (0.008) -0.031** (0.006) 0.001 (4.66e-04) 1.68e-05** (5.64e-06) -4.16e-07** (1.13e-07) 0.055** (0.008) -0.032** (0.006) 6.14e-04 (4.66e-04) – – – – -8.38e-06 (9.54e-06) 1.18e-07 (1.95e-07) 2.552** (0.023) 386.93** (<0.001) 0.191 Log (capital stock per worker) Log (employment) Log (capital stock per worker) * Multi-plant dummy Log (employment) * Multi-plant dummy Distance in miles * Multi-plant dummy Distance in miles2 * Multi-plant dummy Distance in miles3 * Multi-plant dummy Orthogonal distance2 * Multi-plant dummy Orthogonal distance3 * Multi-plant dummy – 3b 0.257** (0.005) -0.005 (0.005) -0.009** (0.001) 1.06e-04** (2.51e-05) -4.08e-07** (1.11e-07) 4b 0.257** (0.005) -0.005 (0.005) -0.003** (2.87e-04) 5b 0.257** (0.005) -0.005 (0.005) -0.003** (2.87e-04) – – – – – – – – – -6.38e-06 (9.53e-06) – – – – 2.575** (0.025) 481.06** (<0.001) 0.190 2.615** (0.027) 386.90** (<0.001) 0.191 2.550** (0.023) 481.07** (<0.001) 0.190 2.547** (0.023) 639.59** F (prob.) (<0.001) R2 0.189 Notes: see notes on Table 1 Constant 2b 0.257** (0.005) -0.005 (0.005) -0.004** (0.001) 1.55e-05** (5.56e-06) 15 20.0 Single Plant Multi-Plant Labour Productivity 17.5 15.0 12.5 10.0 7.5 5.0 0 40 80 120 160 200 Local Distance Figure 1: Distance and labour productivity 16