Finding an Impact of Preservation Policies: Price Effects of Historic Landmarks on Attached Homes in Chicago 1990-1999 Douglas Noonan Assistant Professor School of Public Policy Georgia Institute of Technology Doug.Noonan@pubpolicy.gatech.edu Draft Copy. Please do not cite without permission. Comments welcome. ABSTRACT: Since the 1960s, historical preservation policies have been used to protect landmarks and neighborhood character, as well as to promote local development. Landmark designation by local governments may have a variety of effects on the value of historical properties and their neighbors. This paper offers new empirical evidence on the effect of landmark designation on property values. Using a hedonic price approach for 70,000 attached home (i.e., condos, townhomes) sales during the 1990s in Chicago, robust estimates suggest that homes in landmark buildings (and landmark districts to a lesser extent) sell at a premium (6 - 15%) over other similar properties. Yet conclusions that historic preservation policies cause this price increase are premature. Using a repeat-sales framework (the subsample of properties that sold multiple times during the 1990s), the effect of landmark designation on appreciation rates can be identified. Given that construction quality and other unobserved property characteristics are likely to be different for landmarks, the repeat-sales approach properly controls for a property's predesignation value. The repeat-sales results suggest that landmark designation in Chicago does not have a positive effect on property values, and may even lead to lower appreciation rates. These results are consistent with the idea that preservation policies have struck a rough balance between competing effects, both positive (e.g., prestige, stability) and negative (e.g., restricted uses). I. Introduction Urban renewal and community development have close and complex relationship with historic preservation. Historic buildings and neighborhoods often find themselves the focus of redevelopment efforts – either as an obstacle or a catalyst. On the one hand, redevelopment and land-use changes may draw the ire of preservationists by transforming historical structures, landscapes, or some “character” of a neighborhood. On the other hand, historic landmarks may be exploited as amenities to foster local redevelopment. In any event, the historic character of the built environment and the extent to which it is preserved are pressing issues in many urban policy debates. “Smart growth” advocates, for instance, commonly recognize the importance of historic preservation. Numerous policy tools directly affect historic preservation efforts. At the federal level, the National Register of Historic Places boasted 76,835 properties in 2003 and adds over 1,000 sites annually. This amounts to over one million historic sites listed in the U.S. (see Swaim 2003, Schuster 2002 for further discussion of the National Register). Federal listing is voluntary and carries no restrictions on private property, but it does make rehabilitation of some (income-producing) properties eligible for a 20% investment tax credit. While the federal listing is largely honorific, especially for owner-occupied residences, state and local historic landmark designations may carry considerably more weight. State and local rules governing historic properties can vary widely. Some localities include financial assistance or restrictions on use for historic property owners, sometimes using the National Register to identify historic properties. In addition, the National Historic Preservation Act of 1966 made provisions for property owners to receive tax deductions for preservation easements on historic properties. An owner of a historic hotel could, for instance, give an easement over the hotel’s façade that would prevent the owner (and all future owners in perpetuity) from modifying its historic character in exchange for a tax deduction equal to the lost value of the property. In the local example considered in this paper, the Commission on Chicago Landmarks has been recommending landmark designation for properties to the City Council since established by ordinance in 1968. In the past 35 years, 4,500 properties in 34 historic districts have been so designated. The Commission in the Landmarks Division of the city’s Department of Planning and Development must review and approve alterations or construction that affects landmarks. They also oversee a variety of financial incentive programs for landmark building owners. Owner-occupied residences are eligible for a 12-year freeze on property taxes and waivers of building permit fees. Other incentives apply to different landmark property types. Background One rationale for historic preservation policies is that markets fail to optimally provide for preservation. A similar argument is often proffered for environmental preservation. If the traditional identity of a neighborhood or community is a public good, competitive markets may underprovide it. More specifically, individual properties may contribute to 1 the historic character of the urban environment, and this historical externality may affect the well-being of others in ways not captured by prices. The owner of the historic hotel may add to the charm of downtown, and certainly to the quality of the view from apartments across the street, yet the owner receives no compensation from those external benefits. Thus, it is argued, policies are needed to preserve those historic characteristics. In practice, though, historic preservation may represent a very hard case for market failure-motivated policy. Typical spillovers cause harms or benefits that are easier for involved parties to conceptualize. Unlike smoke or noise spillovers, where people are generally able to imagine the worlds with and without the externality, historical character may speak to deeper questions of individual and group identity. This might even be construed as cultural or social capital. Someone whose identity or values have been influenced by growing up in the historical area is likely to measure the historical spillover quite differently than an outsider. The possibility that the amount of historical preservation may affect one’s value of historical preservation makes the policy questions of entitlement to unrestricted property use or to neighborhood stability. Historic preservation policies can have several effects on property markets. They are often evident in prices. Restrictions on property use should reduce property values, reflected in lower sale prices. Eligibility for tax deductions and other financial assistance, on the other hand, should increase property values and be reflected in higher sale prices. Landmark designation that confers honorific status may also see that symbolic value captured by higher prices. Preservation policies also provide stability to a neighborhood by limiting change, thereby reducing the investment for other property owners. Frequently, observers cite intangible external benefits to historic designation like signaling “public commitment” to an area (Schaeffer and Millerick 1991), solving market failure in “providing a sense of unity with the past” (Asabere and Huffman 1994b), strengthening the “social fabric” of a community (New York Landmarks Conservancy 1977), and “catalyzing” rehabilitation of nearby areas (Listokin et al. 1998, Coulson and Leichenko 2001). The Literature Which of these effects dominates is an empirical question. The scholarly literature has yielded mixed results on the price effects of historical preservation policies. Leichenko et al. (2001) review empirical works in this area, showing how the “impact of designation on property values” varies across studies and across empirical methods. Several earlier studies (e.g., Scribner 1976, Gale 1991) use a difference-in-difference method to identify price effect of historic designation. This method typically involves comparing sample average property value growth rates in historic and non-historic districts. Many other omitted factors that differ between areas may be relevant and better explain differential growth rates. More recent scholarship has employed hedonic pricing method to assess the implicit price of properties’ attributes, with historic designation being one of those attributes. Examples of this approach (e.g., Schaeffer and Millerick 1991; Asabere and Huffman 1994a, 1994b; Coulson and Leichenko 2001; Clark and Herrin 1997) control for many other features of properties yet also find mixed results. Schaeffer and Millerick (1991) claim that some of the difference in price effects is due to differences in landmark 2 regulation at local and national levels. Leichenko et al. (2001) control for different types of historic designation and conclude that it does matter in some areas, and that price effects generally differ across cities and sources of data. With over 2,000 local historic district commissions and thousands of diverse properties listed on the National Register, one might expect local studies to yield divergent results. Leichenko et al. (2001) find historically designated properties in Texas to have 5 – 20% higher appraised prices than other properties. Coulson and Leichenko (p.118, 2001) find that local “historical designation adds about 17.6% percent to the value of a unit” in Abilene, TX. In Philadelphia, owner-occupied properties located in historic districts listed on the National Register sell at 26% higher prices than other properties sampled by Asabere and Huffman (1994b). Philadelphia condominiums with historic easements, however, sell for about 30% less than comparable properties, and that price is discounted by 4.6% per year after the donation (Asabere and Huffman 1994a). Another interesting question, which the empirical literature has addressed more sparingly to date, is one of externalities from historic preservation. It is hypothesized that historic buildings may have positive (or negative) effects on neighboring properties, and that preserved properties may also have positive external effects beyond the effect that unit’s own price. Coulson and Leichenko (2001) seek to estimate the external impact of historic designation, using a hedonic price method that includes the number of historically designated properties in a unit’s Census tract as an attribute of that unit. They find that each additional historic house in a tract is associated with sales price that is 0.14% higher. Thus, in Abilene, TX where an average tract has 13 historically designated properties, houses sell for 1.8% higher than tracts with no historically designated properties. Other benefits may accrue from historic preservation policies that are not captured by prices. There may be public goods benefits from preservation beyond the impact on properties and nearby properties. Several authors have sought to measure those public goods benefits of historic preservation using stated preference techniques such as contingent valuation (see, e.g., Kling et al. 2004, Chambers et al. 1998). There is a temptation to conclude that higher or lower prices associated with historic landmarks are the consequence of their designation. Without a careful research design, however, this conclusion may be unwarranted. Authors rarely directly confront this issue.1 Historic designation is likely correlated with other (unobserved) characteristics of the property. Higher quality properties, those maintained better, or those in premium locations may be more likely to become designated.2 Moreover, properties in areas ripe for revitalization or in “hot” areas may attract the attention of other landowners and local officials who support landmark status, especially in the case of landmark districts. Thus, buildings in neighborhoods characterized by high or rising prices may also receive landmark designation (possibly against the desires of the owner). If we think that historic designation is assigned deliberately depending on site characteristics and expectations 1 2 Exceptions include Gale (1991) and Schaeffer and Millerick (1991). In theory, designation may “follow the market” (Schaeffer and Millerick 1991). 3 about the future (Coulson and Leichenko 2004), then a selection bias may limit our ability to interpret the results. Does designating an Abilene home as historic cause its price to rise by 18%, or do high priced (and high quality) homes become designated? Caution is called for in interpreting the observed price differential associated with historic buildings. This paper offers more empirical evidence on the relationship between prices and historic designation. The empirical methodology employed here allows for more robust interpretation of the “effect” or “impact” of historical designation. Moreover, unlike previous research, the methods used here account for spatial dependence in the data and improve inferences about the statistical significance of marginal prices of landmark characteristics. This spatial econometric approach informs our understanding of the neighborhood effects historic landmarks. II. Data description The data for this analysis come from several sources. Landmark information comes from the City of Chicago’s Landmarks Division of its Department of Planning and Development (City of Chicago 2004). For the 193 landmarks and 37 landmark districts in the city (including 4,500 properties), information on their date of designation, architect, and year of construction is available. Numerous sources contribute to the geographic data. The U.S. Census Bureau’s TIGER files provide most of the geographic maps used. These were complemented by a map of Chicago’s community areas (Siciliano 2004). The property and sales data come from the Multiple Listing Service (MLS) records of sales of all “attached” residential property sales in the city of Chicago from 1990 – 1999. These attached properties typically include condominiums and townhomes (in contrast with detached single-family housing, or multi-family housing). There are 73,106 attached residential property sales using the MLS in Chicago during the 1990s, which accounts for a large share of all residential property sales in the City. MLS records include information on many property attributes (e.g., address, number of rooms, parking availability, number of bedrooms and baths). The MLS records were sufficient to map 71,893 of these observations, although many of these records are missing valid information. This is especially true for the “year built” and “square footage” variables, unfortunately two of the more important variables. As expected, many of the properties are concentrated downtown, near Lake Michigan, and in other pockets scattered around the city. Perhaps not surprisingly, most of the City’s landmarks are concentrated in similar areas. (See Map 1. Blue indicates a landmark; green indicates the city border; black indicates a property sale.) Missing information for certain key variables in the MLS dataset has been dealt with in the following way. First, the analysis is performed using the subsample of those observations for which no information is missing. Second, the missing values are replaced using the predicted values from an auxiliary regression.3 Third, the analysis is For the “square footage” variable, which is missing 20,210 observations, several auxiliary regressions were run sequentially to construct and estimated square footage variable. The first auxiliary regression included covariates: year built, # units in building, # of rooms, # bedrooms, # baths, master bath dummy, # 3 4 performed without the “year built” variable. Insofar as the results (for the variables of interest) differ substantially across these three different methods of handling missing values, the differences will be so indicated. Even though the MLS data is not of perfect quality, it does have several desirable features. First, it captures actual sales and perceived attribute values of those involved in the transaction. Actual market data are superior to appraisal data in this regard, although sales data reveal prices only for properties actually sold rather than the universe of properties in a city. A selection bias is thus possible.4 Second, the MLS data records have information about a wide range of attributes of the property. This include information about the list and sale price and date, the agent making the sale, the dimensions of various rooms, tax payments, etc. Finally, because the sample covers nearly all sales of attached properties during a 10-year span, many properties were sold multiple times during that period. This allows for a repeat-sale approach.5 fireplaces, basement dummy, garage dummy, parking spot dummy, waterfront dummy, area of living room, area of dining room, area of master bedroom, area of kitchen, year of sale, latitude, longitude, distance from Lake, distance from CBD, distance from nearest park, distance from nearest water body, distance from CTA rail line, estimated block group demographics (population density, income, housing value, percent nonwhite, and year of construction), and some interaction terms. The R 2 for this regression is 0.54. Still, for those observations lacking both “year built” and “square footage,” another auxiliary regression was run to predict “square footage” using the same covariates as the previous regression, except that “year built” was omitted. The R2 for this regression was 0.35. For those 713 observations also missing “# bedrooms,” another auxiliary regression predicted square footage as before, except that “# bedrooms” was omitted. Its R2 = 0.36. Likewise, a fourth auxiliary regression omitted “# units in building” to estimate square footage for 2,775 observations. Its R2 = 0.36. For the “year built” variable, which is missing 39,081 observations, the auxiliary regressions included covariates: square footage, # units in building, # rooms, # bedrooms, # baths, master bath dummy, # fireplaces, basement dummy, garage dummy parking spot dummy, waterfront dummy, area of living room, area of dining room, area of master bedroom, area of kitchen, year of sale, latitude, longitude, distance from Lake, distance from CBD, distance from nearest park, distance from nearest water body, distance from CTA rail line, estimated block group demographics (population density, income, housing value, percent nonwhite, and year of construction), and landmark status. Its R 2 = 0.01, obviously a cause for concern. 4 It is interesting to note that becoming a landmark during the 1990s appears unrelated to the number of times a property has been sold in the 1990s. See the Appendix for the results of the first-stage of the twostage Heckman model to control for the selectivity bias in the repeat-sales sample. The probit in the first stage indicates that many attributes of a property predict whether it will have multiple sales, yet properties that became landmarks during the 1990s appear no more or less likely to have repeat sales. Moreover, properties that were or will be in landmarks, designated at any time, are no more or less likely to have repeat sales. Interestingly, proximity to the nearest landmark is negatively related to being a repeat-sale property, suggesting that landmarks may make nearby neighbors less likely to sell. This may be consistent with the hypothesized stabilizing effect of preservation. 5 Such an approach might be thought of as similar to the difference-in-difference approach previously employed in comparing changes in average sales prices across neighborhoods, except now the we can compare changes in actual sales prices for the same properties. 5 Map 1 6 The variables employed in this analysis are: Table 1: Variables Used Variable Definition log-price ln (real sales price, adjusted to 1 January 2000 $ using Chicago’s housing CPI deflator) log-area ln (area of unit in feet2) floor estimated floor number of unit (e.g., 1st floor, 4th floor) year built-e estimated year unit built (see footnote 3) year built year unit built unitbldg number of units in the building rooms number of rooms in unit bedrooms number of bedrooms baths number of baths master bath master bathroom dummy fireplaces number of fireplaces garage garage dummy parking spot parking spot dummy parking garage or parking spot dummy waterfront waterfront dummy distance to CBD distance to State and Monroe downtown (km) distance to Lake distance to Lake Michigan (km) distance to water distance to nearest river or lake (km) distance to CTA distance to nearest CTA rail line (km) distance to park distance to nearest park (km) latitude decimal degrees north longitude decimal degrees east northside northern half of the city dummy BG-income median household income (in $1000s), block-group, estimated* BG-value median house value (in $1000s), block-group, estimated* BG-density population density (1000s/km2), block-group, estimated* BG-nonwhite percent non-white, block-group, estimated* BG-year built median year built for residences, block-group, estimated* BG-landmarks number of landmarks, block-group, estimated* landmark designated a landmark by 2004 (includes properties in districts) district inside a landmark district designated by 2004 CL-year built year built of closest landmark CL-date designated date (in days) of designation of closest landmark CL-distance distance to closest landmark (km) year year of sale appreciation appreciation rate from first to last sale in 1990s price1 real price (in $1000s) of first sale in 1990s designation designated a landmark between first and last sale in 1990s desig90s designated a landmark any time during the 1990s * These block-group characteristics were estimated for the sale year using a linear interpolation of the 1990 and 2000 Census estimates for each block group. 7 The following table shows the descriptive statistics for the variables used. Table 2: Descriptive Statistics Variable N real price 71885 log-price 71884 log-area 66841 floor 63730 year built-e 59889 year built 32809 unitbldg 68941 rooms 71294 bedrooms 67890 baths 71866 master bath 71893 fireplaces 71893 garage 71893 parking spot 71893 parking 71893 waterfront 71893 distance to CBD 71893 distance to Lake 71893 distance to water 71893 distance to CTA 71893 distance to park 71893 latitude 71893 longitude 71893 northside 71893 BG-income 71891 BG-value 71891 BG-density 71889 BG-nonwhite 71891 BG-year built 71891 BG-landmarks 71891 landmark 71893 district 71893 CL-year built 71893 CL-date designated 71771 CL-distance 71893 year 71891 appreciation 6415 price1 6415 designation 6415 desig90s 71893 mean $178,377.90 11.85 7.05 7.30 1932.39 1941.83 157.35 4.68 1.91 1.53 0.46 0.29 0.35 0.17 0.88 0.07 5.80 1.84 0.79 0.64 0.33 41.93 -87.66 0.91 $47,974.70 $244,206.00 12.27 0.24 1924.52 0.85 0.03 0.03 1967.88 10360.18 0.53 1995.35 0.09 $167,424.80 0.003 0.01 std. dev. 157227.50 0.69 0.46 10.79 160.50 214.72 247.76 1.81 0.80 0.66 0.50 0.50 0.48 0.37 0.32 0.25 4.04 2.81 0.74 0.67 0.28 0.05 0.04 0.29 21103.45 116753.50 8.43 0.19 235.24 1.22 0.17 0.16 376.42 4222.40 0.83 2.82 1.02 137560.30 0.05 0.09 8 III. Empirical Method Hedonic Price Method These data are analyzed using hedonic price models. Hedonic price models are based on the theory that houses are bundled goods – goods with many different attributes – and that the marginal prices for the attributes can be identified by assessing how sale prices vary with bundles’ attributes. This technique is common in urban and environmental economics, where researchers using hedonic analyses to identify the marginal price of changes in location, environmental quality, and other neighborhood characteristics. See Rosen (1974), Freeman (2003), and Cropper et al. (1988) for further discussion of the method. The first-stage of a hedonic analysis is usually all that is estimated. The first-stage hedonic regression estimates the following general model: Pricei = f(Attributesi) + εi (1) where Pricei is the sale price, Attributesi is a vector of attribute of a house, and εi is an error term, all for the ith house. Equation (1) is typically estimated using a regression framework, with specification often following a Box-Cox procedure. Cropper et al. (1988) recommend a semi-log specification as most robust to omitted house attributes. The estimated coefficients for each attribute can be interpreted as a marginal price for that attribute. In the semi-log specification, the coefficient measures the percent change in sale price associated with a marginal change in the attribute. Repeat Sales The Chicago MLS data offer an opportunity to use a repeat-sales framework for the hedonic analysis. This approach has an advantage in that it controls for all time-invariant unobserved or omitted attributes. If sale prices vary between the two different sales of the same property, then attributes that do not vary over time offer no explanation. Consider a semi-log specification of the hedonic price function for a sale of the ith house in period t: ln(Priceit) = βAttributesit + γInvarianti + δLandmarkit + εit (2). The coefficient β indicates the marginal price (in percent terms) of the attribute. Also, γ is the marginal price of the Invarianti variable, representing time-invariant attributes of house i. The Landmarkit variable is another attribute of house i in period t, indicating whether the house is designated as a landmark (=1) or not (=0). Thus, δ is the marginal price of landmark status. Estimating (2) would be limited in its ability to identify the “effect” of landmark status on price if some attributes (time variant or invariant) were correlated with Landmark and omitted. Taking the difference of ln(Priceit) and ln(Priceis), for the sale of the same house in periods t and s, yields: ln(Priceit) – ln(Priceis) = βAttributesit + γInvarianti + δLandmarkit + εit – βAttributesis + γInvarianti + δLandmarkis + εis ln(Priceit/Priceis) = β(ΔAttributesi) + δ(ΔLandmarki) + εit – εis (3). 9 As the time-invariant attributes drop out, the change in ln(Price) is a function of the change in attributes and the change in landmark status. This construction assumes that the marginal attribute price is constant over time. Equation (3) can be easily adjusted to allow for β to vary over time, however. In equation (3), the estimated δ coefficient still represents the marginal price associated with a change in landmark status. By estimating (3) instead of (2), however, δ is no longer subject to bias from omitting Invarianti variables. This applies to observed or unobserved time-invariant variables. This can be an especially important consideration in for historic landmark properties, where a variable of intangible or unobserved property characteristics may explain its different price rather than its mere formal designation. For example, if landmark properties have higher quality construction, have owners who actively maintain them, have special or unique “historic” design features, or have extra prestige associated with them, then a hedonic analysis that omits these difficult-toobserve variables (which are constant over time) will not bias its δ estimate. In other words, historic designation will not be proxying for all of the underlying features that got the property designated in the first. It will better capture the before-and-after price effect of designation. To operationalize equation (3) for repeat-sales that occur at different intervals (t and s), the dependent variable is normalized by the years between sales. This repeat-sales model is then straightforward to estimate: ln(Priceit/Priceis)/(yeart – years) = β(ΔAttributesi) + δ(ΔLandmarki) + θi (4). The dependent variable can now be interpreted as the annualized appreciation rate for property i. The θi error term is estimated using Huber-White robust errors.6 Spatial dependence Before proceeding to estimate the hedonic models, the matter of spatial dependence in the data needs to be addressed. It is common, especially in cities like Chicago, to observe very strong spatial clustering by attributes. Just as Pricei and Attributei are not randomly distributed geographically around the city, neither are the error terms. This can lead to spatial autocorrelation – where the model’s error terms are spatially clustered. As a result, the standard errors of the marginal price estimates in the hedonic models may be biased (typically downward in the case of positive spatial autocorrelation) and inferences may be incorrect. The coefficients remain unbiased, however. This is just one way in which spatial dependence may exist in the data, and it is the one most commonly addressed in recent hedonic research.7 Note, however, that the error structure in equation (3) contained εit – εis , which may not be zero in expectation if equation (2) is based on the full sample of all sales (includes repeat and single sales). To account for this, θi is replaced with an estimate of the inverse Mills ratio (from a probit of whether a sale was a repeat sale or not). Controlling for this selectivity bias does not appear to have substantial effects on the results of interest to this paper. Nonetheless, these results are presented in Table 3 and Table 4. 7 Another form of spatial dependence, often called a “spatial lag”, posits that the dependent variable is endogenous or that sale prices of neighbors affect each other. This sort of contagion effect has been observed in residential property sales (e.g., Ioannides 2003) and can also be modeled. But this approach is beyond the scope of this paper. 6 10 A spatial autoregressive (SAR) model can account for spatial structure of the error term. (See Anselin 2001, 2003 for further discussion.) In this regression model, an N × N weights matrix W is introduced. W describes the “neighborliness” of observations to each other. A common W uses contiguity to define neighbors, assigning a positive value to all observations adjacent to the observation in question and zero to all other observations. Inverse distance matrices are also a common weights matrix, where each element of W is 1/dij and dij is the distance between observations i and j. Given the nature of the sales data (i.e., each observation is a point in space, and many of them are “stacked”), a spatial weight matrix based on distance bands is used. Here, all observations that are within a specified distance to the observation in question are treated as neighbors, and the remainder are not. Defining W based on distance bounds, the hedonic model changes to incorporate the spatial structure in the error. The vector of errors, θ, in model (4) is specified as: θ = Wθ + µ , (5) where µ is an independent and identically distributed vector of error terms, and λ is the nuisance parameter. λ corrects for the spatial correlation in the error rather than any interdependence among observed variables. Estimating (4) with the spatial autoregressive error via OLS now involves a non-spherical error and will leave the coefficients unbiased but the standard errors both biased and inefficient. Combining equation (4) in vector notation and equation (5) reveals the following spatial autoregressive model: y = Wy + (ΔAttributes)β + (ΔLandmark)δ – W(ΔAttributes)β + W (ΔLandmark)δ + µ (6). Equation (6) differs substantially from equation (4). Accounting for error structure described in (5) avoids the biases that result from estimating (4). Different ways to estimate this model include maximum likelihood (ML) and generalized method of moments (GMM). This analysis uses the SpaceStat (Anselin 1995) software package to estimate the spatial models. In practice, ML estimation requires inverting an N x N matrix that is computationally demanding and, in the case of large datasets, intractable. For that reason, this study (N > 70,000) opts for the GMM approach. The moment conditions for the model can be solved to obtain consistent estimates of β and δ via feasible generalized least squares. GMM does not provide a way to test for the significance of the nuisance parameter λ in the model. The estimation technique uses λ to find consistent estimates of β and δ but cannot make inferences about the presence of spatial dependence. For this analysis, W is defined as a contiguity matrix where neighbors are those within ½ mile of the repeat-sale property, or within ¼ mile of the full sample of all sales.8 8 Alternative constructions of W were tested here, including 5-, 10-, and 20-nearest neighbors. Constructions of W based on defining neighbors as those within ¼ mile or ½ mile (corresponding to 2 and 4 city blocks in Chicago, respectively) were ultimately selected due to computational limits. While the structure of spatial dependence in this data appears more expansive than this small range allows, even a sparse W matrix with contiguity defined as within a ½-mile band is nearly 900MB large for 60,000 observations. Future research will address alternative weights matrices. 11 Diagnostic tests for the presence of spatial dependence in the data are also conducted. Two prominent tests are reported here. First is the Moran’s I test. Moran’s I, one of the oldest and best-performing tests, is a two-dimensional variant of time series correlation based on Moran (1950). The Robust LM (Error) statistic tests for spatial error robust to the presence of another form of spatial dependence (Anselin et al. 1996). IV. Empirical Results The first set of results are presented for the hedonic regression using all sales of attached housing in Chicago during the 1990s. This hedonic model estimates equation (2) for a large set of attributes of the properties and neighborhoods. As is common practice, a Box-Cox transformation was conducted first. The results of the Box-Cox suggested a semi-log form for the appropriate specification – consistent with recommendations elsewhere in the hedonics literature (Cropper et al. 1988).9 The coefficients estimated using the semi-log model in Table 3 should be interpreted as percent changes in real sales price for the property, on the margin. Thus, another room or a waterfront location is associated with properties that sell for 2% and 3% more, respectively. Nearly 60,000 observations had complete (or estimated) information for all variables. Table 3 shows results for 3 different models – two OLS models (restricted and unrestricted) and a restricted model that accounts for spatially autocorrelated errors. All test statistics are reported using robust errors. The restricted model results indicate a good fit to the data. The R2 = 0.79 for the restricted model, and 0.81 for the unrestricted model. The estimated coefficients for this large dataset are typically significant at the 0.05% level, well beyond typical standards for statistical significance.10 Each of the coefficients for property attributes and neighborhood characteristics have the expected sign. Bigger units, with more rooms and parking (but not a garage or an assigned spot), sell for higher prices. Prices were also higher for sales downtown and near parks, not too close to the river or CTA lines, and in areas with high property values, low density, fewer nonwhites, lower incomes, and new buildings. A possible surprise is the positive coefficient for the “distance to Lake” variable, which indicates that each mile away from Lake Michigan is associated with a higher sales price. Strictly interpreted, this coefficient indicates that Lake proximity is a disamenity, after controlling for being on the waterfront (an amenity), being near lakefront parks (an amenity), being near downtown (an amenity), and being near any body of water (an amenity). In light of these controls, the omission of variables directly measuring access to transportation, and the “attached homes” nature of the sample, this result may not be too surprising. The variables of interest in Table 3, the landmark variables, tell an interesting story. Units in properties that are designated landmarks (districts or individual buildings) sell The Box-Cox transformation yielded a θ = 0.048. Admittedly, given such a large N, the models presented here lack numerous possible quadratic and interaction terms, as well as other variables that may be relevant. Numerous other specifications have been estimated, with little substantive effect on the variables of interest. The parsimonious models are presented here. 9 10 12 for a substantial premium over comparable properties. First, each additional landmark in a block group is associated with 1 – 2% lower sales prices for attached homes in that block group. This contrasts with Coulson and Leichenko’s (2001) findings. Moreover, older buildings in a block group also appear associated with lower prices. More directly, however, the landmark status of the property itself is significantly related to its sale price. Units in properties that were designated landmarks (by 2004) sold for 15.5% higher prices. Controlling for community areas, that premium falls to 13.5%. (Controlling for year of construction of the particular property using this dataset does not affect the coefficient substantially. See Table A1 in the Appendix for results including “year builte”.) Those properties in landmarks, where the landmark is a district, have only a 6 – 8% premium – suggesting that landmark buildings are greater amenities than landmark districts. So far, these results are mostly consistent with previous literature and conventional wisdom. The hedonic equations in Table 3 also account for the properties’ proximity to other landmarks. In the restricted model, the price effect of distance to the nearest landmark is not significantly different from zero, but it becomes significant after controlling for community areas. It appears that properties that are farther from landmarks sell at a premium, and that premium is greater if the nearest landmark was constructed more recently and designated longer ago. These effects are consistent with attached homes prices being higher in newer buildings and neighborhoods, and may reflect that recent landmarks are increasingly “marginal.” Yet the SAR results suggest the effect of CL-distance may not be significant. While there may be a price effect of proximity to landmarks, this effect is highly sensitive different modeling assumptions about space and neighborhoods. As mentioned before, care should be taken before interpreting the results shown in Table 3 to demonstrate that landmark designation has an “effect” or “impact” on prices. Landmarks do sell for higher prices, 6 – 15% higher on average. Yet this may be attributable to unobservable characteristics of the property that are correlated with designation, rather than the designation itself. Estimating equation (4), and equation (6), can help us discern the price effect of landmark designation as a tool for historical preservation. An important limitation of this research is in the construction of some of the landmark variables. These variables (landmark, district, CL-year built, CL-date designated, CLdistance) are based on properties and districts that were landmarks as of 2004. They do not account for the fact that some of these properties and districts became landmarks after the sale. As new landmarks were designated during the 1990s, this may change a property’s closest landmark. These variables are best interpreted as representing the marginal price of current or future landmarks. 13 Table 3: Hedonic regressions for all attached home sales, Chicago, 1990-1999 Variables constant log-area unitbldg unitbldg2 rooms bedrooms baths master bath fireplaces garage parking parking spot waterfront distance to CBD distance to CBD2 distance to lake distance to lake2 distance to water distance to water2 distance to CTA distance to CTA2 distance to park distance to park2 northside latitude northside× latitude longitude BG-income BG-value BG-density BG-nonwhite BG-year built BG-landmarks district landmark CL-year built CL-date designated CL-distance year year2 community areas N= R2 = a OLS restricted Coeff. t-stat 107.26* 1.84 0.492*** 17.34 -8.9E-05*** -7.60 1.8E-08*** 5.38 0.020*** 4.76 0.088*** 6.25 0.172*** 18.74 0.059*** 15.85 0.062*** 15.44 -0.021*** -5.57 0.101*** 18.79 -0.065*** -15.8 0.039*** 7.27 -0.141*** -28.18 0.003*** 28.05 0.066*** 6.31 -0.0001 -0.64 0.037*** 6.67 -0.011*** -7.12 0.065*** 11.76 -0.009*** -6.47 -0.039*** -2.78 0.095*** 8.32 -126.6*** -4.36 -0.219 -0.49 3.027*** 4.36 1.962** 2.52 -2.7E-04*** -2.91 5.1E-04*** 28.35 -0.003*** -13.96 -0.455*** -38.16 -0.0001*** -13.76 -0.021*** -16.13 -0.095*** -3.94 0.155*** 6.74 4.5E-05*** 10.82 -3.9E-06*** -9.73 0.004 1.24 0.041*** 59.77 59982 0.794 OLS unrestricted Coeff. t-stat -2365.50*** -2.60 0.484*** 17.18 -1.2E-04*** -9.77 2.0E-08*** 6.29 0.020*** 4.77 0.091*** 6.22 0.174*** 18.68 0.058*** 15.96 0.056*** 14.15 -0.037*** -8.81 0.121*** 21.67 -0.084*** -17.64 0.035*** 6.29 -0.077*** -7.26 0.008*** 13.77 0.241*** 12.02 -0.006*** -7.45 0.033*** 3.89 -0.007* -1.88 0.043*** 4.94 -0.012*** -3.08 -0.020 -1.26 0.073*** 5.87 541.5*** 6.11 11.582*** 7.98 -12.928*** -6.11 16.127*** 10.81 -6.4E-05 -0.65 4.2E-04*** 22.41 -0.003*** -13.17 -0.267*** -19.88 -0.0001*** -12.78 -0.007*** -4.78 -0.059** -2.29 0.135*** 5.44 1.1E-05** 2.29 -2.0E-06*** -4.46 0.033*** 5.48 3.268*** 3.64 -0.001*** -3.6 Included 59982 0.808 SAR restricteda Coeff. z-stat -53.883 -0.56 0.456*** 96.36 -6.5E-05*** -7.22 1.1E-08*** 5.01 0.020*** 20.62 0.099*** 42.00 0.180*** 57.72 0.050*** 16.27 0.053*** 18.28 -0.027*** -7.37 0.113** 24.88 -0.077 19.97 0.026*** 5.16 -0.160*** 23.18 0.003*** 12.38 0.043** 2.41 0.001*** 2.75 0.035*** 3.67 -0.015*** -7.74 0.092*** 9.87 -0.006*** -4.09 -0.054** -2.51 0.072*** 3.51 -248.1*** -6.58 -2.283*** -3.15 5.928*** 6.58 -0.924 -0.68 0.001*** 6.99 2.6E-04*** 13.82 -2.0E-04 -0.84 -0.192 12.59 -0.0001*** -10.19 -0.012*** -6.09 -0.045** -2.19 0.127*** 6.38 1.1E-05 1.53 -2.5E-06*** -4.87 -0.007 -1.21 0.039*** 60.29 59982 0.762 Contiguity defined as all observations within ¼ mile, or approx. 2 Chicago city blocks. = 0.650. * significant at 10%, ** significant at 5%, *** significant at 1% level throughout the paper. 14 Table 4: Repeat-Sales Hedonic Models Variables constant price1 price12 log-area unitbldg unitbldg2 rooms bedrooms baths master bath fireplaces garage parking parking spot waterfront BG-landmarks designation designation×years since design. district landmark BG-landmarks difference CL-year built CL-date designated CL-distance year years between sales years between sales2 distancea, lat/longb, BGc, differencesd controls inverse Mills ratio OLS restricted Coeff. t-stat -1001.2 -1.65 -0.001*** -3.32 3.3E-07*** 2.66 0.026 -0.099* 0.112 -0.069 0.013 0.017 -0.298* 0.76 -1.81 1.51 -0.87 0.42 0.83 -1.77 0.196 -0.133 0.004 1.47 -1.01 0.07 -0.046** 0.037** -2.21 2.39 OLS unrestricted Coeff. t-stat -929.38 -1.31 -0.001*** -5.33 3.6E-07*** 3.64 0.014 0.34 0.0002 1.19 -3.2E-08 -0.90 -0.009 -0.60 0.034* 1.95 0.020 0.64 0.019 0.47 0.035 0.99 -0.053 -0.89 0.046 0.66 -0.025 -0.30 0.006 0.25 0.017 0.75 -0.275 -1.49 0.021 0.69 0.189 -0.133 -0.046 6.9E-06 -1.9E-06 -0.043 0.028** -0.061 0.007 (yes) 1.27 -0.87 -0.93 0.31 -0.54 -1.60 2.14 -1.18 1.27 Heckman restricted Coeff. z-stat 54.724 0.55 0.001*** -3.22 2.9E-07** 2.27 0.051 0.184 -0.208 0.251 0.047 0.015 -0.287 1.30 0.97 -0.96 1.09 0.75 1.05 -1.13 0.116 -0.090 -0.016 0.44 -0.36 -0.09 -0.013 -0.045 -0.45 -0.80 (yes) R2=0.01 N=5462 R2=0.01 0.153 -0.119 -0.046 -1.2E-05 -3.0E-07 -0.022 -0.019 -0.059** 0.007** (yes) 0.463 N=6011 Heckman unrestricted Coeff. z-stat -0.001*** -3.14 3.6E-07*** 2.51 0.008 0.13 0.0001 1.19 -3.0E-08 -0.48 -0.014 -0.77 0.025 0.67 0.022 0.53 0.030 0.73 0.061* 1.69 0.102 1.24 -0.133 -1.35 0.167 1.64 0.020 0.34 0.015 1.05 -0.285 -0.40 0.020 0.06 N=5479 1.47 Wald= 2377 0.60 -0.49 -0.25 -0.29 -0.08 -0.64 -0.92 -2.43 2.43 SAR restrictede Coeff. z-stat -76.01* -1.84 -0.001*** -2.81 2.4E-07* 1.93 0.011 -0.072 0.087 -0.080 0.018 0.016 -0.196 0.36 -1.47 1.52 -1.55 0.30 1.06 -0.77 0.121 -0.070 0.48 -0.29 -0.034 0.036*** -1.08 3.85 (yes) 0.275 N=5462 2.01 Wald= 2453 (yes) N=5467 R2=0.01 a Array of distance variables (to CBD, to lake, to water, to CTA, to park). Array of geographic variables (northside, northside×latitude×distance to lake, latitude, longitude). Interaction term omitted for restricted model. Longitude omitted in Heckman models due to collinearity. c Array of block-group variables (income, value, density nonwhite, year built). d Array of difference variables. Unrestricted: changes in BG variables, parking, fireplaces, all room types, and units. Restricted: changes in bath, bedrooms. e Contiguity defined as all observations within ½ mile, or approximately 4 Chicago city blocks. = 0.207. Moran’s I = 0.0105***. Robust LM(error) = 0.336. (p-value = 0.6) b 15 Table 4 shows the results of estimating equation (4), where the dependent variable in the repeat-sales hedonic framework is now the (annualized) appreciation rate. For attached homes in Chicago, the MLS data has complete (or estimated) information for nearly 5,500 properties that were sold at least twice during the 1990s. As is common in repeatsales hedonic regressions, the explanatory power of the models wanes considerably relative to the sort of hedonics in Table 3. This is due to the fact that all of the time invariant attributes of a property (construction quality, neighborhood quality, etc.) drop out of equation (4) and provide little explanation for differential appreciation rates. Nonetheless, Table 4 depicts the results of the several repeat sales models: two using OLS, two controlling for the selectivity bias, and one that controls for spatial autocorrelation. As is common in repeat-sales hedonics (see, e.g., Kiel and McClain 1995), because changes in supply of or demand for (time-invariant) characteristics may affect appreciation rates, these controls are included in the specifications in Table 4. Results for many of these control variables are omitted from Table 4, but Table A2 in the Appendix reprints the full results for the Heckman unrestricted model. The repeat-sales framework offers limited evidence of the impact of Chicago’s landmark designation program on the value of attached homes in 1990s. Unfortunately, even in a city as large as Chicago with an extensive and vibrant historic landmarks program, only 16 attached homes were sold before and after a landmark designation during the 1990s. The OLS models indicate that properties that became designated landmarks between sales saw their property values appreciate at slower rates than other properties. The restricted OLS model indicates a 29.8% lower appreciation rate for properties that became landmarks, significant at the 8% level. This estimated effect is less precise in the unrestricted model, which controls for more property attributes. Similarly, controlling for the selectivity bias (e.g., homes that sold multiple times may be somehow different from other homes), diminishes this negative landmark effect somewhat. No models estimate a positive effect of landmark designation on appreciation rates. A few other results evident in Table 4 are worth noting. Properties that were or would become landmarks appreciated more slowly (although not statistically significant from zero). This effect was reversed for those in landmark districts (again, also not statistically significant). Appreciation rates for properties that became landmarks do not appear to differ substantially over time. Finally, there does not appear to be a statistically significant effect on appreciation rates of increasing the number of landmarks in a block group. V. Summary and Conclusion This paper has added to the empirical literature on the price effects of historical preservation (landmark) programs. It has used an extensive MLS dataset of attached home sales in the city of Chicago during the 1990s, combined with other geographic and demographic data. The empirical method employed, a hedonic price method, estimates the implicit price of housing attributes, including historic landmark status. Unfortunately, landmark designation effects cannot be differentiated from correlated, unobserved housing traits. Consistent with previous results, the hedonic regressions show landmarks 16 having substantially higher prices than comparable properties. This premium is smaller if the landmark is district rather than a building. In addition, while older buildings and neighborhoods receive a discount, proximity to a landmark that is newer (in construction date) and less recent (in designation date) confers a premium. Yet, these effects may be capturing unobserved neighborhood characteristics as well. A repeat-sales framework was introduced to address this identification issue. While few properties in the sample became a landmark in between sales, those that did suggest that the price effect of landmark designation is not positive. If anything, local landmark designation appears to harm property values. This result is consistent with another study of price effects of landmark designation in Chicago (Schaeffer and Millerick 1991). The results here apply only to local, City of Chicago landmark status. Future work will control for National Register status. Additionally, the Chicago Historical Resources Survey (for more information, see City of Chicago 2004) can be incorporated to improve the controls for historical qualities of properties that have not yet been designated landmarks. This 1996 survey identified over 17,000 properties in the city with historical or architectural significance. It collected information about building style and type, architect, and amount of alteration that has taken place. Using this data source will offer better controls on historical qualities independent of official designation. Diminished prices for landmarks may not be worrisome on their own, especially if the purpose of historical preservation is to maintain affordable housing. It does seem plausible that historical preservation tools such as those used in Chicago – which makes it costly or impossible to update older residential properties – will keep housing affordable by lowering the relative quality of landmark residences. Effective landmark preservation policies may constrain owners ability provide optimal mixes of housing service, and the properties accordingly sell at a discount. Unfortunately, affordable housing goals may be reached not through lowering housing costs, but by lowering the quantity or quality of housing. Another view of lower prices for landmarks, suggests a sort of “taxation by regulation” approach to historical preservation. Landmark owners may lose a little property value, it is argued, but preservation is serving the broader public interest. Restrictions on property use are justified by the sizeable external benefits of preservation (Coulson and Leichenko 2001). These externalities accrue from neighborhood stabilization, adding prestige or maintaining the “charm” of a neighborhood, and other alleged positive spillovers. Thus, lower prices for designated landmark may be merely the cost of achieving the external benefits from preservation. The results presented here give limited empirical support for this view. The hedonic regression for all attached home sales in Chicago in the 1990s indicates that block groups with more landmarks are disamenities. It also suggests that properties nearer to landmarks, near to landmarks that were constructed long ago, and near to landmarks that were newly designated sell at discounts. Although these negative price effects may be an artifact of the sample, they provide little support for the view that 17 landmark designation confers substantial external benefits to other properties.11 The hedonic regression for repeat sales actually provides some weak evidence that landmark designation has negative spillovers for attached homes. Properties’ appreciation rates may not differ significantly depending on their own landmark status, but they do appear to be somewhat lower as the number of landmarks in the block group increases. Space matters Judging by the effects of various weights matrices (i.e., definitions of neighborliness), it appears that the neighbor effects in the attached housing market in Chicago are strong for price levels and weaker for appreciation rates. The neighbor effects on prices appear at its strongest around one-half mile of a property, though appreciation rates seem to be interdependent with much closer neighbors. Accounting for spatial interdependence in the data has relatively limited influence on the estimated marginal prices associated landmarks. By and large, little changed in the SAR estimates, except that some statistical significance was lost. This is a common result when the data are positively spatially correlated (as standard errors are biased down). Not surprisingly, landmark designation in Chicago exhibits spatial dependence (see Map 1). Perhaps most interesting is the different in the BG-landmarks coefficient between the OLS and SAR models in Table 3. This suggests that spatial interdependence in the data may inflate the effects of an area’s landmarks count in hedonic analyses. Otherwise, controlling for spatial effects has minor effect on the estimated coefficients. This weak effect of spatial interdependence is of particular interest for landmarks – which are often touted as having powerful effects on neighborhood identity, character, and social fabric. If the spatial interdependence was indeed especially strong concerning landmarks, we might have expected that to be captured when controlling for neighbor interactions. Future research that better accounts for the spatial structure of the data (i.e., better W matrices) may revise this conclusion. Conclusive evidence of the price effects of historic preservation programs is elusive, even for a single market. Properties in landmarks and landmark districts in Chicago clearly sell for much higher prices than other properties. Yet, we cannot distinguish these effects from other unobservable traits of the property that are correlated with designation status. Very little attention has been paid to controlling for these unobserved quality characteristics, a shortcoming addressed by the repeat-sales approach introduced in this paper. Doing so demonstrates the difficulty in identifying causal effects of preservation policies. Additional research is needed to explore the possible external effects of preservation on other properties and on welfare more generally. 11 There may be sizable external benefits not captured by properties, e.g., public goods values. These were found in studies like Kling et al. (2004) and Chambers et al. (1998). 18 References Anselin, Luc. 1995. SpaceStat version 1.80 User’s Guide. Morgantown, WV: Regional Research Institute, West Virginia University. Anselin, Luc. 2001. “Spatial econometrics.” in B. Baltagi, ed. Companion to Theoretical Econometrics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 310 – 330. Anselin, Luc. 2003. “Spatial Externalities.” International Regional Science Review. 26 (2): 147 – 152. Anselin, Luc, A. K. Bera, Raymond Florax, and M. J. Yoon. 1996. “Simple Diagnostic Tests for Spatial Dependence.” Regional Science and Urban Economics. 26: 77 – 104. Asabere, Paul K. and Forrest E. Huffman. 1994a. “The Value Discounts Associated with Historic Façade Easements.” The Appraisal Journal. 62 (2): 270 – 277. Asabere, Paul K. and Forrest E. Huffman. 1994b. “Historic Designation and Residential Market Values.” The Appraisal Journal. 62 (3): 396 – 401. Chambers, Catherine M., Paul E. Chambers, and John C. Whitehead. 1998. “Contingent Valuation of Quasi-Public Goods: Validity, Reliability, and Application to Valuing an Historic Site.” Public Finance Review. 26(2): 137 –154. City of Chicago. 2004. “Chicago Landmarks” website. http://www.cityofchicago.org/Landmarks/ Last accessed 6 October 2004. Clark, D. E., and W. E. Herrin. 1997. “Historical Preservation and Home Sale Prices: Evidence from the Sacramento Housing Market.” Review of Regional Studies 27: 29 – 48. Coulson, N. Edward and Robin M. Leichenko. 2001. “The Internal and External Impact of Historical Designation on Property Values.” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics. 23 (1): 113 – 124. Cropper, Maureen L, Leland Deck, and Kenneth E. McConnell. 1988. “On the Choice of Functional Forms for Hedonic Price Functions.” Review of Economics and Statistics. 70(4): 668 – 675. Freeman, A. Myrick. 2003. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. Gale, Dennis E. 1991. “The Impacts of Historic District Designation.” Journal of the American Planning Association. 57 (3): 325 – 341. 19 Ioannides, Yannis M. 2003. “Interactive Property Valuations.” Journal of Urban Economics. 145 – 170. Kiel, Katherine A. and Katherine T. McClain. 1995. “The Effect of an Incinerator Siting on Housing Appreciation Rates.” Journal of Urban Economics. 37: 311 – 323. Kling, Robert, Charles Revier, and Karin Sable. 2004. “Estimating the Public Good Value of Preserving a Local Historic Landmark: The Role of Non-Substitutability and Citizen Information.” Urban Studies. 41 (10): 2025 – 2042. Leichenko, Robin. M., N. Edward Coulson, and David Listokin. 2001. “Historic Preservation and Residential Property Values: An Analysis of Texas Cities.” Urban Studies. 38 (11): 1973 – 1987. Listokin, David, Barbara Listokin, and Michael Lahr. 1998. “The Contributions of Historic Preservation to Housing and Economic Development.” Housing Policy Debate. 9 (3): 431 – 478. Moran, P. A. P. 1950. “A Test for the Serial Dependence of Residuals.” Biometrika. 37: 178 – 181. New York Landmarks Conservancy. 1977. The Impacts of Historic Designation— Summary. Study conducted by Raymond, Parish, Pine and Weiner, Inc. new York Landmarks Conservancy, New York. Rosen, Sherwin. 1974. “Hedonic Prices and Implicity Markets: Product Differentiation in Perfect Competition.” Journal of Political Economy. 82 (1): 34 – 55. Schaeffer, Peter V. and Cecily Ahern Millerick. 1991. “The Impact of Historic District Designation on Property Values: An Empirical Study.” Economic Development Quarterly. 5 (4): 301 – 312. Schuster, J. Mark. 2002. “Making a List and Checking it Twice: The List as a Tool of Historic Preservation.” The Cultural Policy Center at the University of Chicago, working paper #14. http://culturalpolicy.uchicago.edu/workingpapers/Schuster14.pdf Last accessed 10 October 2004. Scribner, D. 1976. “Historic Districts as an Economic Asset to Cities.” The Real Estate Appraiser. May/June: 7 – 12. Siciliano, Christopher. 2004. Community area map, downloaded from University of Chicago library website: http://www.lib.uchicago.edu/e/su/maps/chicomm.zip Last accessed 6 October 2004. 20 Swaim, Richard. 2003. “Politics and Policymaking: Tax Credits and Historic Preservation.” Journal of Arts, Management, Law and Society. 33 (1): 32 – 39. 21 Appendix Table A1: Hedonic model, with all sales, including “year-built” variable Dep. Var.: log-price Variables constant log-area floor year built-e unitbldg unitbldg2 rooms bedrooms baths master bath fireplaces garage parking parking spot waterfront distance to CBD distance to CBD2 distance to lake distance to lake2 distance to water distance to water2 distance to CTA distance to CTA2 distance to park distance to park2 northside latitude northside× latitude northside× latitude× distance to lake longitude BG-income BG-value BG-density BG-nonwhite BG-year built BG-landmarks district landmark CL-year built CL-date designated CL-distance year year2 N= R2 = Coeff. -3379.231*** 0.5117*** 0.0048*** -1.4E-05* -0.0002*** 3.3E-08*** 0.0173*** 0.0912*** 0.1731*** 0.0578*** 0.0566*** -0.0535*** 0.1288*** -0.0891*** 0.0210*** -0.0110 0.0076*** 0.2529*** -0.0084*** 0.0183** -0.0041 0.0470*** -0.0152*** -0.0094 0.0713*** 932.06*** 15.1148*** -22.25*** -0.0013*** 14.6732*** 0.0006*** 0.0004*** -0.0025*** -0.1942*** -0.0001*** -0.0071*** -0.0356 0.1390*** 1.1E-05** -2.2E-06*** 0.0182*** 4.0059*** -0.0010*** 48863 0.8157 t-stat -3.64 15.16 25.98 -1.66 -16.05 8.11 4.02 4.92 15.04 14.88 12.83 -12.10 22.18 -17.78 3.79 -0.99 13.95 13.59 -10.20 2.21 -1.27 4.78 -3.13 -0.55 5.16 9.69 9.27 -9.69 -6.73 10.35 4.93 21.05 -11.18 -13.05 -14.10 -4.27 -1.37 5.61 2.07 -4.47 2.93 4.35 -4.30 p-value 0 0 0 0.097 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.321 0 0 0 0.027 0.206 0 0.002 0.583 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.17 0 0.039 0 0.003 0 0 22 Table A2: Full Heckman (ML) model for Repeat Sales Appreciation Rate regression Selection (repeat sales) probit Variable Coeff. z-stat p-value Coeff. z-stat p-value constant 217.49600** 1.98 0.047 350.2115*** 21.28 0 price1 -0.00071*** -3.42 0.001 0.04341*a 1.74 0.082 price12 3.14E-07*** 2.81 0.005 log-area 0.00779 0.17 0.864 -0.05032* -1.84 0.066 unitbldg 0.00015 1.30 0.195 -0.00008 -1.63 0.102 unitbldg2 4.65E-08 -1.42 0.156 6.99E-09 0.91 0.363 rooms -0.01980 -1.14 0.254 -0.01806** -2.00 0.046 bedrooms 0.00162 0.07 0.947 -0.04589** -2.48 0.013 baths 0.01572 0.46 0.643 -0.01066 -0.55 0.585 master bath 0.04412 1.00 0.316 0.05255*** 2.83 0.005 fireplaces 0.10693** 2.32 0.021 0.10101*** 5.81 0 garage 0.49731** 2.35 0.019 0.66481*** 19.32 0 parking -0.60945*** -2.64 0.008 -0.76222*** -18.9 0 parking spot 0.67186*** 2.66 0.008 0.82285*** 22.52 0 waterfront 0.05878* 1.80 0.071 0.04082 1.30 0.194 BG-income 0.00107 0.87 0.384 0.00017 0.32 0.748 BG-value -0.00016 -1.05 0.294 -0.00011 -1.19 0.233 BG-density 0.00437** 2.38 0.017 0.00574*** 5.74 0 BG-nonwhite -0.41092* -1.94 0.052 -0.19274*** -3.20 0.001 BG-year built -0.00001 -0.45 0.653 BG-landmarks 0.00822 0.51 0.608 -0.00635 -0.76 0.444 designation -0.16326 -1.37 0.170 designation×years since design. 0.00102 0.05 0.961 year -0.14065** -2.39 0.017 -0.20791*** -32.71 0 distance to CBD -0.02723* -1.73 0.083 -0.03950*** -6.63 0 distance to lake 0.01143 0.44 0.663 0.02197*** 3.40 0.001 distance to water -0.02107 -0.89 0.375 0.00465 0.30 0.763 distance to CTA 0.00433 0.13 0.899 -0.04087** -2.22 0.026 distance to park 0.24087 3.15 0.002 0.15089*** 4.61 0 northside -0.14228 -0.84 0.403 northside× latitude× distance to lake -0.00010 -0.36 0.721 latitude 1.48168* 1.66 0.098 1.51950*** 4.62 0 district -0.02964 -0.19 0.849 -0.15042 -1.09 0.276 landmark 0.02416 0.17 0.866 0.08265 0.63 0.526 CL-year built -0.00004 -1.35 0.178 -0.00006** -2.38 0.017 CL-date designated 1.56E-06 0.46 0.645 3.51E-06 1.63 0.102 CL-distance 0.00237 0.07 0.942 0.04026** 2.59 0.01 BG-nonwhite -0.27664 -1.12 0.263 BG-density -0.00104 -0.33 0.740 BG-value 0.00005 0.32 0.751 BG-income -0.00057 -0.62 0.534 BG-landmarks -0.06295 -1.43 0.152 parking spot 0.00833 0.30 0.763 parking 0.00675 0.20 0.841 diff’s garage -0.00448 -0.14 0.888 btwn. fireplaces 0.07908 0.98 0.329 master bath -0.00600 -0.23 0.819 baths 0.10043 2.77 0.006 bedrooms 0.03121* 1.75 0.080 rooms -0.00042 -0.04 0.971 unitbldg -1.36E-08 -0.98 0.327 unitbldg2 0.00010 0.90 0.366 years between sales -0.00294 -0.12 0.903 years between sales2 0.00100 0.41 0.681 desig90s -0.01542 -0.20 0.839 N = 59946 uncensored N = 5462 censored N = 54484 a log-price was used in the selection equation. 23 24