1 Evaluating the Regional Economic Effects of Structural Funds Programs Using the REMI Policy Insight Model By1 Frederick Treyz, Ph.D and George Treyz, Ph.D 1 The authors are respectively CEO and President of Regional Economic Models, Inc.; 306 Lincoln Ave. Amherst, MA 01002; (tel) 413-549-1169; info@remi.com. The results and analysis of Southern Italy represent the joint work of REMI and IRPET. The staff who are actively involved in the analysis of IRPET are Sara Mele, Roberto Pagni and Renato Paniccia. 2 Evaluating the Regional Economic Effects of Structural Funds Programs Using the REMI Policy Insight Model By Frederick Treyz, Ph.D., George Treyz, Ph.D.2 This paper presents scenarios to address major types of Structural Funds programs using the REMI macroeconomic model. The purpose is to show how the total socioeconomic effects of a broad range of programs can be evaluated using a widely available model that is developed to analyze the economies of nations and sub-national regions. The model results show the total macroeconomic impacts of changes that occur due to direct policy effects.3 We show the total effect of structural measures and public investments on a representative economy. The analysis shows how to conduct a comparative evaluation of the future effectiveness of expenditures for different investments and structural and cohesion funds programs. These comparisons will provide a basis for developing information necessary for policy-makers to predict the relative effectiveness of various expenditures on major economic development goals. This facilitates the process of making choices about the future allocation of operation program funds. Here we provide specific analyses and results for representative structural-funds analysis covering a broad range of programs. These programs include subsidies for the 2 The results and analysis of Southern Italy represent the joint work of REMI and IRPET. The staff who are actively involved in the analysis of IRPET are Sara Mele, Roberto Pagni and Renato Paniccia. 3 This model has been in continual development since 1980 and is well-documented in academic literature. See for example, Fan, Treyz and Treyz (2000), Greenwood, Hunt, Rickman and Treyz (1991), and Treyz, Rickman and Shao (1992). 3 productive sector, investments in transportation infrastructure, human-capital investment and tourism investment. The approach is to represent the direct effects of a policy, use these effects as inputs into a macroeconomic model, and generate the economic and demographic changes that occur as a result of the policy. The simulation results are reported as the difference in economic activity on an annual basis that is caused by the direct economic change. For example, investing in transportation infrastructure increases the quality of transportation infrastructure, which has the effect of reducing transportation costs. The direct effects of the transportation investment are based in part on an estimate of the reduction in percentage terms of transportation costs. These transportation cost changes are entered into the Transportation Cost Matrix of the Policy Insight model as a change in travel between the regions in a multi-regional model. From this, the results of the analysis show the macroeconomic effects of transportation improvements. Particular attention is focused on supply-side effects such as those of subsidies for: Major manufacturing industries Investment in labor productivity Investment due to an increase in access to intermediate inputs Reduction in transportation costs due to an investment in transportation infrastructure The results are stated in terms of changes in key macroeconomic and demographic indicators. The inputs for the subsidies to industries, for example, have 4 major effects on exports, intermediate and final sales, exports to the rest of the nation, output, gross domestic product, employment, unemployment rate, migration, relative production costs, and real disposable income per capita. For example, consider the analysis of a subsidy. The subsidy may lead to a longterm location of a firm due to the relative sensitivity in the locations of fixed capital stock to the initial investment cost. Shares of the local and export markets would increase output. Employment would be increased and unemployment decreased as output increases. The employment and real-wage gains would decrease the outward net migration that was indicated in the baseline forecasts. The model continues to track through all of the causality until a simultaneous solution for each year is found. In order to examine structural change, it is necessary to have a model that explains all of the key cause-and-effect relationships in the economy so that interventions can be introduced to change the status quo. For example, if a model does not include labor supply by occupation and/or industry, it is difficult to predict the effects among training programs. Models that do not explicitly include the effects of improved access to labor or intermediate inputs will miss one of the primary reasons that some regions prosper, which is the availability of a large pool of trained labor and access to specialized intermediate inputs. In a draft paper that we are preparing for the European Commission, we conclude that “each of the models represents a different focus. Quest II focuses on forward-looking rationality and international trade balance, Venables and Gasiorek on micro-economic behavior of firms in space, REMI on explicit structures based on maximizing behavior of actors in response to current conditions and key statistical parameters based on large data sets, and HERMIN on special characteristics in different 5 countries as revealed in the relationships in recent years between variables in aggregate time series estimates.”4 The major goal for E.U. Structural Funds and many other Public Investments is sustainable economic development. Unfortunately, accurate estimates of the relative effectiveness of alternative public expenditures in meeting this goal are often not available. Thus, allocation of euros may or may not be optimal. In order to determine the relative effectiveness three steps are required. 1. Examine each of the operational plans in detail. In particular, we must examine the direct effects on the economy in the short and long run. While the direct-demand effects will be important in the short run, it is the long-run supply-and-demand effects that will be the most important factors in sustainable development. 2. Input these direct effects into a structural, economic-policy-analysis model that includes all of the key chains of causality through which public fund investments will influence the economy. 3. Run the model and calculate the relative effectiveness of the euro expenditure in accomplishing the major objectives of the public investments. Some examples of the ways that public policy can directly affect the socioeconomic outcomes in the economy are: Increase the private capital investments in the economy: Instruments: Subsidies Tax policies Facilitate the working of capital markets “A Comparison of the Four Economic Policy Analysis Models that Have Been Selected by the E.U. Commission for Structural Fund Evaluation.” By Frederick Treyz and George Treyz. REMI mimeo. 4 6 Increase demand on a permanent basis: Instruments: Public investments in tourism Infrastructure investments Reduce Labor and Capital Costs: Instruments: Reduce non-wage labor costs Tax policies Increase Productivity: Investments: Technology development Labor training Increase access to labor and intermediate inputs Transportation infrastructure Make the area a more attractive place to live in: Investments: Public infrastructure Environmental improvements Reduce crime Improve consumer access to goods and services Tax policy Increase Labor Supply: Investments: Effect the age structure of the population Increase participation rate Change tax support for non-workers Change attitudes; enable people over 65 to continue to work Promote local products Add variety by expanding some industries 7 The model used must be able to forecast the effects on the total regional economy of the direct inputs into the model represented by structural funds intervention. It must also have a plausible structure that captures all of the key chains of causality through which the public investment (or micro-analysis) directly affects flow through the community. We believe that the REMI model is the only model that meets these requirements. The remainder of this paper will be devoted to a description of and preliminary results from two models that we have built for the E.U. Directorate-General for Regional Policy Coordination of Evaluation Commission. One model was jointly developed and applied by REMI and IRPET (Instituto Regionale Par La Programmoz oine Economica Toscana, Via La Farina 27, 50132 Florence, Italy). The other REMI Policy Insight model is for a multi-regional configuration of four areas in Spain. In order to build our structural model of Italian regions we gathered data for all areas and then built a database that included raw data such as wage rates, employment, and detailed demographic data. In addition, using our model structure we were able to generate productivity and other concepts. 8 Figures 1-5 are maps of Italy that represent economic effects on the textile industries. Such maps can be helpful in assessing the strengths and weaknesses of a region. Figure 1 shows the industry of textiles and textile products. It shows that comparative wage rates are highest in Piemonte in Northern Italy. Italy: Wage Rate: Textiles & Textile Products Figure 1 9 Figure 2 illustrates labor productivity as we estimate it using the comparative availability of workers to choose from in the textile industry and in occupations used in that industry. In this case, Lombardia has the highest productivity. Italy: Labor Productivity: Textiles & Textile Products Figure 2 10 Figure 3 shows wages adjusted for productivity. Italy: Wage Rate divided by Labor Productivity: Textiles & Textile Products Figure 3 11 Figure 4 shows the price of textiles considering both the production cost and the access to variety. Italy: Composite Price: Textiles & Textile Products Figure 4 12 Figure 5 shows us that production costs are lowest in Lombardia despite their relatively high wage rates. Italy: Production Cost: Textiles & Textile Products Figure 5 This background can illustrate the structural detail in the REMI model and could be used along with similar data for other industries to select policies to develop as economic development strategies. An overview of the REMI model abstracted from the REMI model documentation book is included as an appendix to this paper. Further information about the model and its parameter estimation, etc., is a forthcoming OECD publication.5 Using a REMI-IRPET model of Objective 1 areas in Southern Italy, IRPET and REMI have carried out a number of simulations for selected structural fund expenditures. 13 Here we will first present the preliminary comparative results of these simulations and then we will describe the inputs that went into REMI Policy Insight, as well as the explanations of the macro results for each step in the simulation process. In order to evaluate the effectiveness of the alternative structural-funds program, the policy simulation model has made a comparison of benefit per 100,000 euros of alternative benefit measures. Table 1 shows four different types of investment. 2006 Jobs per 100,000 euros Investment in 50% Subsidy to AG Equipment Human Capital: Blue Collar Training Tourism Productivity Improvements and Promotions Integrated Transport System 2006 2006 Labor force Population per 100,000 per 100,000 euros euros 2006 GDP per euro invested 2006 Real Disposable Income per euro 32 8 2 1 0.3 5 1 0 0.3 0.1 24 8 2 1.5 1.2 19 5 1 0.6 0.2 Table 1: Preliminary Estimates of the Effects of Structural Fund Investments in the Objective 1 areas of Southern Italy in 2006. The first simulation was for a program that subsidized agricultural equipment purchases. The first three results of the simulation are stated per 100,000 of the expenditures during the seven-year period from 2000-2006. The first result shows that 32 jobs were generated in 2006 from the past and current subsidies for the equipment. In 2006, some of the results are due to the supply-side productivity gains from investments “The Evaluation of Programs Aimed at Local and Regional Development: Methodology and Twenty Years of Experience Using REMI Policy Insight.” By Frederick Treyz, and George Treyz. Forthcoming OECD publication. 5 14 in previous years as well as the demand-side effects of spending for the seventh year of the equipment in 2006. The first is subsidy to agricultural equipment. The second policy is subsidy for human capital, in particular blue-collar training. The third is a study on tourism, and the fourth is transportation analysis. In each of these cases, benefit measures were used, including jobs, labor force, and population per 100,000 euros. Gross domestic product (GDP) per euro and real disposable income per euro generated by the various structural funds programs were also used in the models. Looking from one policy to the others we see that in terms of job creation there is a big difference between various policies. For example, investments in blue-collar training have developed relatively few jobs per euro, whereas a subsidy in agricultural equipment generates a high number of jobs. There are similar differences, although not quite as wide-ranging, in terms of the other measures of changes in population, GDP, and disposable personal income. The subsidy to agricultural equipment generated the highest number of jobs per euro since this subsidy provides an indirect subsidy to the agricultural industry. Agriculture is a relatively labor-intensive industry. Thus by increasing the competitiveness of agriculture through the subsidy there are many jobs created. Even in the case of GDP per euro this effect is relatively high. However, since agriculture is a relatively low-income industry, the effects on real disposable income creation per euro of subsidy are not much higher than they are for the blue-collar training or transport system investment. In fact, they are significantly lower than they are for the improvements in 15 tourism productivity. This simulation did not consider possible additional costs to the E.U. related to additional agricultural surpluses. To measure the jobs generated by the subsidy to agricultural equipment in 2006, we first measured the amount of agricultural equipment that would be new equipment. Then we assumed that one-third of the new equipment would have been purchased without the subsidy. Next we divided 60% of the equipment for agriculture by the capital-to-output ratio in order to give us an estimate of the amount of extra output we would have for agriculture. Then 80% of that extra output was put into sales that would occur without competition to other firms in the area. This is particularly true because of the assumption that the government of the E.U. absorbs the surplus production. We assumed that 20% of the surplus firm output would be in competition with other firms in the area. We also assumed that the life expectancy of the equipment would be 10 years. These gave us the inputs for agricultural product sales. The other 40% of the extra equipment was attributed to the food and beverage industry and was divided by the capital ratio of .95, giving us the amount that was spent in the food-products industry. All of the food sold in the food-product industry is in competition with other food sales and was thus entered into the model as firm sales. This accounts for any other firm in the food-products industry in Southern Italy, as well as extra sales due to a greater variety of suppliers. We calculated the share of local contribution to the subsidy and we added that to personal taxes. The last input was the amount of expenditure per year on the machinery equipment that was purchased each year. This was put in as demand originating within the area but supplied within and without the area. The extra demand supplied locally added to economic activity through 2006 when the program ended. This 16 completed the inputs that were put into the final total for the expenditures in agricultural equipment. The effects of the subsidy consist of four parts. The final demand for machinery and agricultural equipment in 2006 was 7.4% of the final total employment change. The sales of agricultural goods consisted of 70.4%. The effect of food and beverage product sales made up 22.7% of the final total. Yet, 0.5% of the total employees are taken away due to extra local taxes to pay the local portion of the subsidy. 2012 Jobs per 100,000 euros Investment in 50% Subsidy to AG Equipment Human Capital: Blue Collar Training Tourism Productivity Improvements and Promotions Integrated Transport System 2012 2012 Labor force Population per 100,000 per 100,000 euros euros 2012 GDP per euro invested 2012 Real Disposable Income per euro 14 8 4 0.5 0.2 6 1 0 0.5 0.2 25 13 6 1.7 1.4 8 5 2 0.3 0.1 Table 2: Preliminary Estimates of Structural Fund Investments in the Objective 1 areas of Southern Italy in 2012. In 2012, the jobs generated by the subsidy to agricultural equipment decrease. These results are supply-side effects from the equipment. This is due to the fact that the agricultural equipment has a 10-year life expectancy. Therefore, the new machinery wears out, causing a loss of employees. Jobs per 100,000 euros decline due to the aging of the equipment. 17 The final demand for machinery and agricultural equipment in 2012 was –3.4% of the final total. The sales of agricultural goods made up 75.3% of total. The effect of food and beverage sales consisted of 24.3%. The total employees due to extra local taxes consist of 0.4% of the final total. SIMULATION: Occupational training in Regione Campania, data from P.O.R. (Operative Regional Program) Ob. 3 2000-2006 (Sara Mele). Policy variables: assumptions and sources Occupational training, detail: Blue collars/Other personnel We have estimated the number of trainees (blue collars/other personnel) considering an average cost per person of about 6.000 euros. This training increased labor access and thus labor productivity. This increase in labor productivity in turn led to lower cost in Southern Italy, which increased competitiveness and thus sales. It also reduced local cost for locally produced goods. In calculating labor access, we assumed that only 50% of the trained labor force would remain in the area and be active in the labor force. This assumption was made based on the high unemployment rates in Southern Italy. This effect contributed 15% of the employment effect in 2006 and 111% in 2012. Exogenous Final Demand, detail: Education We assumed that training programs are offered by private agencies in the education sector. Therefore, we introduced an exogenous demand for these firms equal 18 to the total cost of training courses (completely financed by public resources). This effect contributed 92% to the employment effect in 2006 and –13% in 2012. The negative effect in 2012 (six years after the training would be completed) was due to the stimulation to the economy in the first six years, which led to residential and nonresidential construction, which was in greater supply in 2006 than it otherwise would have been. Personal Taxes, detail: Applicable Personal Income Priority III for “Human resources” is financed by the European Social Fund (63%) and national (26%) and regional (11%) governments. So we have estimated the increase in personal taxes for citizens of Regione Campania necessary to finance the Regional Operational Programme. Regional co-financing is completely collected with regional taxes. For the national co-financing we have calculated the share of national taxes paid by Campania’s citizens. Personal taxes from 2000-2006 reduced the result in 2006 and increased it by 9% in 2012 using the same effect as explained for the training expenditure above. SIMULATION: Subsidies to increasing tourism sector competitiveness and tourism expenditure (Operative Regional Program) Ob. 3 2000-2006. Total Factor Productivity The main objective of the measure is to increase Total Factor Productivity (TFP). In particular the target is expressed in terms of Value added per unit of labor in the 19 tourism sector (Hotels and Restaurants). The present value is 48.0, while the target value is 55.0. The TFP of the Hotel and Restaurant industry has been increased consistently. The increase in productivity had an important effect on the cost of production in the Hotel and Restaurant industry. For local residents this had the effect of reducing costs of restaurant meals and thus increasing real incomes and also leading to some substitution of restaurant meals for all items that they might otherwise have purchased. The high local content of restaurant meals added to the employment gain. Of course, some reduction of capital and labor input per meal mitigated this effect. The other major effect was the reduction in the cost of Hotels and Restaurants in Southern Italy for both Italian tourists and tourists from abroad. Both of these effects increased the “export” of these services and thus increased employment. In this particular simulation we used a depreciation rate of 5% for the depreciation of the equipment. Exogenous demand in Investments The increasing investment in Hotels and Restaurants by producing sectors have been estimated through the investment bridge matrix associated to Campania I-O matrix estimated by IRPET. SIMULATION: Subsidies to inter-modal commodities transportation (Operative Regional Program) Ob. 3 2000-2006. 20 Policy variables: assumptions and sources Transportation Cost One of the main indicators of such measures is to increase the amount of tons of commodities by railroad per 100 inhabitants. The present value is 1.99 and the target value is 2.75. This will determine a decrease in transportation cost by moving commodities from road to railroad (the parameter has been estimated using data drawn from the Transportation National Account 1994 and Italian State Railways Yearbook). The projection of decreasing transportation cost at the regional level has been estimated using the transport margins in the Italian Objective 1 I-O matrix at market price. This gain contributed 29.6% of the gain in employment in 2006 and 76.2% in 2012. Accessibility Increase in accessibility adds to the variety of intermediate production inputs that producers can choose from. The accessibility costs in 2006 are 14% of the employment gains, and in 2012 this gain is raised to 65.9%. These intermediate inputs range from access of components of products that are produced, to the access of specialized legal services. This greater access creates an agglomeration effect that increases productivity and reduces costs. These reductions improve competitiveness and increase sales and employment. Exogenous demand in Construction The increasing demand in investment in Construction has been estimated through the total amount of investment and the usage of the specific intermediate column cost of 21 railroad building provided by the Ministry of the Economy. The construction of the infrastructure is 55.9% of the employment in 2006, but reduces the gain by -42.2% in 2012. Again the reduction in 2012 is an echo of the extra construction of residential and commercial space simulated by the accelerated economic activity from 2000-2006. An example of a 1% reduction in transportation costs for Andalucia This simulation for Andalucia is based on the arbitrary assumption that a project is undertaken to reduce transportation costs by 1%. Figure 6 shows a reduction of transportation cost of internal transportation in Andalucia to 99% from what they are in the baseline. The model used is a four-area model that would allow us to calculate input and reductions of transportation costs to any of the other areas in the model. Policy Variable Values for Transportation Costs down 1% for Andalucia Figure 6 22 Figure 7 assumes an access gain of one-half the value of transportation costs since access depends on transportation costs and other factors. Policy Variable Values for Accessibility Costs down .5% for Andalucia Figure 7 Figure 8 indicates a 0.05% reduction in labor costs. In this case, this represents an average reduction of commuter time by 15 seconds each way. If commuting time is valued at one-half of the wage rate this would be a 0.05% reduction in the premium the average commuter would add to his or her reservation wage. 23 Policy Variable Values for Commuting Costs down .05% in Andalucia Figure 8 Figure 9 shows reductions in the cost of production for all industries except the Finance, Insurance and Real Estate industry. The reason that this industry is an exception is that real estate and housing prices will be up due to increased demand resulting from incomes and populations that are higher than they were in the baseline. Transportation Costs –1%, Accessibility Costs -.5%, and Commuting Costs -.05% for Andalucia Compared to REMI Standard Regional Control Rel Cost of Production by % Change for Andalucia Figure 9 24 Figure 10 illustrates the increase in employment that occurs due to lower prices and increased market shares that occur because of increases in competitiveness. Transportation Costs –1%, Accessibility Costs -.5%, and Commuting Costs -.05% for Andalucia Compared to REMI Standard Regional Control Total Employment by Percent Change for Andalucia Figure 10 Figure 11 shows the output of these same effects. The self-supply effects are due to the immediate reduction in costs and prices in the home market while the export response to more competitiveness grows more gradually. Transportation Costs –1%, Accessibility Costs -.5%, and Commuting Costs -.05% for Andalucia Compared to REMI Standard Regional Control Output Components by Percent Change for Andalucia Figure 11 25 Next we show the changes in market shares in 2010 for a sample industry in Figure 12. Here we note that the Andalucians’ share of its own market increases by 0.23%. The Andalucians’ share of the markets in other areas of Spain increase by between 0.03% and 0.04%, while its increase in sales to the rest of the world goes up by 0.07%. These changes lead to a total increase of 0.18% in output for Andalucia. Note also that its purchases from other Spanish areas go down by 1.8% as the increased competitive effect offsets the stimulated effect of increase in the Andalucian economy. Transportation –1%, Accessibility Costs -.5%, and Commuting Costs -.05% for Andalucia Compared to REMI Standard Regional Control Domestic Trade Flows by Percent Change Figure 12 Table 3 shows the chain of causality even more completely. Note that the GDP gain remains even though the employment gains are lower in 2017 than in 2000. This is due to the general gain in the productivity of labor assumed in the baseline as well as increasing labor productivity due to increased access. The improved conditions in Andalucia reduce the number of the out-migration in the baseline forecast. At first, exports to other areas decrease and it is only over time that the gains in competitiveness increase the penetration into those markets. 26 16-Jun-03 REMI Standard Reg Control Accs -.5% &trans cost down by 1%& icom cst dn .05% [Top] - Differences Andalucia Variable 2000 Employment (Thous) 5.701 Gross Regional Product (GRP) (1,000M 97Euro) 0.2426 Personal Income (1,000M Nom Euro) 0.1718 PCE-Price Index (97 Euro)(Reg vs National Baseline) -0.01671 Real Disp Personal Income (1,000M 97Euro) 0.1946 Population (Thous) 0.3516 Econ Migrants 0.1204 Total Migrants 0.1204 Labor Force 1.509 Demand (1,000M 97Euro) 0.3862 Output (1,000M 97Euro) 0.4134 Delivered Price -0.0002 Relative Cost of Production -0.00011 Labor Intensity -1.55E-05 Labor Access Index 0.000342 Indust Mix Index 0 Reg Pur Coeff (SS over Dem) 0.000784 Imports (1,000M 97Euro) -0.0282 Self Supply (1,000M 97Euro) 0.4143 Exports to Multiregions (1,000M 97Euro) -0.00345 Exports to Rest of Nation (1,000M 97Euro) 0 Export to Rest of World (1,000M 97Euro) 0.002526 Wage Rate (Thous NomEuro) 0.007013 2010 3.927 0.2654 0.2077 -0.05173 0.2071 1.657 0.1106 0.1106 2.277 0.3037 0.392 -0.00039 -0.00031 -8.60E-05 0.000619 0 0.000811 -0.06997 0.3736 0.005084 0 0.01323 0.01286 2017 3.543 0.2836 0.2607 -0.07393 0.2251 2.539 0.1014 0.1014 2.43 0.2983 0.4135 -0.00044 -0.00036 -0.00012 0.000627 0 0.000846 -0.08693 0.3852 0.00839 0 0.01989 0.01509 Table 3: The Effects of 1% Reduction in Transportation Costs in Andalucia, including an Access Increase of .5% and a Commuting Cost Decrease of .05% This is a simplified example. In a real example we would have to consider the building of the transportation infrastructure, the cost of maintenance and the source of the funding of the project. Also, if this project increases the transportation costs to and from other regions this would reduce the costs of other areas’ deliveries into Andalucia, in addition to Andalucia’s reduction of costs into these areas. In some industries this might increase Andalucian output, and in other areas it might reduce it. 27 Summary In this paper we have shown how looking at returns to structural-fund investments would increase the efficiency of the investment of these funds in achieving their objectives. We have also made the case for using a model that fully represents the structure of the economy to show the macro-economic effects of investments intended to change the structure of the local economy. 28 APPENDIX: Overview of the REMI Model6 OVERVIEW OF THE MODEL REMI Policy Insight is a structural economic-forecasting and policy-analysis model. It integrates methods from several other model types to help its users understand the total macroeconomic effects of policy decisions. It has the inter-industry detail available from input-output models. It allows for behavioral responses to housing and consumer prices, wages, and production costs as in computable general equilibrium models. Dynamic responses and other parameters are estimated using econometric methods. The agglomeration economies that are key to a region are represented using new economic geography theory. The model is dynamic, generating forecasts and simulations on an annual basis, and accounting for behavioral responses to wage, price, and other economic factors. While the REMI model comprises thousands of simultaneous equations, its structure is relatively straightforward. The exact number of equations varies depending on the extent of detail in the model. The overall structure of the model can be summarized in five major blocks: (1) output and demand, (2) labor and capital demand, (3) population and labor force, (4) wages, prices and costs, and (5) market shares. The blocks and their key interactions are shown in Figures 1 and 2. Figure 1 6 “The REMI Economic Geography Forecasting and Policy Analysis Model.” Treyz and Treyz. (2002). 29 Figure 2 The output block consists of output, demand, consumption, investment, government spending, exports, and imports, as well as feedback from output change due to the change in the productivity of intermediate inputs. The labor and capital demand block includes labor intensity and productivity as well as demand for labor and capital. The demographic block includes labor force participation rate and migration equations. The wages, prices and production costs block includes composite prices, determinants of production costs, the consumption price deflator, housing prices, and the wage equations. The market shares block includes the proportion of local, inter-regional and export markets captured by each region. Models can be built as single-region, multi-region, or multi-region national models. A region is defined broadly as a sub-national area, and could consist of a state, province, county or city, or any combination of sub-national areas. Within a large, multinational currency zone such as the European Union, models of a national economy can be built using the same economic framework employed in regional models. Single-region models consist of an individual region, called the home region. The rest of the nation is also represented in the model. However, since the home region is only a small part of the total nation, the changes in the region do not have an endogenous effect on the variables in the rest of the nation. 30 Multi-regional models have interactions among regions, such as trade and commuting flows. These interactions include trade flows from each region to each of the other regions. There are also multi-regional price and wage cost linkages. The average price in each of the regions depends on the production cost in each of the other regions plus the transportation to the region in question. Block 1. Output and Demand This block includes output, demand, consumption, investment, government spending, import, product access and export concepts. Output for each industry in the home region is determined by industry demand in all regions in the nation, the home region’s share of each market, and international exports from the region. For each industry, demand is determined by the amount of output, consumption, investment and capital demand on that industry. Consumption depends on real disposable income per capita, relative prices, differential income elasticities and population. Input productivity depends on access to inputs because with a larger choice set of inputs, it is more likely that the input with the specific characteristics required for the job will be formed. In the capital stock adjustment process, investment occurs to fill the difference between optimal and actual capital stock for residential, non-residential, and equipment investment. Government spending changes are determined by changes in the population. Block 2. Labor and Capital Demand The labor and capital demand block includes the determination of labor productivity, labor intensity and the optimal capital stocks. Industry-specific labor productivity depends on the availability of workers with differentiated skills for the occupations used in each industry. The occupational labor supply and commuting costs determine firms’ access to a specialized labor force. Labor intensity is determined by the cost of labor relative to the other factor inputs, capital and fuel. Demand for capital is driven by the optimal capital stock equation for both non-residential capital and equipment. Optimal capital stock for each industry depends on the relative cost of labor and capital, and the employment weighted by capital use for each industry. Employment in private industries is determined by the value added and employment per unit of value added in each industry. Block 3. Population and Labor Force The population and labor force block includes detailed demographic information about the region. Population data is given for age, gender and ethnic category, with birth and survival rates for each group. The size and labor force participation rate of each group determines the labor supply. These participation rates respond to changes in employment relative to the potential labor force and to changes in the real after-tax wage rate. Migration includes retirement, military, international and economic migration. Economic migration is determined by the relative real after-tax wage rate, relative employment opportunity and consumer access to variety. 31 Block 4. Wages, Prices and Costs This block includes delivered prices, consumer prices, housing prices, production costs, equipment costs, the consumption deflator, and the wage equation. Economic geography concepts account for the productivity and price effects of access to specialized labor, goods and services. These prices measure the price of the industry output, taking into account the access to production locations. This access is important due to the specialization of production that takes place within each industry, and because transportation and transaction costs of distance are significant. Composite prices for each industry are then calculated based on the production costs of supplying regions, the effective distance to these regions, and the index of access to the variety of output in the industry relative to the access by other uses of the product. The cost of production for each industry is determined by labor costs, capital costs, fuel costs, and intermediate inputs. Labor costs reflect a productivity adjustment to account for access to specialized labor, as well as underlying wage rates. Capital costs include costs of non-residential structures and equipment, while fuel costs incorporate electricity, natural gas and residual fuels. The consumption deflator converts industry prices to consumption commodity prices. For potential migrants, the consumer price is additionally calculated to include housing prices. Housing price changes depend on changes in income and population density. Wage changes are due to changes in labor supply and demand conditions, and changes in the national wage rate. Changes in occupational demand and employment opportunities relative to the labor force determine wage rates by industry. Block 5. Market Shares The market-shares equations measure the proportion of local and export markets that are captured by each industry. These depend on relative production costs, the estimated price elasticity of demand, and effective distance between the home region and each of the other regions. The change in share of a specific area in any region depends on changes in its delivered price and the quantity it produces compared with the same factors for competitors in that market. The share of local and external markets then drives the exports from and imports to the home economy. 32 REFERENCES An Evolutionary New Economic Geography Model; Wei Fan, Frederick Treyz and George Treyz; Journal of Regional Science, Vol. 40(4), 671-695; 2000. Migration, Regional Equilibrium, and the Estimation of Compensating Differentials; Michael Greenwood, Gary Hunt, Dan Rickman, George Treyz; American Economic Review, Vol. 81(5), 1382-1390; 1991. The REMI Economic-Demographic Forecasting and Simulation Model; G.I. Treyz, D.S. Rickman and G. Shao; International Regional Science Review 14(3), 1992:221-253. The REMI Geography Forecasting and Policy Analysis Model; Frederick Treyz and George Treyz; Copyright 2002. “A Comparison of the Four Economic Policy Analysis Models that Have Been Selected by the E.U. Commission for Structural Fund Evaluation.” By Frederick Treyz and George Treyz. REMI mimeo. “The Evaluation of Programs Aimed at Local and Regional Development: Methodology and Twenty Years of Experience Using REMI Policy Insight.” By Frederick Treyz, and George Treyz. Forthcoming OECD publication. “REMI Model Documentation: REMI Policy Insight.” Regional Economic Models, Inc. Copyright 2003.