Applied general equilibrium. A Classical - Keynesian - Schumpeterian approach. Oscar DE-JUAN University of Castilla – La Mancha Conference on Economic Growth and Distribution Luca, 16-18 June 2004 ------------------------Address: Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales 02071 Albacete (España) e-mail: oscar.dejuan@uclm.es Abstract. This paper sets the basis for a computable applied general equilibrium model (AGE), useful for policy evaluation and growth analysis. It is rooted on Classical, Keynesian and Schumpeterian traditions which seem naturally fitted for the purpose. Classical Political Economy was concerned with the analysis of the processes of production, distribution, consumption and accumulation (that brings about economic growth). The social accounting matrix (SAM) of section 2 is a fair reflection of this scheme, while the AGE model of the next two sections is supposed to explain the systems of prices and quantities there embedded. Reading vertically the first block we get the Sraffian prices of production than can also be expressed as Post-Keynesian administered prices. Reading horizontally we obtain the level and composition of output as a multiple of autonomous demand. This is nothing but Keynes’s principle of effective demand, where ‘animal spirits’ have been replaced by Schumpeterian innovative firms. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 1 1. Introduction. This paper presents the basic traits of a computable applied general equilibrium model. AGE models, to abridge, explain the system of prices and quantities embedded in the flows of production, distribution, consumption and accumulation embedded in a social accounting matrix (SAM). Once the parameters have been computed by different techniques (‘calibration’ being one of them) the model becomes a useful instrument for policy evaluation, impact analysis and the like. They allow us to compute the effects on the level and composition of output, employment or income distribution, associated to a variety of scenarios: - Major public expenditures like the European funds for regional development, which affect both the demand side and the supply side (productivity and costs). - Fiscal reforms, like the introduction of a tax or the substitution of the system for funding pensions. - Industrial and innovation policies that try to foster a particular sector. - Change in monetary policy or changes in international financial markets leading to a major shift of interest rates and exchange rates. - Energy shock that drills up the price of oil. - Effects of a major technical innovation like the diffusion of information and communication technologies. Our model, that is dynamic by nature, is aimed at explaining the sources and effects of economic growth. Which industries have played the role of locomotives? How much has productivity increased and what have been the required transformations in the capital/output ratio, the capital/labour ratio and the types of labour employed? AGE models has been a successful branch of Neoclassical economics since the early nineties: Kehoe & Kehoe (1994), Ginsburgh & Keyzer (2002), Kehoe, Srinivas & Whalley (2004) 1. The basis, no matter the heroic assumptions introduced to make the model computable by calibration, is Walrasian general equilibrium (Walras, 1871-74). Starting from given preferences, technology and endowments of capital and labour, the model determines the market clearing prices. Both production and consumption are represented by Cobb-Douglas functions that admit substitution of factors in production and substitution of goods in consumption. The real wage, the interest rate (identified with the rate of profit) and relative prices will change until the size and composition of output is such that warrants full employment, full capacity and utility maximization. AGE models can be built from different perspectives. Pyatt and Round (1979, 1985), Pyatt (1992) used the information contained in a SAM to derive fixed-priced multipliers useful for policy analysis. Neoclassical AGE tend to see these multipliers as a first step towards flexi-price models. We shall see, however, that for certain purposes the assumption of fixed prices is a more realistic one. Many years ago von Neumann (1945-46) studied how relative 1 In the Appendix of Ginsburgh& Keyzer, there is an introduction to GAMS software, which is the technique generally used for calibration. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 2 quantities and prices should be for the economy to achieve its potential rate of growth. The model does not describe the actual dynamics of capitalist economies, but it highlights certain equilibrium conditions and limits, that we shall take into account. Post-Keynesians have developed stock-flow models where financial variables influence the performance of the real sector (Godley, 2004). Although in this paper we focus on the real sector of the economy, we shall leave room for financial variables so that they can be used in other studies. The Cambridge Multisectoral Model (Barker & Petterson, 1987) was a successful combination of input-output techniques and econometrics, that we consider better than mere ‘calibration’ from the data of a SAM. Gibson & Seventer (2000) have developed recently a ‘structuralist’ AGE model comparable to the neoclassical one but allowing for unemployed resources. All of these models provide useful ideas. The model we are going to present here is based, however, in three major traditions in Economics: Classical, Keynesian and Schumpeterian. Let’s call it ‘Clakesch – AGE model’. Any model is particularly well suited for certain purposes. If we were asked to explain welfare gains we should refer the reader to the Neoclassical models derived from Walras and Pareto. But whenever we are asked to analyse the dynamics of a demand-constrained system, or to evaluate the impact of economic policies on output, employment and distribution, our Clakesch-AGE has competitive advantages. It is like playing at home a math of European football in a field designed for that purpose. Neoclassical AGE practitioners seem to play American football in a European football pitch. They are so many and so talented players, that one can expect some interesting results. It is our contention, however, that with the same effort the results would have been much more successful in a Clakesch -AGE model. The scheme of the paper is as follows. In section 2 we present the basic SAM suggested by the United Nations (1993). This SAM (and, indeed, the whole system of national accounts), reflects faithfully the processes of production, distribution, consumption and accumulation, envisaged in Classical Political Economy. In section 3 we decipher the Classical-Sraffian prices of production embedded in the first vertical block of the SAM (i.e. in the inputoutput table by industries). In parallel we explain distributive variables and the general price level. In section 4 we read horizontally the SAM to figure out the quantity system. The super-multiplier we derive from a compact SAM will allow us to compute the level of composition of output associated to a particular vector of autonomous demand. This is nothing but Keynes’s and Kalecki’s ‘principle of effective demand’ (Keynes, 1936; Kalecki, 1971). Schumpeter (1912) fills the vector of autonomous demand and explains why and how it moves forward. By launching into new goods, new processes and new markets (exports included here), the innovative firms become the driving force of the system and the ordinary vehicle of technical change. This approach makes clear that the locomotives of the economy are located in particular industries and backs the need of a disaggregated analysis of the economy following the paths opened by Leontief’s (Dietzenbacher & Lahr, 2004) and Stone’s (1981). In the last section we summarize the peculiarities of our Clakesch – AGE model contrasting them with the Neoclassical one. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 3 2. A social accounting matrix for a growing economy. Social accounting matrices (SAM) reflect the transactions (accounts) between activities, factors and institutions. The advantage of SAM over other national accounting techniques is that they present in full detail the production, distribution and expenditure relationships among a huge number of agents. The United Nations Statistics Division (1993) grants researchers freedom to design a SAM in the way most convenient for their specific purposes. The basic scheme they suggest fits perfectly our purposes. In this section we shall remind this scheme justifying a handful of personal options. A) Activities as industries producing goods. We identify industries with goods. This assumption does not deny the possibility of joint production. It simply implies the possibility to obtain a symmetric matrix for inter-industry transactions (, in Table 1), where the number of columns (industries) coincides with the number of rows (goods). Disaggregation by industries should be as large as possible. According to their economic nature, we should separate four groups: (1) intermediate goods and services (energy, raw materials, industrial goods, services to enterprises…); (2) fixed capital goods by type (big infra-structures, structures, equipment, industrial vehicles and houses); (3) goods and services for final consumption classified by function (food, clothing, personal services,…); (4) collective services provided by government. B) Factors of production and primary distribution of income. In Classical Political Economy, labour is the only factor of production, properly speaking. It receives incomes according to the wage stipulated in the labour contract. Working with a SAM, it is easy to introduce different types of employees each one receiving a specific kind of income. The rest of value added constitutes an “operating surplus”, attached to the firms until it is “redistributed” into taxes, interest payments, rents, dividends, reserves and depreciation allowances. 2 C) Institutions and expenditures. a. Non financial corporations or “firms” (F). They accumulate reserves and decide investment. To simplify notation, we can identify them with industries (1, 2 … n), which add up to F. 2 Capital depreciation is a difficult issue to tackle with. The best account differentiates capital goods by type and age, using the scheme of “joint production” (Lager, 1997). A simpler alternative supposes that capital goods are replaced after a period (different in each industry and for each commodity). To provide for such replacement, firms retain ‘depreciation allowances’ purchasing financial assets. There is still a simplest alternative that we are going to use in this paper only for the purpose to alleviate the exposition. We add up intermediate consumption and fixed capital consumption. We are imagining that firms devote a portion of labour and goods to repair fixed capital. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 4 b. Financial institutions (B). They relate agents with capacity to finance and agents in need of finance. The key distinction separates “monetary financial institutions” (the banking sector) and “non-monetary financial institutions” (mutual and pension funds). To abridge we shall refer to both as B. c. Households (H). For our purposes it is convenient to differentiate households according to their income source and expenditure patterns. H1 would represent, for instance, households of non-qualified workers, whose income is rather low and devoted entirely to consumption. H2 stands for households of qualified workers with medium incomes, most of them consumed in a basket that includes luxury goods. H3 for households of managers, self-employed, property income recipients; a substantial part of such incomes is supposed to be saved; in their consumption basket, luxury goods are quite important. Hp for households of pensioners and other transfers recipients, whose expenditure patterns are similar to H1. d. Government (G). By means of taxes and transfers, it pays a key role in the redistribution of income. It is also conceived as an ‘industry’ providing free social services. e. Rest of the world (RW). A useful classification would distinguish between foreign countries with our same currency (rest of Europe) and foreign countries with a different currency (rest of the world, Europe excluded). The exchange rate is defined as e = dollars / euro. An appreciation of the euro would be reflected in an increase in e. D) Accounts. The flows among industries, factors and institutions are classified (according to the economic nature) in the following accounts. a. Production account. The traditional input-output table is included in the first block of Table 1. The rows inform about the sale of outputs; the columns about the purchase of inputs. ‘Value added’, i.e. payment to the primary factors of production, makes the balance. b. Income or current account. Rows in the second block inform about the origin of incomes (distribution of primary incomes and redistribution). Columns indicate the allocation of disposable income into final consumption and savings. c. Accumulation or capital account. With the savings and transfers of capital (rows in third block), firms finance their investments separated by industries and types of capital goods. Households invest in houses. d. Finance account. It informs about the flows of funds from creditors to debtors (usually intermediated by banks). To simplify the making of Table 1, we have grouped them into a single row with positive figures for borrowing and negative figures for lending. We distinguish five types of financial assets: FA1: cash and bank deposits; FA2: bills; FA3: bonds (medium and long term); FA4: equities; FA5: bank loans. e. Balance of payments with the rest of the world. Transaction with the rest of the world (current, capital and finance) are gathered in the last vertical block. The inflow of foreign currency (exports of goods and services, for instance) bear a positive sing. The outflow of foreign De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 5 currency associated to imports, loans from the rest of the world and so on, are treated as negative. 3 E) Satellite accounts (and complementary information). The combination of flows and stocks improves the usefulness of a Sam. The following ‘balances’ or ‘stocks tables’ will proof to be very convenient. a. Tables gathering informations about total population (by age, sex and level of studies), working population, etc. b. Labour matrix (L) with so many columns as industries and so many rows as types of labour (non qualified labour, qualified labour, managers…). c. Fixed capital matrix (K) with so many columns as industries and so many rows as capital goods (big infra-estructures, structures, equipment, industrial vehicles, houses). At the time of gathering the information it would be convenient to specify the degree of capacity utilization of the capital installed. d. Balance sheet of outstanding financial assets (FA1 to FA5). The most liquid ones are identified with ‘money’ (FA1=M3). The most illiquid ones (bonds and equities) represent certain rights upon the real capital of the economy (our table K). 3.Prices and distribution in a capitalist economy. Competition forces firms to introduce the best available techniques, to use capacity at the optimal level and to adjust prices to the production costs (which includes a normal and general profit rate on the value of capital invested). Sraffa (1960), inspired in the Classical-Marxian tradition, built the system of equations leading to such prices. He proves, that given technology and the real wage, we can determine a unique vector of relative prices (in terms of a chosen numeraire) and the general rate of profit. Before expounded the price equations let us comment on the ‘givens’, i.e. technology and the real wage. A) Technology. Our production functions are directly taken from the first vertical block of the SAM that corresponds to an input-output table (IOT). They are Leontief’s production functions with constant technical coefficients. Entrepreneurs are free to choose among different techniques, but, once the choice has been done, they cannot combine at will inputs and factors of production. Constant returns to scale are also assumed. In the short run, as a mechanism of adjustment to demand fluctuations, entrepreneurs may change the degree of capacity utilization (capital / output ratio). But using capital more hours a day implies hiring extra labour, so the degree of mechanization (capital / labour ratio) remains constant. Technology is materialized in the following sets of data. The ‘rest of the world sector’ is traditionally represented by a column for exports and a row for imports (and the like). The advantage of row-column system is that it follows the same accounting principles as the rest of accounts and it makes easier the treatment of tariffs. The advantage of the column system is that it simplifies the presentation of the SAM and allows seeing the balance of payments at a glance. Tariffs would be included in the price of imports and in the current account (payments from the rest of the world to government). 3 De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 6 (a) A matrix of intermediate goods coefficients: A qˆ 1 . This is a square matrix n·n, n being the number of industries. 4 We can separate domestic from imported intermediate tables (d, m) and compute two different matrices of technical coefficients (Ad, Am). 5 Let ˆ be a diagonal matrix indicating the percentages of imports for each good. These percentages reflect price elasticity of imports and are bound to change with the ratio domestic price / international price. Our previous matrix A can be segmented in two: Am A·ˆ and Ad AI . (b) A rectangular matrix of labour coefficients: l L qˆ 1 . The matrix has so many columns as industries and so many rows as types of labour. (c) A rectangular matrix of capital coefficients: k K qˆ 1 , with so many rows as capital goods. Note that these figures reflect the normal or desired capital / output coefficients. B) Distribution. Workers consider as a social conquest the real wage achieved in the past (wr). In the yearly wage agreements, trade unions will try to consolidate it, fixing the nominal wage (w) such that: wt=wt-1+, ( being the expected or targeted inflation for year t). Historically, the real wage has risen pari passu with productivity, so we can expect that trade unions will claim for further increases in the nominal wage proportional to productivity gains. Tensions in the labour market (reflected by percent deviations of the employment rate () from its conventional value) will encourage trade unions to demand further increases in nominal wages. 6 [1] wt wt 1 f (ˆ ) f ' (ˆ ) In the previous equation wt refers to the nominal wage in year t for the basic labour category (let say, ‘non qualified labour’). Other types of labour will earn a 4 To make easier our presentation, we shall assume that the information supporting the IOT allows us to separate prices and quantities. The first industry, for instance, produces 5 million tones of cereal, each tone worth 8.000 euros. If one tone compost (industry 2) worth 10,000 euros is required for that purpose, the technical coefficient a21 will be 1/5=0,2. In practice we just know that the gross output of industry 1 amounts to 4,000 million euros. If we divide all the cells in the first column of by 4,000 we obtain technical coefficients in value terms, for instance a’21 = 10,000/8,000 = 1,25. All the formulas would be similar, although they apply to different physical units. By construction, at time 0 all the prices would be 1. They do not refer, however, to 1 tone of cereal, 1 tone of iron and 1 machine, but to an imprecise numbers of tones and machines. 5 IOT of European countries usually separate import from other European countries (in euros) and imports from the rest of the world (in dollars). This is the type of information that best fits our purposes. The price of imports should include tariffs and all types of taxes. 6 Alternatively, we could refer (changing the sign) to deviations from the conventional unemployment rate. Notice that there is not a ‘natural’ employment or unemployment rate marking a long period equilibrium. It is just an historical position that is bound to change with aggregate demand fluctuations. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 7 multiple of it, a multiple that is supposed to be constant except for the periods where there are excesses or shortages of a particular type of labour. The rate of profit is obtained in parallel to the prices of production. Relative prices vary, precisely, to make possible that the ‘representative’ firm of each industry obtains the normal rate of profit on the capital advanced (r). 7 The interest rate is another distributive variable. For our purposes (analysis of the economy of a country or region within Europe) both the interest rate and the exchange rate can be taken as given. 8 C) Prices of production, administered prices and inflation. Now we are in conditions to derive the Sraffian system of prices of production corresponding to a competitive capitalist economy. It results form a vertical reading of the matrices of direct coefficients. 9 The price of production of any commodity appears can be presented as a multiple of the unit labour cost, although it is a complex multiplier that mixes technical and distributive variables. [2] p p·A wr ·l r·( p·k ) wr ·l ·I A r·k 1 Post-Keynesian economists have a preference for administered prices. Entrepreneurs set prices marking-up primary costs, expressed in monetary units (w, for nominal wage, instead of wr). The rate of profit on fixed capital (r) 7 We assume that only fix capital is properly advanced. Intermediate consumption and wages are paid regularly out of sales proceeds. By ‘representative’ firms we mean the one using the best available technology. Probably a handful of innovative firms are using more productive technologies protected by patents and the like. A bulk of firms may be using old-fashioned technology until they replace capital or quit the industry. Note, that whenever we compute technological coefficients by calibration from IOT, we refer to the average technology in the industry. 8 Note that in the treatment of the rate of profit and interest rate we depart from Sraffian tradition. The equations of prices of production, after choosing the numeraire, have one degree of freedom; it can be either the real wage or the rate of profit. Sraffa (1960) starts the book referring to the first one. But he shifts later on to the second variable, saying that the rate of profit (identified with the interest rate) is a ‘pure number’ that can be defined without reference to any numeraire. Pivetti (1991) justifies such an option. In our opinion, there is no problem with the real wage and there are negative implications associated to the second one: it implies the identification of the rate of profit and the rate of interest. Following the Classical-Marxian tradition (usually well summarized by Kalecki) we accept their mutual independence. There is not such a thing as a ‘long run real interest rate’, determined by the rate of profit; but neither can we expect that the rate of profit will follow the movements of the rate of interest. We can simply refer to the ‘conventional interest rate’, the one that has ruled in the past and is expected to rule in the future. Such convention can be influenced by a persistent monetary policy by the Central Bank, who sets the interest rate in money markets. For studies centered in the European economy, the interest rate should be an endogenous variable related to the conventional rate, the base rate fixed by Central Bank and the tensions in the financial markets. The exchange rate would be another variable to take into account and should be explained in parallel to interest rates. 9 Taxes and tariffs can be added (to this and the following formulas) by multiplying the relevant distributive variables by (1+t). De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 8 is substituted by a profit margin or mark-up on circulating capital, which appears as a diagonal matrix <I+b>.10 We have also separated domestic and imported intermediate goods. 11 Both formulas are legitimate and compatible provided the mark-up depends on the sectoral degree of mechanization. The higher the capital / labour ratio, the higher has to be the sectoral mark-up on circulating capital in order to get a normal rate of profit on fixed capital. In a capitalist economy long term mark-ups are forged by competition and the divergence among them can be taken as given for the usual time span of input-output tables (five years). Marks up may be sensible to the degree of capacity utilization, but here we are interested in the basic structure of administered prices (pa) that consider the average mark-up over the cycle (b). [3] pa pa Ad pm ·Am w·l · I b The use of administered prices has practical advantages. First, they provide a way to skip the fixed capital matrix: when it exists, is not very reliable. Second, it provides a formula to figure out the general level of prices (P). In the preceding formula we have just to substitute l by l’= total labour / final output; and Am by A’m = value of imports / final output. The mark-up b’ would be the share of profits in income. [4] P ( p m ·Am' w·l ' )·(1 b' ) Inflation is a cost-push phenomenon. It may reflect a pure distributive conflict (higher economic power exercised by trade unions, domestic entrepreneurs and international providers of row materials) or demand pressures in a fast growing economy (a transient phenomenon that could be endogeneized in our model). The dynamics of the price level can be represented by the following equation: [5] Pˆ ˆ ˆ bˆ Inflation has a trend element, which nowadays can be safely identified with the rate targeted by the Central Bank (). If nominal wages rise at a rate ˆ , inflation expectations will be confirmed ( P̂ ). Inflation will be higher than targeted in the following cases. (a) the increase of nominal wages exceeds the previous rate: ˆ wˆ ( ˆ ) is positive; (b) the euro cost of imports rises( ˆ 0 ), either because the dollar price of imports increases or the euro depreciates; (c) the aggregate mark-up rises (b > 0). D) Market prices and demand. 10 11 We shall represent diagonal matrices by angular brackets or a circumflex. The value in euros of imported row materials (and the like) is pm·Am, where pm= $pm /e (e defined as dollars per euro). De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 9 So far we have just considered supply forces. Markets prices are supposed to reflect both supply and demand. In principle, excesses of demand will push prices up. But this is a transient phenomenon since higher prices and profits in industry j will attract investments, production will rise cancelling out the excesses of demand for commodity j, relative prices will return to the long run equilibrium determined by production costs. This is the theoretical scheme. In practice only a handful of primary products (oil and row materials, in particular) are sensitive to demand, as Post-Keynesians have repeatedly showed after Sylos-Labini (1957). Such prices are determined abroad and are taken as data in our model. In an advanced industrial economy, the bulk of industries are prepared to accommodate demand shocks piling inventories and adjusting capacity utilization. In services there is not such a possibility but the risk of loosing customers by continuous changes in prices has convinced entrepreneurs to maintain prices in their long run equilibrium, marked by costs of production.12 We can take for sure –a key conclusion for our purposes– that in an advanced industrial economy relative prices are not influenced by the ordinary ups and downs of demand. 4. Output and growth in a demand-constrained system. In section 3 we have seen that a vertical reading of the first block of the SAM leads to the Sraffian system of prices of production or to Post-Keynesian administered prices. We can expect that competition in a capitalist economy will enforce such prices. In a similar vein, a horizontal reading of the SAM would provide us with a system of quantities. It was implicit in the Classical equations (Kurz and Salvadori, 1998; Nell, 1998, 2004). And it was the core of von Neumann (1945-46) general equilibrium. Both models provide useful hints for understanding certain equilibrium conditions and certain limits. 13 But they do not describe properly the working of a capitalist economy that it is supposed to be a demand constrained system. According to the Keynesian principle of effective demand, the equilibrium level of output at a given moment does not depend on the productive capacities of the economy but on the expected demand at normal prices (Keynes, 1936; Kalecki, 1971; Kornai, 1979). It can be expressed as a multiple of the autonomous demand expected for the period under consideration. In the simplest Keynesian model, the multiplicand is identified with investment, and the multiplier with the inverse of the propensity to save. After an increase in investment expenditures, output will growth until the savings stemming from the new incomes match the new investments: S=I. In this section we are going to translate the principle of effective demand to a multisectorial growing economy. Our first task is to separate autonomous from induced demand, in order to endogeneize the second kind of flows and derive a ‘super-multiplier’. Autonomous demand is independent of income. Their main elements are identified in the last column of Table 2: exports, 12 13 NeoKeynesian literature explains this phenomenon under the heading of ‘menu costs’. A couple of examples will suffice. (1) The growth of the system is limited by the basic input whose production is growing more slowly. (2) The golden rule is achieved when the rate of growth and the rate of profit coincide. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 10 government real expenditures, modernization investment, private expenditures financed out of current or capital transfers. To make possible the expected increases in autonomous demand, firms are supposed to demand intermediate goods, to hire labourers (who will consume a significant proportion of their new incomes) and to purchase new capital goods to expand capacity. Production will adjust to aggregate demand (autonomous plus induced). It will rise until the new ‘uncommitted incomes’ ( = incomes not devoted systematically to consumption or expansionary investment) match the value of autonomous demand (Z). Table 3 makes clear such process emphasizing that it is Z which determines . A brief review of the components of aggregate demand will illuminate some points. Table 2 Table 3 A) Autonomous demand. (a) Exports. For small open economies, exports constitute the main element of autonomous demand. Exports are supposed to depend on the rate of growth of the international economy and the exchange rate. Both variables are exogenous to our model. But there are a couple of endogenous determinants: the relative prices of tradable goods and the general level of prices. Any AGE model is supposed to introduce the price elasticity of exports and imports. In our Clakesch model this is the single most important link between prices and quantities. (b) Government expenditures. Public consumption and public investment are policy instruments and, for this reason, autonomous. The same can be said about current and capital government transfers that feed autonomous private expenditures (whether for consumption or investment). Autonomous means independent of current income. Such expenditures, however, are influenced by other variables determined by the model or that can be figured out with the information provided by the SAM and satellite accounts (population by age, unemployment rate, etc.). (c) Modernization investment. Innovative entrepreneurs compete (or try to escape from competition) by introducing new goods either for consumption or for investment. The new capital goods are the ordinary vehicle of technical change, although it may take several years to perceive their effects. Let’s call ‘modernization investment’ the expenditures involved in the the production of these new goods. Schumpeter (1912) made clear that innovations usually come out in clusters and that new products call for complementary ones, at the time they displace old-fashioned substitutes (‘creative destruction’). The diffusion of new products follows usually a ‘logistic curve’. After the introduction of the product, demand accelerates; latter it decelerates and even stagnates when the market becomes saturated. Among the determinants of innovation and modernization investment we should consider competitive pressures, physical capital, human capital and other facilities. Financial conditions do also matter, by speeding up or slowing down the implementation of investment De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 11 decisions. In the next section we shall refer briefly to changes in interest rates. Let us comment here on the importance of differential profits rates. A higher than normal profit rate (ri>r) provides a stimulus for investment and allows funding it in a non-risky way (i.e. out of profits). External finance becomes also more accessible since funds can be raised in better conditions. B) Induced demand. (a) Induced or expansionary investment. Firms expand capacity so that the expected increases in demand are matched efficiently, i.e. using capacity at the desired degree (expressed by the equality between the actual capital (output ratio (kt) and the desired one (k). Investment will be k times the expected increased in demand, to which production adjust. For the economy as a whole we get: I=k·g·Y. This is the well-known accelerator principle. 14 Expression [6] presents the basic steps we should cover to obtain domestic induced investment. I i" k · g · q [6] I i' I E k ·I i" ~ I i I h·i ·I i' I i ,d I ·I i Some observations will help understanding the preceding equations. 1. In our disaggregated economy [k] is a matrix with so many columns as industries and so many rows as capital goods. Net output (Y) is replaced by a diagonal matrix of sectoral total outputs <q>, whose expected rates of growth appear also as a diagonal matrix <g>. The combination of these three matrices provides us the basic investment decision (I”) formalized in the first equation of [6]. 2. By construction, the driving force of the economy lies in the expected rates of growth of autonomous demand (column vector gz). Firms, however, cannot predict changes in gz, they rely in the path of growth of demand for their products (g). In doing so, excesses of capacity (negative or positive) are bound to occur (Ek) any time there is a variation in gz. They should be subtracted form I” as it is indicated in the second equation (and explained in De Juan 2004). 3. The accelerator should be flexibilized by distinguishing between investment decisions and investment expenditures. The first ones are based on the conventional rate of interest (i*), the one that has ruled in the past and is supposed to continue in the foreseeable future. Temporal deviations may speed up investment expenditures (if negatives) or slow them down (if positives). Investment decisions may be altered by the ~ ~ term h·i , being i (i i * ) / i * and h a positive parameter (apparently quite small). 14 As far as we know there are not many attempts to endogeneize investment in a multisectoral model. Leontief (1970) and Lager (1997) are the exceptions, although their objectives are different from ours. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 12 4. In impact analysis we are not concerned with total expenditures but with domestic ones. To obtain induced domestic investment (Ii,d) we should pre-multiply Ii by the diagonal matrix <I->. , as we know, indicates the proportion imported for each commodity. Such proportion reflects the price elasticity of imports and will vary with the real exchange rate. (b) Induced consumption. In The General Theory, Keynes assumed that the bulk of private consumption depends on household disposable income. The hypothesis was verified at that time and has been ratified ever since. In the second half of the 20th century the propensity to consume of households has been quite high and stable. Kalecki contributed to the discussion suggesting that the aggregate propensity to consume was a weighted average of the propensities of different income groups. Our SAM allows us to present different social groups, each one characterized by a particular propensity to consume and a particular consumption basket. De-Juan, Cadarso & Córcoles (1994) presents an induced domestic consumption matrix (Cid) that, once more, we shall approach in several steps. [7] Ci nn Ci ' nn DC nh · PC hh ·VAhn I VAT nn ·DC nh · PC hh · I T y ·VA TR hn hh C id I ·C i Our point of departure is the matrix of value added or primary incomes [VA] with so many rows as income groups (h) and so many columns as industries (n). Pre-multiplying by <PC> we obtain the incomes systematically consumed. In the diagonal of <PC> we find the consumption propensities of the different income groups. [DC] indicates the distribution of consumption expenditures among goods. 15 It is a rectangular matrix with n rows (each one for any consumption product), and h columns (each one for each social group). By construction, any column of [DC] adds up to 1. In the first equation in [7] we have abstracted from transfers and taxes. In the second equation we introduce current transfers (TR) and income taxes (Ty) to obtain disposable income. To express consumption in ‘base prices’ (as the rest of the SAM), we discount the value added tax (VAT). In the last equation we pre-multiply the previous result by <I-> in order to get domestic induced consumption. . Our model is prepared to introduce the influence of prices in the distribution of consumption among different goods, the influence of interest rate on the propensities to consume (or save) and wealth effects. We are not going to do so because empirically these new variables add very little. Cambridge multisectoral model has shown that linear expenditure functions, similar to the 15 Information about propensities to consume and expenditure patterns can be obtained from family budget statistics. The problem is that the consumption functions of such statistics do not coincide with the consumption goods contemplated in input – output tables. A bridge is necessary to join both statistics. Econometrics will help to fill up certain gaps. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 13 ones we have used here, explain consumption better than any other. (Barker & Petterson, 1987, following Stone’s suggestions). Changes in prices might affect the substitution in consumption between, let’s say, two types of meat, but not between food and dressing, that is the level we are considering in a SAM. C) Multipliers. At this moment we are in conditions to determine the equilibrium level of output corresponding to a vector of autonomous demand (Zt) and the super-multiplier that captures induced consumption and induced investment. First we obtain the enlarged interindustry transaction table (*), adding up the tables of intermediate consumptions (d), final induced consumption (Cid) and final induced investment (Iid). Second, we divide the cells of each column by the total output of the industry to obtain the enlarged matrix of coefficients (A*d). Third we compute a Leontief’s inverse to obtain MQ. [8] *d d Ci ,d I i ,d [9] Ad* *d ·qˆ 1 [10] MQ I Ad* 1 MQ is the multiplier of total output. Like Miyazawa-Maseegui (1963) and Kurz (1992) it ties together the Classical and Keynesian traditions. Like Hicks (1950) it adds up induced consumption and induced investment. And like Pyat and Round (1979) it is derived from a SAM and presented in a disaggregated fashion.16 Each column of the super-multiplier matrix informs us about the direct and indirect effects of a unitary expansion of industry j over the output of all the industries that provide resources to j. The provision may be in a direct or indirect way, and the “resources” are defined in the broadest sense so to include intermediate goods, final consumption goods of new hired workers, and fixed capital goods to expand capacity at the required rate. Economists are generally less interested in total output (that includes intermediate goods) than in final output (Y), income (VA) or employment (L). Table 4 explains how to obtain the corresponding super-multipliers MY, MV, ML. 17 Table 4 16 The format is not similar. Traditional input-output multipliers and SAM multipliers are built adding up additional columns and rows to the original transaction matrix. Our enlargement consists in increasing the values of the cells of the original n·n matrix. 17 The formulas, as they appear, compute the effects on gross final output and gross income. To obtain the multipliers of net output and income, we should have previously endogeneized depreciation. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 14 D) Theory of output and policy evaluation. One of the fundamental issues of Economics is the explanation of the level and composition of output in a given moment (t) and its growth. Given the vector of autonomous demand (and its rate of growth) and once the super-multiplier has been computed, the answer is straightforward. With reference to total output we can write: [11] q t I A* 1 ·Z t MQ·Z t . qt MQ·Z t MQ·g z ·Z t The same scheme may be useful for policy evaluation. If we are asked about the effects of European structural funds on a country and a period (not necessarily a year), we have to consider the second equation and change the elements of vector Z where public expenditure impinges on. Usually the impact on autonomous demand requires a previous analysis. Unemployment benefits, for instance, will rise private autonomous consumption distributed among consumption goods following a specific pattern. Certain reforms may modify both the multiplicand and the multiplier. Think in a reduction of tariffs. Exports (an important element of Z) will rise according to price elasticity. But imports will also rise, at the expenses of domestic demand. A change in and the multiplier seems unavoidable. In the case of major reforms the general level of prices and relative prices may be affected, which would oblige us to a second round of computations. Imagine, for instance, a complete abolition of tariffs when the country joins a free trade association. Imagine that exports rise much more than imports and push capacity far above the normal level, causing a rise in the general level of prices. Inflation usually conveys a real appreciation of the exchange rate so in the second round we should compute the effects of a fall in exports and a rise of imports. Trade liberalization also implies a rise in productivity that affects relative prices. All these effects can be analysed by a Clakesch - AGE models and treated in different scenarios. 5. Conclusions (by way of contrast). In this paper we have developed an applied general equilibrium model, rooted on the Classical, Keynesian and Schumpeterian traditions, as an alternative to the Neoclassical paradigm developed in the early nineties. A direct contrast between them may help a deeper understanding of both of them. Table 5 shows the different sets of data. It is obvious that our model needs more information from outside. This apparent weakness may become a strength, since it grants more degrees of freedom and allows the researcher to introduce institutional and historical or ‘path dependent’ variables. The system may operate for different levels of wages (real and nominal), rates of interest, exchange rates, inflation rates … The ones which have ruled in the past may become ‘conventional’ and influence economic behaviour. (Of course they may also change and agents should adapt to the new outcomes). De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 15 Table 5 The differences in the data, are a reflection of the different conceptions about the working of a capitalist economy and the meaning of economic equilibrium. Neoclassical AGE models, not less than Walras seminal book, are supply constrained and static in nature. They take as given certain endowments of capital and labour and solve for the prices that warrant full capacity and full employment in the production of the set of goods which maximizes consumers’ utility. Prices are ‘market clearing’ and ‘efficient’. Our Clakesch model is interested in the dynamics of a demand-constrained system. The vector of autonomous demand emerges as the driving force of output and employment. Although in the preceding table it is just one element of autonomous demand, it influences, loosely, the others. It is, indeed, the main vehicle of technical change, which brings about productivity gains and, later on, real wage increases. The effects from the demand side are not less important. A cluster of innovations with important diffusion and dragging effects (the last ones captured by the super-multiplier) will bring about a long wave of prosperity. When the market for new products becomes saturated, and no other innovations take the relay, we can expect a big recession. Relative prices play a crucial role in both models. While the Neoclassical model focuses on allocation of given resources; the Clakesch model emphasizes dynamic issue related to innovation and technical change. The innovative sectors enjoying higher rates of return will attract new savings until competence establish the new set of prices of production. Market prices may help to restore the equilibrium after a shift of demand from commodity a to b. In our advanced economies, however, technology makes possible and desirable the adjustment via quantities instead of prices. Firms willing to increase their market-share in industry b and the mass of profits associated to such expansion, will react as follows. In the short run they will math the growing demand by depleting inventories and pushing up the degree of capacity utilization. Later on they will expand capacity via investment. The contrary will happen in industry a. Eventually, the excesses of demand may disappear; markets will clear and firms will get the normal, uniform rate of profit. 18 Being capacity utilization the basic mechanism of short-term adjustments, we can expect that most of the time the ratio capital / output will be above or below the normal or desired position. But since it affects profitability, firms will try at any moment (via investment) to adjust capacity. It is in this sense that we refer to long-period equilibrium. It will be effectively achieved if the rate of growth of autonomous demand remains constant for a sufficient time. Unemployment, on the contrary, does not affect firms’ profitability and can endure for good. We can refer to a ‘historical’ rate of unemployment, but there is nothing ‘natural’ in it. The rate may be halved in a couple of years if autonomous demand resumes at a higher rate of growth. 18 Walrasian prices warrant the same results. But this is not the case in Neoclassical AGE models. In the way prices equations stand, there is no warranty that (after a change in wages, taxes or demand) the new prices ensure a uniform rate of profit. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 16 These hypothesis justify the super-multiplier proposed in section 5 as a tool for policy evaluation and growth analysis. The results will disappoint economists trained in Neoclassical AGE models. They started with social accounting matrices and the fixed-price multipliers derived from them (Pyat & Round 1979, 1985). But this was only a first step. Soon they shifted to AGE models where prices are flexible and have an impact on the quantities supplied and demanded. Are we pretending to go back to fixed-price multipliers? The answer is ‘not’ and ‘yes’ at the same time. For sure our Clakesch model is prepared to answer the traditional questions of flexi-price multipliers. A Clakesch model is also prepared to account for price effects, wealth effects and the like linked to an expansion or contraction in demand. In the same way that we have allowed substitution between domestic and foreign goods, we could consider substitution among factors of production and consumption goods. But are they possible and are they important in practice? Once fixed capital has been installed, will entrepreneurs alter the numbers of workers attached to any machine after a wage increase? Will consumers alter the allocation of income between, let say, food and clothing, when relative prices change? In our opinion, these questions have to be answered in the negative. If so, the fixedprice super-multiplier is not a weakness but a sensible way to approach economic reality in advanced capitalist economies. References Barker, T. & Peterson, W. (1987): Cambridge Multisectoral Dynamic Model of the British Economy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. De-Juan, O.; Cadarso, M.A. & Córcoles, C. (1994): “Multiplicadores inputoutput kaleckianos: una estimación a partir de la tabla input-output española de 1990”, Economía Industrial, n. 298, p. 129-144. De-Juan, O. (2004): “Paths of accumulation and growth. Towards a Keynesian long-period theory of output”, Review of Political Economy, (accepted for publication). Dietzenbacher, E. & Lahr, M. (eds) (2004): Wassily Leontief and Input-Output Economics, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Gibson, B. & Seventer, D. van (2000): “A Tale of Two Models: comparing structuralist and neoclassical computable general equilibrium models for South Africa”, International Review of Applied Economics, Volume 14, Number 2 / May 1, 2000 Ginsburgh, V. & Keyzer, M (2002): The Structure of Applied General Equilibrium Models, Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press. Godley, W. (2004): “Towards a reconstruction of Macroeconomics using a stock flow consistent (SFC) model”, Unpublished paper presented at CERF, Cambridge Hicks, J.R. (1950) A Contribution to the Trade Cycle, (Oxford, Clarendon Press). Kalecki, M. (1971): Selected essays on the dynamics of the capitalist economy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. (papers written between 19331970). Kehoe, P. & Kehoe, T. (1994): “A Primer on AGE Models”¸ Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, v. 18, n2, pp. 2-16. (Available in http://www.minneapolisfed.org). De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 17 Kehoe, t. Srinivasan, T. & Whalley, J. (eds) (2004): Frontiers in Applied General Equilibrium Modelling, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Keynes, J.M. (1936): The general theory of employment, interest and money, London Macmillan. Kornai, J. (1979): “Resource-constrained versus demand-constrained systems”, Econometrica, v. 47, n. 4, p. 801-819. Kurz, H.D.(1985): “Effective demand in a “classical” model of value and distribution: the multiplier in a Sraffian framework”, Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, v. LIII (2), June, p. 121-37. Kurz, H. & Salvadory, N. (1998): Understanding ‚’Classical’ Economics: Studies in long-period Theory, London, Routledge. Lager, C. (1997): “Treatment of fixed capital in the Sraffian framework and in the theory of dynamic input-output models”, Economic Systems Research, v. 9, n. 4, p. 357-373. Leontief, W. (1970): “The dynamic inverse”, in Carter & Bródy (eds.): Contributions to input-output analysis, Amsterdam, North Holland, c. 1, pp. 17-46. Miyazawa, K. & Masegi, S. (1963): “Interindustry analysis and the structure of income distribution”, Metroeconomica, v. 15, n. 2-3, p. 161-95. Nell, E. J. (1998): The General Theory of Transformational Growth, (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press). Nell, E.J. (2004): “Monetising the Classical Equations: a theory of circulation”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, n. 28, pp. 173-203. Pivetti, M. (1991): An essay on money and distribution, London, Macmillan. Pyatt, G. (1991): “Fundamentals of Social Accounting”, Economic Systems Research, 3, pp. 315-341. Pyatt, G. & Round, J. (1979): “Accounting and fixed price multipliers in a social accounting matrix framework”, The Economic Journal, n. 89, p. 850-873. Pyatt, G. & Round, J. (eds.)(1985): Social Accounting Matrices. A basis for Planning, Washington, DC. The World Bank. Schumpeter, J. (1912): Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, Munich, Verlag Dunker & Humbolt. Sraffa, P. (1960): Production of commodities by means of commodities. Prelude to a critique of economic theory, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Stone, R. (1981): Aspects of Economics and Social Modelling, Geneve, Libraire Droz. Sylos-Labini, P. (1957): Oligopolio e progresso tecnico, Milano, Dott A. Giuffrè. United Nations Statistics Division (1993): National Accounts, New York. (Available in the web of the organization: http://unstats.un.org/unsd/sna1993). Von Neumann, J. (1945-6): “A model of general equilibrium”, The Review of Economic Studies, v. XIII, p. 1-9. (Original German paper of 1938). Walras, L. (1889): Eléments d’économie politique pure, Lausanne, F. Rouge. De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model PRODUCTION (Input / output) INCOME distribution / consumption ACCUMULATION (Savings / investment) FINANCE (+ , -) total 1 2 ... n W R F H G 1, 2... F H G B FA1 FA2 FA3 FA4 18 PRODUCTION (Input / output) Table 1: Basic SAM INCOME (distr/consumption) ACCUMULATION Savings/ investment 1, 2, ......................n W, R; F; H; G 1, 2...; F; H; G; B Intermediate Consumption Value Added Final Consumption Final Investment C I VA Total inputs, T1 Property income, Current Transfers Taxes TR REST WORLD (+ , -) total +Exports - Imports X’ Total output T1 Prop. income RW, Cur. Transfers RW Taxes (from+, to -) TRw T2 T3 Savings Capital Transfers Cap. Transfers RW (from+, to -) S TRk TRk,w T2 Net Lending (borrowing +; lend.-) FF T3 Net lending RW (lend +; borrow -) FFw T’4 T4 De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 19 Table 2: Induced and autonomous elements in a SAM PRODUCTION SALES Intermediate Consumption AUTONOMOUS INDUCED INDUCED DEMAND CONSUMPTION INVESTMENT Induced Consumption Induced Investment Exports Gov. C & I. Modernization I INCOME Distributed Value Added Income Taxes Property income, Current Transfers Autonomous C SAVINGS Savings of firms Savings of H & G. Capital Transfers Autonomous I Table 3. A compact SAM that bears the super-multiplier. INDUCED INCOMES UNCOMMITTED INCOMES 1 2 . . n INDUCED DEMAND 1, 2, ........................................... n AUTONOMOUS DEMAND Λ* Z Intermediate consumption. Induced final consumption. Induced final investment. Exports Government C & I Private autonomous C & I. Modernization Investment Σ (ZΣ) De-Juan: A Clakesch applied general equilibrium model 20 Table 4: Super-multipliers Multiplier of Total Output Multiplier of Final Output Multiplier of Income (VA) Multiplier of Employment MQ I Ad* MV v·I A MY I Ad · I Ad* * 1 d d *d Ad* 1 ML l · I Ad* 1 1 We subtract from MQ intermediate consumption. v is a rectangular matrix with so many rows as primary factors (wages of non qualified labour, wages of qualified labour, profits…) l is a rectangular matrix with so many rows as types of labour. Table 5: Data in Neoclassical and Clakesch AGE models Neoclassical – AGE model Clakesch –AGE model Endowements (K, L). Technology (malleable production functions) Technology (Fixed coefficients, but capital/output ratio may adjust to demand fluctuations) Individual preferences (malleable consumption functions) Expenditure patterns of social groups Distribution (wr) Autonomous demand (gz).