Using a real exchange rate model to make real and nominal forecasts Peter Sellin Sveriges Riksbank November 2006 Abstract In this paper we evaluate the forecasting performance of a real exchange rate model applied to the Swedish Krona’s real and nominal effective exchange rate, as well as the bilateral exchange rates against the US and the Euro area and the implicit USD/EUR exchange rate. The theoretical model implies a cointegrating relation between the real exchange rate, relative output, terms of trade and net foreign assets. The vector error correction model’s forecast performance is quite satisfactory for most of these exchange rates once the dynamics of the model have been augmented with an interest rate differential. JEL classification: C52, C53, F31. Keywords: real exchange rate, nominal exchange rate, forecasting. I am grateful for helpful comments by Paolo Giordani, Jesper Hansson, Tor Jacobson, Anders Vredin and Mattias Villani on a previous version of this paper. 1 Introduction A standard inter-temporal open economy model typically finds that the steady-state real exchange rate is related to the relative productivity in the tradables sector, the terms of trade and the net foreign asset position (see for example Lane and MilesiFerretti (2004) and Obstfeld and Rogoff (2004)). In this paper we will test if forecasts from a vector error correction model based on the Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2004) model can beat a random walk at horizons of 1 to 12 quarters. A simple extension of the empirical model allows us to consider forecasts of the nominal as well as the real effective exchange rate. We also forecast the effective exchange rate indirectly as a weighted average of forecasts of the SEK/EUR and SEK/USD exchange rates. Finally, we evaluate the implicit forecast of the USD/EUR exchange rate. We find that the model forecasts are quite satisfactory once the dynamics of the model have been properly specified. The out-of-sample forecasting performance of exchange rate models poses a special challenge to open economy macroeconomists. The standard finding in the empirical literature, starting with the seminal article by Meese and Rogoff (1983) evaluating the models of the 1970’s, is that no model can consistently outperform a random walk (for an evaluation of the models of the 1990’s see Cheung, Chinn and Pascual (2005)). However, the tests used have not been appropriate for testing nested models, as has been pointed out by for example Clark and McCracken (2001). Now research in this area has started using inference procedures that have recently been developed by Clark and West (2006a, 2006b). Their test procedure corrects for an upward bias in the alternative model’s sample mean squared prediction error. The test is easy to use and can also be applied to multi-step forecasts, using standard normal inference. Gourinchas and Rey (2005), Alquist and Chinn (2006) and Melodtsova and Papell (2006) use the new test. The results are somewhat more supportive regarding the ability of forecasts from exchange rate models to beat a random walk. Gourinchas and Rey (2005) estimate a model of the effective US dollar exchange rate using the ratio of net exports to net foreign assets as explanatory variable. They present forecasts that are consistently better than a random walk at horizons of 1 to 16 quarters over the period 1978:1 to 2004:1. Alquist and Chinn (2006) consider three different models: the sticky price monetary model, the 2 uncovered interest rate parity relation and Gourinchas and Rey’s (2005) model. Alquist and Chinn investigate the dollars bilateral exchange rates relative to the Canadian dollar, the UK Pound, the Japanese yen and the euro. They could not identify a model that was able to outperform a random walk forecast for all horizons and all bilateral exchange rates considered. However, the Gourinchas and Rey model did quite well for short forecast horizons of 1 and 4 quarters, except for the JPY/USD exchange rate. Molodtsova and Papell (2006) consider several models: the flexible price monetary model, uncovered interest parity, purchasing power parity and two types of Taylor rule models. They also consider a greater number of US bilateral exchange rates compared to Alquist and Chinn. They find that the models perform quite well at short forecast horizons. This is especially true for the Taylor rule models. The Swedish real effective exchange rate has been modelled recently by Bergvall (2002), Lindblad and Sellin (2003), Nilsson (2004), and Lane (2006). A common finding in these studies is that an improvement in the terms of trade lead to an appreciation of the real exchange rate. The first three studies also find that an increase in relative productivity (or relative output) leads to an appreciation, while Lane (2006) finds such a variable to be insignificant and excludes it from the analysis. However, none of the papers mentioned above focused on forecasting, which is the main focus of the present paper. The outline of the paper is the following. In Section 2 we present the steadystate exchange rate equation derived by Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2004). In Section 3 we estimate a vector autoregressive model and analyse a possible cointegrating relation among the variables that is consistent with the theoretical model. The model is then extended to a model for the nominal exchange rate. In Section 4 we evaluate forecasts of the real and nominal effective exchange rate. In Section 5 we model the bilateral SEK/EUR and SEK/USD exchange rates. We then weight these forecasts together to form a forecast of the effective exchange rate and we also compute the implicit USD/EUR exchange rate. These forecasts are then evaluated using the inference procedures developed by Clark and West (2006a, 2006b). Section 6 concludes. 2 A model of the real exchange rate We will base our analysis on the theoretical model derived in Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2004). The main result in their paper is that higher steady state tradable output 3 endowment (YT ) , terms of trade ( PTx ) , and net foreign assets (B) lead to a higher relative price of nontradables. The latter follows since an increase in any of the factors mentioned leads to greater wealth and hence increased demand for goods and leisure, the latter inducing a reduction in the supply of labour used (exclusively) in the production of nontradables. The derived steady-state variation in the real exchange rate is (log) linear in the price of nontradables: - q (1 ) log( PN ) (1 ) (1 ) log( YT ) (1 ) log( PTx ) (1 )r B Y0 (1) where q is the log of the real exchange rate defined as the foreign price level relative to the domestic price level, (1 ) is the weight placed on consumption of nontraded goods in the utility function, is a constant, (1 )[(1 ) ( ) ]1 with the intertemporal elasticity of substitution and the elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods, r is the exogenously given real interest rate, Y0 is the steady-state output. Thus, higher net foreign assets and tradable output as well as an improvement in the terms of trade lead to an appreciation of the real exchange rate. Equation (1) rewritten in obvious notation as 0 q 1 log( YT ) 2 log( PTx ) 3 B Y0 (2) forms the basis for our empirical analysis. To get some rough idea of the size of the coefficients we should expect to see we shall make some assumptions about the size of the elasticities above. We will assume an elasticity of substitution between traded and nontraded goods of 0.74 , as estimated by Mendoza (1995) for a sample of industrialised countries. Adolfsson et al (2005) set the share of imports in aggregate consumption to 0.31 for the Euro area. In addition to imports, traded goods should also include exportable goods. In view of this it does not seem unreasonable to choose the weight placed on consumption of traded goods in the utility function to 0.5 . The elasticity of intertemporal substitution is set to 0.67 as in Mendoza (1995). With the final assumption that the real interest rate r = 0.01 per quarter we get the parameter values ( 1 , 2 , 3 ) ( 0.7, 0.7, 0.014). 4 Following Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2002), we can use an alternative empirical formulation by noting that it is possible for a country to run a trade deficit in steadystate equal to the net investment income on its net foreign asset position: TB B r , Y0 Y0 (3) where TB is the country’s trade balance. Equation (2) can then be rewritten in the alternative form, 0 q 1 log( YT ) 2 log( PTx ) 3* TB , Y0 (4) where we now expect ( 1 , 2 , 3* ) ( 0.7, 0.7, -1.4). We will estimate both specification (2) and (4) as a check on the robustness of the results and to see which model yields the better forecasts. 3 Estimating a VAR model for the effective exchange rate 3.1Preliminaries The benchmark model consists of four variables: real exchange rate, qt , relative output, yt , terms of trade, t , and net foreign assets relative to GDP , bt . The first three variables are measured in natural logarithms. The real exchange rate is measured as the foreign price level relative to the Swedish price level expressed in the Swedish currency. Net foreign assets are measured as a fraction of gross domestic product. The alternative model also consists of four variables: real exchange rate, qt , relative output, yt , terms of trade, t , and the trade balance relative to GDP , tbt . The quarterly value of the trade balance is expressed as a fraction of annual gross domestic product to conform to the measure of net foreign assets. More details about the data are given in an appendix. The levels and first differences of all the abovementioned variables are depicted in Figure 1a-b. In addition some descriptive statistics for the time series are provided in Table 1. The sample covers the period 1985Q1 – 2005Q3. The main reason for starting in 1985 is that we will consider an augmented version of the model that includes a short-term interest rate differential and there was no functioning money market in Sweden before the early 1980s. Allowing for up to four lags would then take us back to the first quarter of 1984, by which time there was a working money 5 market. By using 1985Q1 as the starting date we also avoid the devaluations of the early 1980s and more than half of the observations are from the floating period 1993Q1-2005Q3. A look at the time series in Figure 1 shows that the real exchange rate has been more volatile since the Krona was allowed to float on 19 November 1992. The Swedish economy has experienced a period of relatively high growth since the crisis years of the early 1990s and the net foreign asset position has improved dramatically since then. This is in large part due to continuous trade balance surpluses but valuation effects have also played a role. Another thing worth noting is the deterioration in the Swedish terms of trade during the past ten years. At the end of the sample period the terms of trade were at the same level as before the OPEC collapse of 1986. Because of the small sample size some of the critical values of interest have been bootstrapped (using 4,999 replications in each case). The “Structural VAR Program” developed by Anders Warne has been used for this purpose. This program has also been used in order to investigate parameter stability.1 Otherwise, the results presented in most of the tables have been produced by the Eviews 5.0 program. 3.2 The statistical model We will be using a 4-dimensional vector autoregressive (VAR) model of order k. This model can be expressed in vector error correction form (VEC) as: k 1 X t ' X t 1 i X t i ´ t , (5) i 1 where X t (qt , yt , t , bt )' or alternatively X t (qt , yt , t , tbt )' . The errors are assumed to be independently and normally distributed with mean zero and covariance matrix . Under certain conditions the X t -process is non-stationary while both the first- differenced process X t and the linear combinations ' X t 1 are stationary (see Johansen (1996)). Based on the theoretical considerations discussed above we expect to find one such stationary linear combination, with (1, 0.7, 0.7, 0.014) or alternatively (1, 0.7, 0.7, -1.4), when the vector is normalised with respect to the real exchange rate. 1 See the Structural VAR homepage at http://texlips.hypermart.net/svar/index.html. 6 3.3 The estimated benchmark model (BM) In order to get a good estimate of the cointegration vector it is important to specify the correct number of lags for the VAR. In order to determine the lag order we considered a number of lag order selection criteria. The LR and AIC criteria indicated that a lag order of k=3 is optimal, the FPE criterion favoured 2 lags and the SC and HQ criteria preferred 1 lag. Lag exclusion tests indicated that we should keep 3 lags in the model. Multivariate tests of serially uncorrelated residuals for the k=3 model showed that the null hypothesis of no serial correlation in the residuals cannot be rejected at the 5 percent significance level against the alternative hypotheses of 1st – 4th order serial correlation. Thus 3 lags were used. The null hypothesis that the residuals are normally distributed was rejected, using the test statistics derived by Doornik and Hansen (1994). The reason for this is that the kurtosis values are lower than those from a normal distribution. There was no indication of skewness in the residuals, which according to Juselius (2005) would be a more serious problem. Tests for the cointegration rank (r) are reported in Table 1 for the VAR(3) model. We conclude from Johansen’s likelihood ratio tests that there is one cointegrating vector, which is what we would expect from the theoretical model. Bootstrapping was then used for these test statistics. First, we find that bootstrapped critical values for the trace statistics are higher than the asymptotic values and we cannot reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration. On the other hand a likelihood ratio test does not reject the hypothesis of r=1 against the alternative r=0 at conventional significance levels. There are three near unit roots in the unrestricted system. The choice of r=1 leaves a root of 0.937 in the system. Nevertheless, we judge that the overall evidence against cointegration is not strong enough for us to give up our prior belief in one cointegration vector. We computed the sample means and standard deviations of the firstdifferenced series. None of the means in the first-differenced series are significantly different from zero, see Table 1. We therefore restrict the constant term to the cointegration space to exclude deterministic drifts in the individual series. This implies that in the long run, or in the steady state, output in Sweden will grow at the same rate as in its main trading partners, export and import prices will grow at the same rate, and net foreign assets will converge to some constant fraction of GDP. 7 We have included two dummy variables in the estimated vector error correction model. The first is a devaluation dummy that takes the value one in the 4th quarter of 1992 and zero otherwise and captures the real depreciation after letting the Krona float on 19 November 1992. This dummy variable is included contemporaneously and lagged one period. The second is a shift dummy and captures the change to an inflation targeting regime in the 1st quarter of 1995. It takes the value one up to and including the 4th quarter of 1994 and zero thereafter. Estimating the model by maximum likelihood is equivalent to solving an eigenvalue problem. We use the estimated non-zero eigenvalue to check for nonconstant parameters as suggested in Hansen and Johansen (1999). If the estimated eigenvalue fluctuates over time this can be due to fluctuations in or or both and additional testing is required to determine which is the case. The time path of the estimated non-zero eigenvalue is shown in Figure 2. It looks quite stable indicating no problem with non-constant parameters in the cointegration relation. The cointegrating relation is shown in Figure 3, Panel A. The cointegration vector normalized with respect to the real SEK/TCW exchange rate is given by2 ̂ ´ 1.0, 0.72 , 0.50 , 0.17 , ( 0.54, 2.31) ( 0.02,1.05) ( 0.39, 0.03) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals in parentheses under the estimated coefficients (using bootstrapped t-values). The coefficients are imprecisely estimated. However, we note that the point estimates of ˆ1 and ˆ 2 are quite close to the values we expected them to take. On the other hand, ̂ 3 does not even take the expected sign. The estimated adjustment coefficients are ̂´ 0.11 , 0.03 , 0.04 , 0.13 , ( 0.20, 0.02) ( 0.01, 0.05) ( 0.10, 0.03) ( 0.00, 0.27) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals. The adjustment of the real exchange rate is quite slow with only 11 percent of the gap being closed each quarter. We also note that the confidence interval includes the zero value. Thus, the adjustment is not even significantly different from zero at the chosen level. The evidence of statistically significant adjustment in the second equation indicates that a 2 The complete estimated model is presented in Table 7. 8 weak exchange rate has a positive effect on output, which makes sense for an economy with a large export sector. We next restrict the model by imposing the theoretically derived cointegration vector of the previous section. The restriction is not rejected (the probability value is 0.34). The estimated adjustment coefficients for this model are ̂´ 0.09 , 0.02 , 0.05 , 0.05 . ( 0.14, 0.00) ( 0.01, 0.04) ( 0.09, 0.00) ( 0.02, 0.14) The cointegration relation for the restricted model is shown in Figure 3, Panel B. For this specification the confidence interval for the adjustment in the real exchange rate does not include zero (by a small margin). From this perspective the restrictions can be deemed successful. Next we consider a model with richer dynamics. Since the theory does not have anything to say about the dynamics of the model we can freely choose to include variables that we feel could be important in the short run. A natural candidate is the short-term real interest rate differential, which we add to the restricted model.3 . Thus our new vector of endogenous variables is X t* (qt , yt , t , bt , cit )' , where cit is the cumulated real interest rate differential. The cumulated variable is restricted to zero in the cointegration vector so that we only end up with the interest rate differential, it , in the dynamics. The interest rate differential lagged one period enters with a negative sign and the coefficient is statistically significant at the 10 percent level (using bootstrapped t-values); the two period lag is not significant. The estimated adjustment coefficients for this model are ̂´ 0.12 , 0.03 , 0.04 , 0.03 , 0.52 . ( 0.17, 0.02) ( 0.01, 0.04) ( 0.08, 0.02) ( 0.06, 0.13) ( 3.89, 3.00) The cointegration relation for the restricted model is shown in Figure 3, Panel C. The adjustment in the real exchange rate is now clearly significant at the 80 percent confidence level. 3.4 The estimated alternative model (AM) In the alternative model we have replaced the net foreign asset variable with the trade balance relative to GDP. Another difference is that we have excluded the inflation regime shift dummy from this model. Using the inflation regime shift variable 3 The differential consists of the Swedish 3-month interest rate compared to a weighted 3-month rate consisting of interest rates for Sweden’s main trading partners (using the TCW weights for Sweden). 9 in this model leads to very strange parameter estimates. The shift dummy is highly significant in the trade balance equation but the estimated coefficients in the cointegration vector become extremely large. We have therefore excluded the shift dummy from the model. All of the information criteria considered suggest that one lag should be adequate. But the lag exclusion test favours keeping 2 lags in the model. Estimating a VAR with one lag there is some evidence of serial correlation in the terms of trade residuals. With two lags this serial correlation goes away. Since it is not clear which model is to be preferred we choose to proceed with both k=1 and k=2. Tests for the cointegration rank for the VAR(1) and VAR(2) models respectively give no reason to give up our prior belief in one cointegration vector. As in the benchmark model, bootstrapping the trace test critical values we cannot reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration. But a likelihood ratio test of r=1 against r=0 does not reject r=1 (with a probability value of 0.55). We will restrict the constant term to the cointegration space to exclude deterministic drifts in the individual series. This implies that in the long run the trade balance will converge to some constant fraction of GDP. We check for non-constant parameters using the single non-zero eigenvalue, as explained in the previous section. The time path of the estimated non-zero eigenvalue is depicted in Figure 4. It looks reasonably stable. The estimated cointegrating relation is shown in Figure 5, Panel A. The cointegration vector normalized with respect to the real exchange rate and the vector of adjustment coefficients are given by ̂ ´ 1.0, 0.67 , 0.34 , 0.88 , ( 1.87, 0.69) ( 0.19, 0.82) ( 2.37, 0.54) ̂´ 0.01 , 0.03 , 0.05 , 0.01 , ( 0.03,0.06) ( 0.02, 0.05) ( 0.09, 0.01) ( 0.01, 0.03) for the VEC with k=1 and for the VEC with k=2 we have4 ̂ ´ 1.0, 0.56 , 0.45 , 1.18 , ( 1.66, 0.63) ( 0.01, 0.85) ( 2.47, 0.14) ̂´ 0.04 , 0.04 , 0.06 , 0.02 , ( 0.10,0.03) ( 0.02, 0.05) ( 0.09, 0.01) ( 0.01, 0.04) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals in parentheses below the estimated coefficients (using bootstrapped t-values). The estimated coefficients of the VAR(2) model comes closest to what we expected to find. We note that the point estimates of ˆ 2 and ̂ 3 are quite close to the values we expected them to take. 4 The complete estimated models are presented in Tables 12 and 13 respectively. 10 Disappointingly, ˆ1 does not take the expected sign. However, the 80 percent confidence interval also contains positive values. The adjustment coefficient in the exchange rate equation is halved compared with the benchmark model and it is not statistically significantly different from zero at the 20 percent level. We proceed by imposing the theoretically derived coefficient values in the cointegration vector of the VEC with k=2. The restriction is not rejected at the 1 percent significance level (but is rejected at the 5 percent level). The estimated adjustment coefficients for this model are ̂´ 0.08 , 0.03 , 0.06 , 0.01 . ( 0.14, 0.01) ( 0.02, 0.05) ( 0.10, 0.01) ( 0.02, 0.03) The adjustment coefficient in the exchange rate equation is significantly different from zero at the 20 percent level and is equal in size to that estimated for the restricted benchmark model: -0.08 compared to -0.09. The cointegration relation for the restricted model is shown in Figure 5, Panel B. The estimated adjustment coefficients for the restricted model with an interest rate differential are ̂´ 0.14 , 0.03 , 0.03 , 0.02 , 1.48 , ( 0.19, 0.06) ( 0.02, 0.04) ( 0.07, 0.02) ( 0.01, 0.05) ( 4.03,1.82) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals. The interest rate differential lagged one period enters with a negative sign, which is significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level (using bootstrapped t-values). 3.5 Estimating the nominal effective exchange rate When forecasting exchange rates the interest is usually in the nominal rather than in the real exchange rate. We will consider a very simple way of extending the analysis to get a forecasting model for the nominal exchange rate. This simply involves splitting up the real exchange rate into two components: the nominal exchange rate and the relative price level between the foreign and domestic country, qt et pt (the variables are shown in Figure 1c). We estimate the nominal versions of the restricted models augmented with real interest rate differentials. Thus our new vector of endogenous variables is X t* (et , pt , yt , t , bt , cit )' for the benchmark model and X t* (et , pt , yt , t , tbt , cit )' for the alternative model. 11 Estimating the nominal version of the benchmark model we obtain the following adjustment parameters:5 ( 0.17, 0.02) ̂ ' 0.12 , 0.05 , 0.03 , 0.03, 0.03 , 1.53 , ( 0.08, 0.02) ( 0.01, 0.05) ( 0.07, 0.03) ( 0.06, 0.14) ( 4.97, 2 , 46) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals within parenthesis below the estimated coefficients. We can see that the adjustment of the real exchange rate takes place both through the adjustment of the nominal exchange rate and through the adjustment of the relative price level. However, the point estimate for the adjustment coefficient in the nominal exchange rate equation is twice as big as the one in the relative price level equation. This is not surprising given that most of the sample covers the floating exchange rate period. Estimating the nominal version of the alternative model we get the following adjustment parameters:6 ( 0.16, 0.03) ̂ ' 0.11 , 0.04 , 0.03 , 0.02, 0.02 , 1.74 , ( 0.06, 0.02) ( 0.01, 0.04) ( 0.06, 0.02) ( 0.01, 0.05) ( 4.21,1.36) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals. These results are very similar to those of the benchmark model. 3.6 Discussion Generally speaking, most of the estimated coefficients in the cointegration vector are imprecisely estimated and are not different from zero at the 20 percent significance level, using bootstrapped t-values. However, most of the point estimates are close to the values we would expect from the calibrated model. When we impose the theoretically derived cointegration vectors they are not rejected by the data, i.e. we cannot reject cointegration. The estimated adjustment coefficients in the exchange rate equation and the relative output equation are significant with the expected signs. The real test of the models will be their out-of-sample forecast performance, to which we turn next. 5 The complete estimated model is presented in Table 4. The complete estimated model is presented in Table 5. We note that the output from the Eviews program in Table 5 gives an adjustment coefficient of -5.6 in the interest rate differential equation, which is not even inside the 80 percent confidence interval presented in the text, which is generated by Warne’s Structural VAR program. 6 12 4 Forecast evaluation 4.1 The evaluation procedure We will evaluate forecasts of the percentage change in the exchange rate with horizons h=1,2,…,12 quarters. The first forecast will be based on the model estimated for the period 1985Q1 - 1997Q4. The estimation window is then moved forward by one quarter at a time using a rolling scheme.7 Thus, we are always using the latest 13 years of data to estimate the model, which gives us 52 observations. The final 1-period forecast is for 2005Q3, which is the last observation in the sample. We thus get a total of P-h+1 h-period forecasts with P=31. Forecast accuracy is measured by mean squared prediction error (MSPE). With at s h being the actual value and f t s h the forecast value, the MSPE for an h-period forecast is defined as: ˆ 2 (h) Ph 1 (at s h f t s h ) 2 , P h 1 s 0 (6) where t=1997Q4. We will compare our forecasts with those of the random walk model, which says that the exchange rate will remain unchanged at the present level during the forecast period. We will also compare our forecasts to those of a VAR in first differences, i.e. leaving out the error correction term. This should tell us something about the value for forecasting purposes of using the theoretically derived relationship between the variables in levels. Meese and Rogoff (1983) found that none of the exchange rate models developed during the 1970s could beat a random walk and this has been the benchmark for exchange rate forecasters ever since. In the spirit of Meese and Rogoff, Cheung, Chinn and Pascual (2005) evaluate the forecasting performance of the models developed during the 1990s, with equally disappointing results. However, as shown by Clark and McCracken (2001) among others, the tests employed in these studies are not appropriate when the models under comparison are nested. The tests are shown to be under-sized. Critical values are derived for the correct asymptotic distributions, but only for 1-step ahead forecasts.8 Clark and West (2006a, 2006b) show that there is an upward bias in the nesting model’s sample mean squared prediction error and how one can correct for this. The 7 We also conducted the analysis using a recursive scheme. The results were very similar. We do not use a recursive scheme since the inference of our tests are not strictly valid for such a scheme (see Clark and West (2006a)). 8 West (2006) gives a useful overview of forecast evaluation techniques. 13 test is applicable also to multi-step forecasts and is easy to implement. We will use the bias correction suggested by Clark and West. Their MSPE-adjusted test statistic is defined as MSPEadj ˆ12 (ˆ 22 adj.) , (7) where subscript 1 indicates the parsimonious (null) model and subscript 2 indicates the larger (alternative) model that nests model 1 (we have suppressed the horizon index h). The adjustment term is defined as adj.(h) N h 1 ( f1,t s h f 2,t s h ) 2 . N h 1 s 0 (8) This term adjusts for the upward bias in MSPE produced by the estimation of parameters that are zero under the null. We implement the test by first defining 2 2 2 ~ f t s h at s h f1,t s h at s h f 2,t s h f1,t s h f 2,t s h , (9) ~ The null hypothesis is equal MSPE. We test for equal MSPE by regressing f t s h on a constant and using the resulting t-statistic to test for a zero coefficient. Clark and West (2006a, 2006b) argue that standard normal critical values are approximately correct. We thus reject the null hypothesis of equal MSPE if this statistic is greater than +1.282 (for a one-tailed 0.10 test) or +1.645 (for a one-tailed 0.05 test). A onetailed test is used since for nested models it does not make sense for the population MSPE of the parsimonious model to be smaller than that of the larger model. We use Newey-West autocorrelation consistent standard errors to construct the t-statistic because multi-period forecasts will in general be autocorrelated. Finally, we would like to draw attention to the fact that the seminal paper by Meese and Rogoff (1983) and many subsequent studies use the actual values for their exogenous regressors and still could not beat a random walk. Our exercise is more challenging in that the forecasts only involve endogenous variables. We make fully dynamic forecasts, i.e. a multi-period forecast uses predicted rather than actual values for all variables during the forecast period. 4.2 Evaluating the forecasts In Table 6 we present the MSPEs for forecasts of the benchmark real exchange rate model (VEC), a random walk (RW), and a VAR in first differences, as well as the adjusted MSPEs. In the last two columns of the table we present the usual ratio of 14 the (unadjusted) MSPEs and the t-values of the Clark-West statistic (for the adjusted MSPEs). We first compare the change in the exchange rate forecasted by the model to a random walk forecast, which says that the exchange rate will remain unchanged. We see that the forecasts of the unrestricted model (reported in Panel A) as well as those of the restricted model (in Panel B) cannot beat a random walk. However, the forecasts of the restricted model augmented with an interest rate differential (reported in Panel C) are significantly better than those of a random walk at horizons of 5-10 quarters at the 10 percent significance level, using a one-tailed test. Thus, it is not enough to impose the theoretical cointegration vector. We also need to model the dynamics better by introducing some financial variable like the real interest rate differential. Comparing the forecasts of the benchmark model to those from a simple VAR in first differences, in Panel C, we see that the restricted cointegration vector of the VEC model helps us to make better forecasts, which lends some support to the theoretical model. Figure 6a well illustrates the curse put on anyone attempting to forecast the SEK/TCW exchange rate using fundamentals. It seems that no matter what, the Krona is always expected to appreciate in value. Figure 6b shows how the curse is lifted by including the interest rate differential in the dynamics of the model. Especially noteworthy are the forecasts in the quarters preceeding the substantial depreciation of the Krona in 2000. In Table 7 we analyse the forecast performance of the alternative real exchange rate model. The results are similar to those reported for the benchmark model in that we need to augment the dynamics with an interest rate differential in order to beat a random walk forecast. The alternative model yields better forecasts in the short run but worse forecasts in the long run compared to the benchmark model (Panel C). The forecasts from the nominal versions of the benchmark and alternative models are presented in Table 8, Panels A and B respectively. The predictive ability is not quite as good as for the real models, even though the forecasts of the alternative model are still fairly good. The AM forecasts outperform a random walk at all horizons. They do not outperform the forecasts from a simple VAR in first differences at conventional significance levels, but most of the t-values are close to one for all forecast horizons. The overall assessment is that we cannot reject the theoretical model as a description of how the real effective exchange rate is related to fundamental macroeconomic variables. But this conclusion is dependent on our ability to 15 successfully model the dynamics about which the theoretical model has very little to say. We are successful in beating the random walk forecasts for both the real and nominal SEK/TCW exchange rates. 5 Forecasting the effective exchange rate indirectly Given that one is interested in forecasting not only the effective exchange rate but also a few of its largest components one would like these forecasts to be consistent with each other. One way of assuring that this is indeed the case is to model the component bilateral rates and then weight these together to form an effective exchange rate that is approximately equal to the broader effective exchange rate index. In this section we will estimate models of the SEK/EUR and SEK/USD exchange rates. The forecasts from these models will then be weighted together to form an approximate SEK/TCW forecast. The use of the theoretical model in modelling the bilateral exchange rates gives rise to a few issues that we first need to address. When we analyse a country’s real effective exchange rate the implementation of the theory is quite straightforward. There is one issue concerning the output variable. Lane and Milesi-Ferretti state that the level of output should be understood to be measured relative to output overseas, since a global increase in tradable output would increase the relative price on non-tradables in all countries (leaving the real effective exchange rate unchanged). With regard to the real effective exchange rate the net foreign asset position as well as the terms of trade will have symmetric effects. The home country’s increased wealth, whether as a result of an increase in net foreign assets or improved terms of trade, reflects the decrease in wealth in the rest of the world (due to the same factor). However, this is not necessarily the case if we are considering a bilateral exchange rate. Both countries’ wealth could increase (or decrease) reflecting a decrease (or increase) in the wealth of the rest of the world. Thus, when considering a bilateral exchange rate the implementation of the theory is less straightforward. However, it seems that a similar way of reasoning as above concerning the output variable should apply to the other two variables as well; we should be considering the relative net foreign asset position and the relative terms of trade of the two countries whose bilateral exchange rate we wish to model. 16 5.1 The estimated SEK/EUR model To determine the number of lags to use in the VAR we start with a look at some lag order selection criteria. The LR, FPE and AIC criteria indicated that a lag order of k=3 is optimal, while the SC and HQ criteria deemed 1 lag to be sufficient. Lag exclusion tests indicated that we should keep 3 lags in the model. Multivariate tests of serially uncorrelated residuals for the k=3 model showed that the null hypothesis of no serial correlation in the residuals cannot be rejected at the 5 percent significance level against the alternative hypotheses of 1st – 4th order serial correlation. Based on the above we decided to use 3 lags. Next we performed tests of the normality of the residuals. The null hypothesis that the residuals are normally distributed was rejected, using the test statistics derived by Doornik and Hansen (1994). As in the SEK/TCW model the reason for this is that the kurtosis values are lower than those from a normal distribution, while there was no indication of skewness in the residuals. Tests for the cointegration rank (r) are reported in Table 9 for the VAR(3) model. We conclude from this test that there is one cointegrating vector, which is what we would expect from the theoretical model. Bootstrapping was then employed. First, we find that bootstrapped critical values for the trace statistics are quite a bit larger than the asymptotic critical values so that we cannot reject the null of no cointegration. On the other hand a likelihood ratio test does not reject the hypothesis of r=1 against the alternative of r=0 at conventional significance levels. In our judgement the evidence against cointegration is not strong enough for us to give up our prior belief in one cointegration vector. We computed the sample means and standard deviations of the firstdifferenced series. None of the means of these series are significantly different from zero, see Table 9. We therefore restrict the constant term to the cointegration space to exclude deterministic drifts in the individual series. This implies that in the long run, or in the steady state, output in Sweden will grow at the same rate as in the Euro area, export and import prices will grow at the same rate, and net foreign assets will converge to some constant fraction of GDP. We have included one dummy variable in the estimated vector error correction model. This is a devaluation dummy that takes the value one in the 4 th quarter of 1992 and zero otherwise and captures the real depreciation after letting the Krona float on 19 November 1992. This dummy variable was found to be significant both contemporaneously and lagged one period. We also include the shift dummy used in 17 the SEK/TCW model, which captures the change to an inflation targeting regime in the 1st quarter of 1995. We used the estimated non-zero eigenvalue to check for non-constant parameters. There were no signs of instability, indicating no problem with nonconstant parameters in the cointegration relation. The cointegration vector normalized with respect to the real SEK/EUR exchange rate is given by9 ̂ ´ 1.0, 0.50 , 0.40 , 0.17 , ( 0.15,1.29) ( 0.22, 0.91) ( 0.38, 0.00) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals in parentheses under the estimated coefficients (using bootstrapped t-values). The coefficients are imprecisely estimated. However, we note that the point estimates of ˆ1 and ˆ 2 are fairly close to the values we expected them to take. On the other hand, ̂ 3 does not take the expected sign. The estimated adjustment coefficients are ̂´ 0.10 , 0.04 , 0.02 , 0.16 , ( 0.18, 0.02) ( 0.02, 0.07) ( 0.06, 0.03) ( 0.04, 0.26) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals. The adjustment of the real exchange rate is taking place with about 10 percent of the gap being closed each quarter. We next restrict the model by imposing the theoretically derived cointegration vector of the previous section. The restriction is rejected at the 5 percent level but not at the 1 percent level (the probability value is 0.04). The estimated adjustment coefficients for this model are ̂´ 0.08 , 0.03 , 0.04 , 0.10 . ( 0.13, 0.03) ( 0.01, 0.05) ( 0.07, 0.00) ( 0.02, 0.18) The results are very similar to those of the unrestricted model. The estimated adjustment coefficients for the restricted model with an interest rate differential are ̂´ 0.08 , 0.03 , 0.04 , 0.11 , 2.65 , ( 0.13, 0.03) ( 0.02, 0.05) ( 0.07, 0.00) ( 0.02, 0.20) ( 5.72, 0.64) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals. Again, the results are basically the same as in the previous specifications. 9 The complete estimated model is presented in Table 11. 18 For the nominal SEK/EUR model we obtain the following adjustment parameters: ( 0.14, 0.05) ̂ ' 0.07 , 0.06 , 0.04 , 0.02, 0.11 , 1.97 . ( 0.08, 0.03) ( 0.02, 0.06) ( 0.06, 0.03) ( 0.01, 0.22) ( 5.05,1.38) According to the point estimates the adjustment of the real exchange rate takes place in equal measure through the adjustment of the nominal exchange rate and the relative price levels (the first two coefficients). However, the adjustment coefficient in the nominal exchange rate equation is not significantly different from zero at the 20 percent significance level, since the 80 per cent confidence interval contains the zero value. Overall, the evidence supporting the theoretical model is rather weak, perhaps reflecting the fact that the model is more appropriately regarded as a model of the real effective exchange rate. 5.2 The estimated SEK/USD model We start with a look at some lag order selection criteria in order to determine the number of lags to use in the VAR. The LR, FPE and AIC criteria indicated that a lag order of k=4 is optimal, while the SC and HQ criteria found 1 lag to be sufficient. Lag exclusion tests indicated that we should keep 4 lags in the model. Multivariate tests of serially uncorrelated residuals for the k=4 model showed that the null hypothesis of no serial correlation in the residuals cannot be rejected at the 5 percent significance level against the alternative hypotheses of 1st – 5th order serial correlation. Based on the evidence presented above we decided to use 4 lags. Next we performed tests of the normality of the residuals. The null hypothesis that the residuals are normally distributed was rejected, using the test statistics derived by Doornik and Hansen (1994). As in the previously estimated models the reason for this is that the kurtosis values are lower than those from a normal distribution, while there was no indication of skewness in the residuals. Tests for the cointegration rank (r) are reported in Table 13 for the VAR(4) model. We conclude from this test that there is one cointegrating vector, which is what we would expect from the theoretical model. Bootstrapping was then used in deriving more accurate critical values for the test statistics. First, we find that bootstrapped critical values for the trace statistics are so large that we cannot reject the null of no cointagration. The choice of r=1 leaves a root of 0.84 in the system. 19 Based on these tests we find that the evidence against cointegration is not so strong that we are willing to give up our theoretically motivated prior belief in one cointegration vector. We computed the sample means and standard deviations of the firstdifferenced series. None of the means in the first-differenced series are significantly different from zero, see Table 12. We therefore restrict the constant term to the cointegration space to exclude deterministic drifts in the individual series. This implies that in the long run output in Sweden will grow at the same rate as in the U.S., export and import prices will grow at the same rate, and net foreign assets will converge to some constant fraction of GDP. We have used the same set of dummy variables that were used in the SEK/EUR model, described in the previous subsection. The cointegration vector normalized with respect to the real SEK/USD exchange rate is given by10 ̂ ´ 1.0, 1.25 , 1.22 , 0.14 , ( 4.53,1.18) ( 1.03, 2.57) ( 0.62, 0.38) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals in parentheses under the estimated coefficients (using bootstrapped t-values). The coefficients are imprecisely estimated. Contrary to the previous models, the point estimates of ˆ1 and ˆ 2 are not close to the values we expected them to take. As before, ̂ 3 does not take the expected sign. Somewhat disturbingly, none of the coefficients are significantly different from zero at the 20 percent significance level. The estimated adjustment coefficients are ̂´ 0.12 , 0.02 , 0.01 , 0.01 , ( 0.34, 0.03) ( 0.00, 0.06) ( 0.02, 0.06) ( 0.05, 0.09) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals. The adjustment coefficients in the exchange rate equation and the relative output equation take the expected sign and are significantly different from zero at the 20 percent level. The adjustment of the real exchange rate indicates that 12 percent of the gap is being closed each quarter. However, since the estimated cointegration vector is far from the one we expected it is difficult to see what one should make of this. 10 The complete estimated model is presented in Table 14. 20 We next restrict the model by imposing the theoretically derived cointegration vector of the previous section. The restriction is not rejected (the probability value is 0.17). The estimated adjustment coefficients for this model are ̂´ 0.08 , 0.01 , 0.01 , 0.00 . ( 0.12, 0.03) ( 0.00, 0.02) ( 0.01, 0.02) ( 0.03, 0.03) The adjustment coefficients in the exchange rate equation and the relative output equation have the expected signs and are significantly different from zero at the 20 percent level. Hence, we get some support for the theoretical model here. The estimated adjustment coefficients for the restricted model with an interest rate differential are ̂´ 0.10 , 0.01 , 0.01 , 0.02 , 0.35 , ( 0.13, 0.04) ( 0.00, 0.02) ( 0.00, 0.03) ( 0.05, 0.01) ( 1.13,1.68) with 80 percent bootstrapped confidence intervals. The results are basically the same as in the previous specification, with an additional variable (the real interest rate differential) that is long-run weakly exogenous with regard to the cointegrating relationship. For the nominal SEK/USD restricted model with interest rate differential we obtain the following adjustment parameters: ̂ ' 0.08 , 0.01 , 0.01 , 0.02 , 0.02, 0.05 . ( 0.14, 0.06) ( 0.02, 0.00) ( 0.00, 0.02) ( 0.00, 0.03) ( 0.05, 0.01) ( 0.95,1.59) We can see that most of the adjustment of the real exchange rate takes place through the adjustment of the nominal exchange rate and very little through the adjustment of the relative price levels. The theoretically derived restrictions seem to fit better for the SEK/USD model than for the SEK/EUR model. In the next subsection we will see if this tentative conclusion has any implications for the forecast evaluation exercises. 5.3 Evaluating the forecasts In Table 15 we present the MSPEs for the benchmark real SEK/EUR exchange rate model; the unrestricted model (reported in Panel A), the restricted model (in Panel B) and the restricted model augmented with an interest rate differential (reported in Panel C). Almost all of the t-values are negative and thus our VEC model is unable to beat a random walk. With the help of Figure 10 it is easy to see why the random walk has been so difficult to beat during the evaluation period. The SEK/EUR exchange 21 rate has been quite stable during this period. The results for the nominal model with an interest rate differential look somewhat better (reported in Panel D). Most of the tvalues are positive and the ones at the 10 – 12 quarter horizons are even statistically significant at the 10 percent level, even though the unadjusted ratios of the MSPEs actually exceed one. However, at these longest horizons we have few forecasts and we should be a bit careful interpreting these results. The initially estimated SEK/USD model yielded forecast MSPEs that rapidly grew very large with increasing horizon. We therefore tried to trim the number of lags and found that the model with one lag (in differenced form) yielded the smallest MSPEs. This then became our preferred model.11 The results for the SEK/USD model overall look more promising than those for the SEK/EUR model (see Figure 16). The restricted model is able to beat a random walk at short horizons (1 – 6 quarters), and the forecasts are better than those of a VAR in first differences (Panel B). When we look at the forecasts of the model with an interest rate differential (in Panel C) we see that it is able to beat a random walk and a VAR at all horizons. The unadjusted ratios of MSPEs are quite small; most of them below 0.5.12 It is clear from Figure 11 why the random walk is a very poor model for the SEK/USD during the evaluation period, with large swings in the exchange rate. The figure also shows that the VEC model yields surprisingly good forecasts. The results are very similar for the nominal version of the model (presented in Panel D). We next consider an approximate SEK/TCW forecast, which we will compare to the actual SEK/TCW effective exchange rate. We use renormalized TCW weights to weigh together the nominal SEK/EUR forecasts and the nominal SEK/USD forecasts both based on the restricted model with an interest rate differential. In order to start off the forecast at the correct level a factor of proportionality between the actual SEK/TCW index and the weighted SEK/EUR – SEK/USD index is computed for the quarter preceding each forecast. This factor is then applied to the forecast path. In Table 17 the MSPEs for the approximate SEK/TCW forecasts are evaluated. The model forecasts are not able to beat a random walk at any horizon; only a few of the t-values are positive. It is small comfort that the forecasts are better than those from a VAR in first differences at horizons above four quarters. 11 We had previously also tried to trim the SEK/TCW and SEK/EUR models, but this resulted in poorer forecast performance. 12 We note that the some of the adjusted MSPEs in the third column of Panel C are negative, making the interpretation of an adjusted MSPE a bit problematic. 22 In Table 18 we evaluate forecasts of the implicit nominal USD/EUR exchange rate obtained as the cross of the nominal SEK/EUR forecasts and the nominal SEK/USD forecasts, again based on the restricted model with an interest rate differential. In view of the poor forecasting performance of the SEK/EUR model, these results look surprisingly good. The VEC model is able to beat both a random walk and a VAR at horizons of 2 – 9 quarters at the 10 percent significance level or better. 6 Conclusions In this paper we have estimated models of the real and nominal SEK/TCW, SEK/EUR and SEK/USD exchange rates using the Johansen approach. Imposing values derived from a calibrated theoretical model on the cointegrating vectors is shown to improve the forecasting performance in general. Augmenting the dynamics of the model by including an interest rate differential further improves the forecast performance, generating forecasts for the real as well as nominal SEK/TCW exchange rates that are superior to those of a random walk at horizons of around one to two years. For the real and nominal SEK/EUR exchange rate the results are not as impressive. The model is not able to beat a random walk at any horizon. Model forecasts of the real and nominal SEK/USD exchange rate are superior to those of a random walk at all horizons. Weighting the nominal SEK/EUR and SEK/USD forecasts together into an approximate SEK/TCW index did not yield good forecasts. On the other hand, and somewhat surprisingly, the model forecasts of the implicit nominal USD/EUR exchange rate are superior to those of a random walk at most horizons. Generally speaking, it seems like a good theoretical model and careful modelling of the dynamics would enable you to construct a model that yields forecasts that are superior to those of a random walk. One caveat is that the sample considered in this paper is quite short, so it would be interesting to follow up on these results at a later date. 23 References Adolfsson, M., S. Laséen, J. Lindé and M. Villani (2005). Bayesian estimation of an open economy DSGE model with incomplete pass-through, Working Paper No. 179, Sveriges Riksbank. Alquist, R. and M.D. Chinn (2006). Conventional and unconventional approaches to exchange rate modelling and assessment, Working Paper No. 12481, National Bureau of Economic Research. Bergvall, A. (2002). What determines real exchange rates? - The Nordic countries. Working Paper No. 2002:15, Uppsala University. Cheung, Y-W, M.D. Chinn, and A.G. Pascual (2005). Empirical exchange rate models of the nineties: are any fit to survive? Journal of International Money and Finance 24, 1150-1175. Clark, T.E. and M.W. McCracken (2001). Tests of equal forecast accuracy and encompassing for nested models. Journal of Econometrics 105, 85-110. Clark, T.E. and K.D. West (2006a). Using out-of-sample mean squared prediction errors to test the martingale difference hypothesis. Journal of Econometrics 135(1-2), 155-186. Clark, T.E. and K.D. West (2006b). Approximately normal tests for equal predictive accuracy in nested models. Journal of Econometrics, forthcoming. Doornik, J.A. and H. Hansen (1994). A practical test for univariate and multivariate normality. Manuscript, Nuffield College, Oxford University, U.K.. Hansen, H. and S. Johansen (1999). Some tests for parameter constancy in cointegrated VAR-models, Econometrics Journal 2, 306-333. Gourinchas, P-O. and H. Rey (2005). International financial adjustment, Working Paper No. 11155, National Bureau of Economic Research. Johansen, S. (1996). Likelihood-based inference in cointegrated vector autoregressive models, 2nd ed. Advanced Texts in Econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Juselius, K. (2005). Lecture notes on advanced macroeconometrics. Lane, P. (2006). The Swedish external position and the Kroner, mimeo, Trinity College, Dublin. Lane, P. and G.M. Melesi-Ferretti (2002). External wealth, the trade balance, and the real exchange rate, European Economic Review 46, 1049-1071. 24 Lane, P. and G.M. Melesi-Ferretti (2004).The transfer problem revisited: Net foreign assets and real exchange rates, The Review of Economics and Statistics 86(4), 841-857. Lindblad, H. and P. Sellin (2003). The equilibrium rate of unemployment and the real exchange rate: an unobserved components system approach, Working Paper No. 152, Sveriges Riksbank. Meese, R. and K. Rogoff (1983). Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies: do they fit out of sample? Journal of International Economics 53, 29-52. Molodtsova, T. and D. Papell (2006). The out-of-sample performance of empirical exchange rate models from the 1970’s to the 2000’s, mimeo, University of Houston, Houston, TX. Mendoza, E. (1995). The terms of trade, the real exchange rate, and economic fluctuations, International Economic Review 36(1), 101-137. Nilsson, K. (2004). Do fundamentals explain the behaviour of the Swedish real effective exchange rate? Scandinavian Journal of Economics 106(4),603622. Obstfeld, M. and K. Rogoff (2004). The unsustainable US current account position revisited, Working Paper No. 10869, National Bureau of Economic Research. West, K. (2006). Forecast evaluation. In Handbook of Economic Forecasting, Vol. 1, G. Elliot, C.W.J. Granger and A. Timmerman (eds.), Elsevier B.V. 25 Appendix: Data The data set spans the period 1984Q1 to 2005Q3. The data set thus allows for up to 4 lags in the models. Current data series are imported from EcoWin to the largest extent possible (the series name is given within square brackets below). Some of the series have been linked back in time to earlier series as indicated. Some earlier data for the Euro zone are taken from the Area Wide Model (See Fagan, Henry, and Mestre (2001)). Real exchange rates The real SEK/EUR is obtained from crossing the SEK/USD and EUR/USD, which are both available in EcoWin. Consumer price indexes are used to convert nominal exchange rates into real exchange rates. SEK/USD Kronor per one US dollar [oecd:swe_ccusma02_stq]. EUR/USD Euros per one US dollar [oecd:emu_ccusma02_stq]. SEK/TCW The nominal effective exchange rate using the IMF:s competitiveness weights (1991 vintage). The fixed exchange rate of the Krona was abandoned on 19 November 1992. Therefore, the index is set equal to 100 on 18 November 1992, which can be translated into a value of 106.17 for the 4th quarter of 1992. The real index has as its base November 1992=100. This translates into a value of 105.75 for the 4th quarter of 1992. (Source: Sveriges Riksbank). Sweden, consumer price index [oecd:swe_cpaltt01_ixobq]. Euro zone, HICP consumer price index [emu_cphptt01_ixnbq]. This series in available starting in 1990Q1. Data for 1984Q2-1989Q4 are taken from the Area Wide Model. U.S.A., consumer price index [oecd:usa_cpaltt01_ixobq]. TCW-weighted consumer price index (Source: Sveriges Riksbank). Terms of trade Terms of trade is computed as the ratio between export prices and import prices. Sweden, export price index [ifs:s1447400dzfq]. Sweden, import price index [ifs:s1447500dzfq]. Euro zone, export price index. Data for 1984Q1-2003Q4 are taken from the Area Wide Model. Data for 2004Q1-2005Q3 are from ECB Monthly Bulletin. Euro zone, import price index. Data for 1984Q1-2003Q4 are taken from the Area Wide Model. Data for 2004Q1-2005Q3 are from ECB Monthly Bulletin. U.S.A., export price index [ifs:s1117400dzfq]. U.S.A., import price index [ifs:s1117500dzfq]. Output 26 Sweden, gross domestic product, seasonally adjusted [ew:swe_01950]. This series is available starting 1993Q1. Data for 1984Q2-1992Q4 are from Sveriges Riksbank. An index is created which is set equal to 100 in 2000. Euro zone, gross domestic product, seasonally adjusted [ifs:s16399b0rywq]. The series is available starting 1999Q1. Data for 1984Q2-1998Q4 is from Sveriges Riksbank (this series is updated on a more timely basis compared to Ecowin[ifs:s16399b0rywq], which could serve as an alternative source together with the Area Wide Model for extensions back in time). An index is created which is set equal to 100 in 2000. U.S.A., gross domestic product [ifs:s11199b0rzfq]. An index is created which is set equal to 100 in 2000. TCW-weighted gross domestic product (Source: Sveriges Riksbank). Net foreign assets The net foreign asset position relative to nominal GDP is the measure used. Our preferred choice for net foreign assets is the net international investment position with market valued foreign direct investment. Unfortunately such a series is available only for the last few quarters for the Euro zone, which is why cumulated current accounts have been used in this case. Sweden, net international investment position, market valued FDI (Source: Sveriges Riksbank) This is an annual series. A quarterly series has been obtained by linearly interpolating so that the annual figure is reached in the 4 th quarter. Sweden, gross domestic product, current prices [oe:swe_gdpq]. Euro zone, net foreign assets, data 1984Q2-2003Q4 from the Area Wide Model. This series is updated for 2004Q1-2005Q3 using the computed growth factors from the cumulated current account balances based on [oe:euro_cbq]. Euro zone, gross domestic product, current prices [oe:euro_gdpq]. U.S.A., net international investment position, market valued FDI [ew:usa16101]. This is an annual series. A quarterly series has been obtained by linearly interpolating so that the annual figure is reached in the 4th quarter. U.S.A., gross domestic product, current prices [oe:usa_gdpq]. 27 Table 1. Descriptive statistics of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: real effective exchange rate, qt , relative output, yt , terms of trade, t , net foreign assets, bt , trade balance, tbt , nominal effective exchange rate, et , and relative price, pt . Variable qt yt Standard JarqueMean Maximum Minimum deviation Skewness Kurtosis Bera 4.793 4.977 4.597 0.098 -0.15 2.14 2.86 0.012 0.059 -0.037 0.026 0.04 1.77 5.27 t bt 4.630 4.711 4.485 0.062 -0.79 2.23 10.59 -0.160 0.215 -0.410 0.154 0.34 2.49 2.52 tbt 0.045 0.089 0.002 0.022 -0.23 1.74 6.25 et pt q t yt t bt tbt et p t 4.749 4.937 4.563 0.115 -0.24 1.46 9.01 -0.004 0.112 -0.073 0.053 0.64 2.46 6.66 0.002 0.110 -0.076 0.025 0.88 6.82 61.09 0.000 0.010 -0.012 0.005 -0.14 2.76 0.47 0.000 0.054 -0.031 0.014 1.29 6.06 55.18 0.001 0.068 -0.070 0.030 0.15 2.67 0.69 0.0004 0.035 -0.031 0.009 -0.01 6.46 41.34 0.004 0.130 -0.073 0.025 1.40 10.24 208.48 -0.001 0.013 -0.034 0.008 -1.72 7.99 126.99 28 Table 2. Johansen cointegration test Sample (adjusted): 1985Q1 2005Q3 Included observations: 83 after adjustments Trend assumption: No deterministic trend (restricted constant) Series: qt , yt , t , bt Lags interval (in first differences): 1 to 2 Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Trace) Hypothesized No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Trace Statistic 0.05 Critical Value Prob.** None * At most 1 At most 2 At most 3 0.315642 0.159804 0.112177 0.035330 58.79283 27.31303 12.86102 2.985445 54.07904 35.19275 20.26184 9.164546 0.0179 0.2734 0.3750 0.5834 Trace test indicates 1 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Maximum Eigenvalue) Hypothesized No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Max-Eigen Statistic 0.05 Critical Value Prob.** None * At most 1 At most 2 At most 3 0.315642 0.159804 0.112177 0.035330 31.47980 14.45201 9.875576 2.985445 28.58808 22.29962 15.89210 9.164546 0.0207 0.4215 0.3458 0.5834 Max-eigenvalue test indicates 1 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values Unrestricted Cointegrating Coefficients (normalized by b'*S11*b=I): qt yt t bt -20.16761 5.246184 -2.055866 3.086618 -18.86939 51.49897 -10.96593 -15.08201 -10.68840 11.27004 -22.01646 6.920338 3.581216 -6.387902 -5.696369 -3.734962 Constant 147.1160 -79.08079 110.9626 -46.92688 Unrestricted Adjustment Coefficients (alpha): q t yt t bt 0.005788 -0.006232 0.002556 0.002256 -0.001579 -0.000933 0.000654 -0.000241 0.001731 0.002892 0.002887 -0.001149 -0.005841 0.003652 0.002762 0.003342 29 Table 3. The estimated real SEK/TCW unrestricted model Vector Error Correction Estimates Sample (adjusted): 1985Q1 2005Q3 Included observations: 83 after adjustments t-statistics in [ ] Cointegrating Eq: CointEq1 qt 1 1.000000 y t 1 0.721723 [ 1.27477] t 1 0.497981 [ 2.37698] bt 1 -0.167318 [-2.03297] Constant -7.145720 [-7.38777] Error Correction: Adjustment coeff. qt 1 qt 2 y t 1 yt 2 t 1 t 2 q t yt t bt -0.105660 [-1.88693] 0.031653 [ 2.88481] -0.036372 [-0.99109] 0.131003 [ 2.00194] 0.158565 [ 1.50949] -0.010586 [-0.51428] 0.087042 [ 1.26430] 0.274976 [ 2.23998] -0.009676 [-0.09124] 0.035030 [ 1.68568] -0.020194 [-0.29054] -0.020162 [-0.16268] 1.379069 [ 2.34125] -0.061501 [-0.53285] 0.158269 [ 0.40997] -0.884125 [-1.28440] 0.496111 [ 0.85026] 0.021049 [ 0.18411] 0.067015 [ 0.17525] -1.704901 [-2.50033] -0.010619 [-0.05877] -0.017518 [-0.49485] 0.353144 [ 2.98248] 0.067466 [ 0.31955] -0.032999 [-0.18329] 0.033940 [ 0.96202] -0.061293 [-0.51944] 0.009220 [ 0.04382] 30 bt 1 0.151809 [ 1.69914] 0.016944 [ 0.96787] 0.069842 [ 1.19274] 0.307913 [ 2.94907] -0.150554 [-1.67905] 0.017709 [ 1.00790] -0.071242 [-1.21229] 0.337025 [ 3.21632] DUMMY92_4 0.073540 [ 3.29461] -0.003204 [-0.73245] -0.024501 [-1.67481] 0.043336 [ 1.66131] DUMMY93_1 0.102368 [ 4.33172] 0.014474 [ 3.12564] -0.025079 [-1.61919] -0.049254 [-1.78345] DUMMY95 -0.005726 [-1.26178] -2.68E-05 [-0.03013] 0.001742 [ 0.58556] 0.000994 [ 0.18746] 0.408592 0.316966 0.030410 0.020696 4.459325 210.5692 -4.784800 -4.435088 0.002486 0.025041 0.391096 0.296758 0.001168 0.004055 4.145717 345.8510 -8.044602 -7.694890 -0.000207 0.004836 0.217618 0.096404 0.013062 0.013564 1.795317 245.6386 -5.629846 -5.280134 -0.000324 0.014269 0.428525 0.339987 0.041530 0.024185 4.840000 197.6354 -4.473143 -4.123431 0.001050 0.029770 Determinant resid covariance (dof adj.) Determinant resid covariance Log likelihood Akaike information criterion Schwarz criterion 6.83E-16 3.66E-16 1003.993 -22.91550 -21.37094 bt 2 R-squared Adj. R-squared Sum sq. resids S.E. equation F-statistic Log likelihood Akaike AIC Schwarz SC Mean dependent S.D. dependent 31 Table 4. The nominal SEK/TCW restricted BM model with interest rate differential Vector Error Correction Estimates Sample: 1985Q1 2005Q3 Included observations: 83 t-statistics in [ ] Cointegration Restrictions: B(1,1)=1,B(1,2)=1,B(1,3)=0.7,B(1,4)=0.7,B(1,5)=0.014,B(1,6)=0 Convergence achieved after 14 iterations. Restrictions identify all cointegrating vectors LR test for binding restrictions (rank = 1): Chi-square(5) 12.39716 Probability 0.029733 Cointegrating Eq: CointEq1 et 1 1.000000 pt 1 1.000000 y t 1 0.700000 t 1 0.700000 bt 1 0.014000 cit 1 0.000000 Constant -8.045304 [-668.579] Error Correction: Adjustment coeff. et 1 et 2 pt 1 pt 2 et p t yt t bt it -0.115907 [-2.09705] -0.053863 [-2.83798] 0.030434 [ 2.55059] -0.027537 [-0.73143] 0.029047 [ 0.40093] -6.918386 [-2.11493] 0.104140 [ 1.03373] -0.006360 [-0.18385] -0.015603 [-0.71745] 0.148649 [ 2.16624] 0.285725 [ 2.16373] 2.151027 [ 0.36077] -0.031211 [-0.31189] 0.032419 [ 0.94344] 0.047160 [ 2.18299] -0.041647 [-0.61099] 0.009048 [ 0.06898] 0.733746 [ 0.12389] 0.519122 [ 1.15123] 0.163929 [ 1.05869] 0.202988 [ 2.08521] -0.683171 [-2.22420] 0.841427 [ 1.42355] -82.96637 [-3.10877] -0.404652 [-0.83907] 0.134393 [ 0.81154] -0.172185 [-1.65385] 0.369047 [ 1.12343] 0.548080 [ 0.86700] 32.45194 [ 1.13697] 32 y t 1 1.000602 [ 1.86566] 0.493932 [ 2.68200] -0.029123 [-0.25153] 0.053979 [ 0.14776] -0.591317 [-0.84111] 62.25682 [ 1.96133] 0.552272 [ 0.99935] 0.211955 [ 1.11694] 0.026893 [ 0.22542] 0.162829 [ 0.43256] -1.357045 [-1.87336] 8.239300 [ 0.25191] -0.027523 [-0.15843] 0.066514 [ 1.11500] -0.037143 [-0.99039] 0.350609 [ 2.96289] 0.149993 [ 0.65868] 7.013416 [ 0.68212] 0.036406 [ 0.21206] 0.013802 [ 0.23413] 0.016823 [ 0.45391] -0.035936 [-0.30730] -0.010483 [-0.04658] 3.780164 [ 0.37204] 0.159991 [ 1.90818] -0.024464 [-0.84970] 0.025644 [ 1.41676] 0.056033 [ 0.98112] 0.297877 [ 2.71034] -3.086917 [-0.62207] -0.141594 [-1.69909] 0.009289 [ 0.32460] 0.015065 [ 0.83741] -0.067500 [-1.18912] 0.346751 [ 3.17432] 2.802869 [ 0.56828] it 1 -0.005457 [-1.89125] -0.000522 [-0.52704] -0.000907 [-1.45529] 0.003119 [ 1.58674] -0.001299 [-0.34341] 0.843587 [ 4.93947] it 2 0.000805 [ 0.27529] -0.000267 [-0.26614] 0.001341 [ 2.12303] -0.000690 [-0.34627] 0.000531 [ 0.13842] -0.161764 [-0.93423] DUMMY92_4 0.091619 [ 3.81003] -0.002579 [-0.31237] 0.001017 [ 0.19589] -0.036385 [-2.22135] 0.029258 [ 0.92823] -2.648199 [-1.86075] DUMMY93_1 0.121065 [ 5.21569] -0.010765 [-1.35060] 0.011535 [ 2.30198] -0.031271 [-1.97784] -0.053330 [-1.75278] -2.810359 [-2.04573] DUMMY95 0.001617 [ 0.21476] -0.006547 [-2.53198] 0.000572 [ 0.35157] -0.006353 [-1.23867] 0.004544 [ 0.46036] -0.131004 [-0.29395] 0.531189 0.426232 0.024227 0.019016 5.060991 220.0027 -4.915727 -4.449445 0.003723 0.025104 0.392669 0.256699 0.002857 0.006530 2.887916 308.7220 -7.053542 -6.587260 -0.001195 0.007574 0.411196 0.279374 0.001129 0.004105 3.119327 347.2440 -7.981783 -7.515501 -0.000207 0.004836 0.326723 0.175989 0.011241 0.012953 2.167552 251.8714 -5.683647 -5.217365 -0.000324 0.014269 0.427204 0.298966 0.041626 0.024926 3.331338 197.5396 -4.374447 -3.908165 0.001050 0.029770 0.632793 0.550582 84.86066 1.125423 7.697220 -118.6920 3.245589 3.711872 1.339998 1.678768 yt 2 t 1 t 2 bt 1 bt 2 R-squared Adj. R-squared Sum sq. resids S.E. equation F-statistic Log likelihood Akaike AIC Schwarz SC Mean dependent S.D. dependent Determinant resid covariance (dof adj.) Determinant resid covariance Log likelihood 1.81E-20 5.00E-21 1233.313 33 Table 5. The nominal SEK/TCW restricted AM model with interest rate differential. Vector Error Correction Estimates Sample: 1985Q1 2005Q3 Included observations: 83 t-statistics in [ ] Cointegration Restrictions: B(1,1)=1,B(1,2)=1,B(1,3)=0.7,B(1,4)=0.7,B(1,5)=-1.4,B(1,6)=0 Convergence achieved after 11 iterations. Restrictions identify all cointegrating vectors LR test for binding restrictions (rank = 1): Chi-square(5) 16.13065 Probability 0.006481 Cointegrating Eq: CointEq1 et 1 1.000000 pt 1 1.000000 y t 1 0.700000 t 1 0.700000 tbt 1 -1.400000 cit 1 0.000000 Constant -7.956576 [-700.331] Error Correction: Adjustment coeff. et 1 pt 1 yt 1 et p t yt t tbt it -0.109513 [-2.37372] -0.038682 [-2.51555] 0.027775 [ 2.66481] -0.021765 [-0.70152] 0.024292 [ 1.17594] -5.609177 [-2.25646] 0.114614 [ 1.24112] -0.021746 [-0.70651] 0.002813 [ 0.13482] 0.094372 [ 1.51964] 0.059470 [ 1.43820] 2.961879 [ 0.59526] 0.108387 [ 0.36715] 0.334972 [ 3.40431] 0.089771 [ 1.34597] -0.345692 [-1.74130] -0.026555 [-0.20089] -70.64450 [-4.44122] 0.737089 [ 1.44386] 0.505509 [ 2.97094] 0.061541 [ 0.53359] 0.086956 [ 0.25329] -0.134147 [-0.58686] 59.07517 [ 2.14770] 34 t 1 -0.023725 [-0.14793] 0.061247 [ 1.14578] 0.004183 [ 0.11545] 0.286975 [ 2.66087] 0.019762 [ 0.27519] 6.644800 [ 0.76896] 0.197186 [ 0.82438] -0.044205 [-0.55447] 0.011651 [ 0.21560] -0.013073 [-0.08128] -0.373864 [-3.49073] -37.80452 [-2.93332] it 1 -0.002556 [-1.96337] -0.001400 [-3.22529] 1.21E-05 [ 0.04100] 0.001011 [ 1.15455] 0.001028 [ 1.76284] 0.787893 [ 11.2312] DUMMY92_4 0.075059 [ 3.55958] 0.002775 [ 0.39489] -0.003736 [-0.78413] -0.027771 [-1.95846] 0.001948 [ 0.20635] -1.851271 [-1.62941] DUMMY93_1 0.121437 [ 5.68051] -0.012642 [-1.77418] 0.013971 [ 2.89267] -0.026281 [-1.82809] -0.006357 [-0.66408] -3.374280 [-2.92940] 0.467910 0.410387 0.027497 0.019276 8.134283 214.7482 -4.957789 -4.695505 0.003723 0.025104 0.350565 0.280356 0.003055 0.006425 4.993145 305.9403 -7.155188 -6.892904 -0.001195 0.007574 0.268105 0.188981 0.001403 0.004355 3.388423 338.2160 -7.932915 -7.670631 -0.000207 0.004836 0.255203 0.174684 0.012435 0.012963 3.169492 247.6817 -5.751367 -5.489083 -0.000324 0.014269 0.187712 0.099897 0.005513 0.008631 2.137581 281.4374 -6.564757 -6.302473 0.000375 0.009098 0.654571 0.617228 79.82767 1.038630 17.52833 -116.1546 3.015774 3.278058 1.339998 1.678768 tbt 1 R-squared Adj. R-squared Sum sq. resids S.E. equation F-statistic Log likelihood Akaike AIC Schwarz SC Mean dependent S.D. dependent Determinant resid covariance (dof adj.) Determinant resid covariance Log likelihood 2.21E-21 1.11E-21 1295.749 35 Table 6. Forecast evaluation: Real SEK/TCW benchmark model Panel A. Unrestricted model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 ˆ VEC 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 0.589 1.403 2.172 2.940 3.590 4.539 5.086 5.287 6.016 6.563 7.229 8.000 0.515 1.317 2.072 2.795 3.402 4.319 4.822 4.985 5.666 6.163 6.807 7.527 2 ˆ RW 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 2 ˆ VAR 0.553 1.333 2.084 2.806 3.406 4.319 4.808 4.956 5.611 6.092 6.683 7.379 0.526 1.296 2.168 3.001 3.582 4.555 5.098 5.476 6.097 6.513 7.382 8.569 2 VEC ˆ 0.474 1.067 1.719 2.407 2.970 3.692 4.114 4.465 4.963 5.240 5.772 6.410 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.24 (-0.67) 1.31 (-2.30) 1.26 (-2.41) 1.22 (-2.03) 1.21 (-1.89) 1.23 (-2.35) 1.24 (-2.37) 1.18 (-1.34) 1.21 (-1.38) 1.25 (-1.42) 1.25 (-1.28) 1.25 (-1.10) 1.12 (-0.79) 1.08 (-0.37) 1.00 ( 0.38) 0.98 ( 0.53) 1.00 ( 0.38) 1.00 ( 0.40) 1.00 ( 0.43) 0.97 ( 0.64) 0.99 ( 0.53) 1.01 ( 0.41) 0.98 ( 0.50) 0.93 ( 0.65) 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.15 ( 0.43) 1.30 (-0.44) 1.30 (-0.85) 1.26 (-0.81) 1.27 (-0.85) 1.31 (-1.06) 1.38 (-1.21) 1.45 (-1.28) 1.51 (-1.33) 1.17 (-1.31) 1.69 (-1.39) 1.79 (-1.55) 1.03 ( 0.35) 1.07 ( 0.11) 1.03 ( 0.28) 1.01 ( 0.39) 1.06 ( 0.28) 1.07 ( 0.28) 1.11 ( 0.15) 1.18 (-0.07) 1.23 (-0.22) 1.29 (-0.35) 1.18 (-0.49) 1.34 (-0.61) Panel B. Restricted model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 ˆ 2 VEC ˆ 0.544 1.387 2.239 3.035 3.786 4.854 5.667 6.464 7.499 8.376 9.782 11.456 2 -adj. VEC ˆ 0.431 1.185 2.012 2.743 3.386 4.329 4.999 5.627 6.478 7.155 8.320 9.786 0.474 1.067 1.719 2.407 2.970 3.692 4.114 4.465 4.963 5.240 5.772 6.410 2 RW ˆ -adj. 0.493 1.261 2.035 2.734 3.355 4.287 4.940 5.553 6.384 7.032 8.195 9.629 2 VAR 0.526 1.296 2.168 3.001 3.582 4.555 5.098 5.476 6.097 6.513 7.382 8.569 Panel C. Restricted model with real interest rate differential Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 ˆ 2 VEC 0.553 1.191 1.471 1.812 2.012 2.550 2.915 3.267 3.673 4.187 5.333 6.654 ˆ 2 -adj. VEC ˆ 0.291 0.635 0.889 0.999 1.006 1.373 1.585 1.727 2.044 2.490 3.462 4.649 0.474 1.067 1.719 2.407 2.970 3.692 4.114 4.465 4.963 5.240 5.772 6.410 2 RW ˆ 2 VEC -adj. 0.404 0.900 1.155 1.386 1.500 2.002 2.321 2.607 2.952 3.392 4.456 5.678 ˆ 2 VAR 0.489 1.199 1.951 2.706 3.243 4.263 4.946 5.551 6.218 6.881 8.149 9.610 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.17 (1.19) 1.05 (0.98) 0.86 (1.11) 0.75 (1.18) 0.68 (1.33) 0.69 (1.41) 0.71 (1.49) 0.73 (1.58) 0.74 (1.73) 0.80 (1.56) 0.92 (1.25) 1.04 (0.97) 1.13 (0.98) 0.99 (1.41) 0.86 (2.14) 0.67 (2.15) 0.62 (2.20) 0.60 (2.45) 0.59 (2.64) 0.73 (2.94) 0.59 (3.21) 0.61 (3.62) 0.65 (4.07) 0.69 (3.88) NOTE. Cases when the Clark-West test statistic is significant at the 10 percent level or better have been shaded. 36 Table 7. Forecast evaluation: Real SEK/TCW alternative model Panel A. Unrestricted model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 ˆ VEC 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 0.532 1.172 1.899 2.522 3.075 3.851 4.346 4.620 5.093 5.327 5.846 6.610 0.468 1.113 1.826 2.440 2.979 3.741 4.223 4.479 4.933 5.144 5.639 6.376 2 ˆ RW 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 2 ˆ VAR 0.521 1.166 1.894 2.517 3.068 3.841 4.330 4.599 5.065 5.290 5.798 6.551 0.485 1.109 1.847 2.489 3.006 3.742 4.213 4.482 4.897 5.105 5.597 6.288 2 VEC ˆ 0.474 1.067 1.719 2.407 2.970 3.692 4.114 4.465 4.963 5.240 5.772 6.410 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.12 ( 0.12) 1.10 (-0.36) 1.10 (-0.69) 1.05 (-0.17) 1.04 (-0.03) 1.04 (-0.13) 1.06 (-0.24) 1.03 (-0.03) 1.03 ( 0.05) 1.02 ( 0.16) 1.01 ( 0.20) 1.03 ( 0.04) 1.10 (-0.88) 1.06 (-1.35) 1.03 (-1.72) 1.01 (-0.95) 1.02 (-0.98) 1.03 (-0.84) 1.03 (-0.70) 1.03 (-0.50) 1.04 (-0.62) 1.04 (-0.64) 1.04 (-0.62) 1.05 (-0.64) 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.05 ( 0.62) 1.09 (-0.08) 1.12 (-0.43) 1.09 (-0.36) 1.10 (-0.56) 1.12 (-0.86) 1.17 (-1.34) 1.19 (-1.43) 1.20 (-1.22) 1.20 (-1.11) 1.18 (-0.99) 1.19 (-1.07) 1.03 ( 0.27) 1.05 (-0.07) 1.04 (-0.08) 1.05 (-0.17) 1.08 (-0.48) 1.10 (-0.70) 1.14 (-1.03) 1.19 (-1.31) 1.22 (-1.46) 1.23 (-1.40) 1.22 (-1.34) 1.21 (-1.46) Panel B. Restricted model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 ˆ 2 VEC ˆ 0.498 1.163 1.925 2.617 3.259 4.120 4.797 5.319 5.962 6.272 6.832 7.638 2 -adj. VEC ˆ 0.425 1.082 1.825 2.500 3.116 3.948 4.589 5.069 5.663 5.924 6.422 7.166 0.474 1.067 1.719 2.407 2.970 3.692 4.114 4.465 4.963 5.240 5.772 6.410 2 RW ˆ -adj. 0.466 1.119 1.866 2.539 3.159 3.994 4.640 5.124 5.727 5.996 6.509 7.268 2 VAR 0.485 1.109 1.847 2.489 3.006 3.742 4.213 4.482 4.897 5.105 5.597 6.288 Panel C. Restricted model with real interest rate differential Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 ˆ 2 VEC 0.417 0.945 1.481 2.045 2.516 3.298 3.854 4.359 4.962 5.346 5.984 7.011 ˆ 2 -adj. VEC ˆ 0.307 0.819 1.323 1.887 2.341 3.108 3.644 4.125 4.707 5.094 5.691 6.667 0.474 1.067 1.719 2.407 2.970 3.692 4.114 4.465 4.963 5.240 5.772 6.410 2 RW ˆ 2 VEC -adj. 0.372 0.897 1.432 2.005 2.484 3.273 3.836 4.343 4.945 5.323 5.952 6.962 ˆ 2 VAR 0.451 1.013 1.659 2.282 2.778 3.573 4.046 4.482 4.998 5.336 5.892 6.839 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 0.88 ( 2.25) 0.89 ( 1.75) 0.86 ( 1.82) 0.85 ( 2.35) 0.85 ( 2.23) 0.89 ( 2.00) 0.94 ( 1.42) 0.98 ( 0.84) 1.00 ( 0.49) 1.02 ( 0.26) 1.04 ( 0.15) 1.09 (-0.40) 0.92 ( 1.22) 0.93 ( 1.19) 0.89 ( 1.59) 0.90 ( 1.57) 0.91 ( 1.69) 0.92 ( 1.78) 0.95 ( 1.45) 0.97 ( 1.10) 0.99 ( 0.45) 1.00 ( 0.08) 1.02 (-0.25) 1.03 (-0.33) NOTE. Cases when the Clark-West test statistic is significant at the 10 percent level or better have been shaded. 37 Table 8. Forecast evaluation: Nominal SEK/TCW, restricted model with real interest rate differential Panel A. Benchmark model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 ˆ 2 VEC 0.522 1.194 1.659 2.290 3.133 4.429 5.696 6.958 9.024 11.516 15.052 20.274 ˆ 2 -adj. VEC ˆ 0.323 0.834 1.248 1.667 2.237 3.093 3.732 4.112 5.019 5.912 7.225 9.716 0.425 0.984 1.568 2.220 2.755 3.394 3.750 4.069 4.450 4.704 5.052 5.568 2 RW ˆ 2 VEC -adj. ˆ 2 VAR 0.466 1.111 1.601 2.238 3.085 4.348 5.523 6.607 8.381 10.404 13.230 17.376 0.454 1.164 1.827 2.420 2.989 3.804 4.389 4.742 5.452 6.281 7.603 9.388 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 2 ˆ VAR 0.370 0.865 1.294 1.699 2.041 2.544 2.911 3.188 3.655 3.931 4.269 4.853 0.409 0.936 1.454 1.942 2.334 2.870 3.147 3.335 3.717 3.955 4.352 5.105 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.23 ( 0.95) 1.21 ( 0.52) 1.06 ( 0.78) 1.37 ( 0.88) 1.14 ( 0.64) 1.30 ( 0.27) 1.52 ( 0.01) 1.71 (-0.02) 2.03 (-0.18) 2.45 (-0.31) 2.98 (-0.48) 3.64 (-0.75) 1.15 (-0.19) 1.03 ( 0.44) 0.91 ( 1.77) 0.95 ( 1.26) 1.05 (-0.53) 1.16 (-1.41) 1.30 (-1.43) 1.47 (-1.37) 1.66 (-1.35) 1.83 (-1.34) 1.98 (-1.32) 2.16 (-1.34) 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 0.96 (1.46) 0.95 (1.17) 0.89 (1.52) 0.82 (2.14) 0.79 (2.27) 0.79 (2.23) 0.81 (2.04) 0.82 (1.85) 0.86 (1.52) 0.87 (1.36) 0.88 (1.41) 0.91 (1.32) 0.99 (0.70) 1.00 (0.60) 0.96 (0.81) 0.93 (0.89) 0.93 (0.93) 0.93 (0.88) 0.81 (0.56) 1.00 (0.30) 1.03 (0.12) 1.04 (0.04) 1.02 (0.13) 0.99 (0.40) Panel B. Alternative model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 ˆ VEC 0.406 0.932 1.397 1.815 2.172 2.679 3.055 3.342 3.819 4.105 4.457 5.057 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 0.328 0.787 1.171 1.559 1.874 2.354 2.666 2.892 3.319 3.608 3.970 4.604 2 ˆ RW 0.425 0.984 1.568 2.220 2.755 3.394 3.750 4.069 4.450 4.704 5.052 5.568 NOTE. Cases when the Clark-West test statistic is significant at the 10 percent level or better have been shaded 38 Table 9. Descriptive statistics of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: real SEK/EUR exchange rate, qt , relative output, yt , relative terms of trade, t , relative net foreign assets, bt , nominal SEK/EUR exchange rate, et , and relative price, p t . Variable qt yt t bt et pt q t yt t bt et p t Mean Standard JarqueMaximum Minimum deviation Skewness Kurtosis Bera 2.111 2.274 1.926 0.093 -0.27 1.93 4.94 0.006 0.063 -0.062 0.033 -0.13 1.97 3.92 0.017 0.096 -0.137 0.061 -1.03 2.95 14.79 -0.145 0.216 -0.377 0.141 0.36 2.73 2.10 2.110 2.273 1.846 0.115 -0.51 1.86 8.15 0.002 0.131 -0.074 0.057 0.74 2.63 8.06 0.003 0.106 -0.069 0.026 0.58 5.45 25.42 <0.001 0.016 -0.015 0.006 -0.13 3.24 0.44 -0.002 0.029 -0.025 0.010 0.57 3.45 5.23 0.001 0.067 -0.070 0.030 0.10 2.74 0.38 0.005 0.125 -0.067 0.026 0.95 7.70 88.99 -0.001 0.013 -0.033 0.008 -1.49 6.98 85.48 39 Table 10. Johansen cointegration test Sample: 1985Q1 2005Q3 Included observations: 83 Trend assumption: No deterministic trend (restricted constant) Series: LNRSEKEUR LNY_SEEU LNTOT_SEEU NFA_SEEU Lags interval (in first differences): 1 to 2 Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Trace) Hypothesized No. of CE(s) None * At most 1 At most 2 At most 3 Eigenvalue Trace Statistic 0.05 Critical Value Prob.** 0.363604 0.160632 0.070195 0.024015 60.10271 22.59218 8.058406 2.017603 54.07904 35.19275 20.26184 9.164546 0.0132 0.5556 0.8195 0.7742 Trace test indicates 1 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Maximum Eigenvalue) Hypothesized No. of CE(s) None * At most 1 At most 2 At most 3 Eigenvalue Max-Eigen Statistic 0.05 Critical Value Prob.** 0.363604 0.160632 0.070195 0.024015 37.51053 14.53377 6.040803 2.017603 28.58808 22.29962 15.89210 9.164546 0.0028 0.4144 0.7834 0.7742 Max-eigenvalue test indicates 1 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values 40 Table 11. The estimated real SEK/EUR unrestricted model Vector Error Correction Estimates Sample: 1985Q1 2005Q3 Included observations: 83 t-statistics in [ ] Cointegrating Eq: CointEq1 qt 1 1.000000 yt 1 0.503960 [ 1.58173] t 1 0.402381 [ 1.66822] bt 1 -0.170795 [-2.19522] Constant -2.152460 [-137.587] Error Correction: Adjustment coeff. q t 1 q t 2 y t 1 y t 2 t 1 t 2 bt 1 q t yt t bt -0.097566 [-1.71016] 0.041227 [ 3.20999] -0.016361 [-0.61275] 0.160939 [ 2.68749] 0.115841 [ 1.02775] -0.017513 [-0.69020] 0.019580 [ 0.37117] 0.288783 [ 2.44085] -0.024933 [-0.22247] 0.029075 [ 1.15233] -0.012079 [-0.23027] -0.061913 [-0.52627] 0.911675 [ 1.77925] -0.045989 [-0.39868] 0.035760 [ 0.14912] -1.095665 [-2.03714] 0.567378 [ 1.08505] -0.007916 [-0.06724] 0.140779 [ 0.57524] -1.491781 [-2.71786] -0.012187 [-0.04698] -0.019382 [-0.33189] 0.261356 [ 2.15269] 0.420652 [ 1.54485] 0.106949 [ 0.40775] -0.018412 [-0.31182] -0.116826 [-0.95166] -0.178961 [-0.65000] 0.121486 0.013586 0.080486 0.320806 41 [ 1.23532] [ 0.61366] [ 1.74867] [ 3.10772] -0.182753 [-1.88521] 0.010288 [ 0.47140] -0.097852 [-2.15671] 0.322369 [ 3.16805] DUMMY92_4 0.056403 [ 2.37508] 0.001929 [ 0.36076] -0.013549 [-1.21901] 0.043974 [ 1.76407] DUMMY93_1 0.093192 [ 3.84800] 0.019027 [ 3.48978] -0.023468 [-2.07041] -0.038744 [-1.52408] DUMMY95 -0.003121 [-0.69208] -4.31E-05 [-0.04245] -0.000448 [-0.21206] 0.001930 [ 0.40779] 0.342649 0.240805 0.035332 0.022308 3.364473 204.3436 -4.634787 -4.285075 0.003391 0.025602 0.361226 0.262261 0.001791 0.005022 3.650037 328.1057 -7.617005 -7.267293 5.31E-05 0.005847 0.126251 -0.009118 0.007739 0.010441 0.932643 267.3600 -6.153252 -5.803540 -0.002326 0.010393 0.459449 0.375702 0.038929 0.023416 5.486142 200.3197 -4.537825 -4.188113 0.000561 0.029635 Determinant resid covariance (dof adj.) Determinant resid covariance Log likelihood 5.62E-16 3.01E-16 1012.142 bt 2 R-squared Adj. R-squared Sum sq. resids S.E. equation F-statistic Log likelihood Akaike AIC Schwarz SC Mean dependent S.D. dependent 42 Table 12. Descriptive statistics of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: real SEK/USD exchange rate, qt , relative output, yt , relative terms of trade, t , relative net foreign assets, bt , nominal SEK/USD exchange rate, et , and relative price, p t . Variable qt yt t bt et pt q t yt t bt et p t Standard JarqueMean Maximum Minimum deviation Skewness Kurtosis Bera 1.976 2.361 1.590 0.185 0.24 2.48 1.75 0.059 0.162 -0.010 0.058 0.54 1.65 10.29 -0.005 0.076 -0.139 0.059 -0.59 2.02 8.09 -0.080 0.443 -0.391 0.220 0.59 2.15 7.37 2.002 2.360 1.677 0.164 0.29 2.47 2.15 -0.026 0.061 -0.111 0.053 -0.17 1.70 6.23 -0.002 0.164 -0.081 0.050 0.83 3.94 12.65 -0.002 0.010 -0.021 0.006 -0.68 3.80 8.61 0.000 0.034 -0.043 0.014 -0.45 3.24 2.97 0.004 0.087 -0.069 0.032 0.33 3.00 1.49 -0.002 0.186 -0.086 0.050 1.08 4.97 29.45 0.000 0.013 -0.034 0.009 -1.30 5.68 48.43 43 Table 13. Johansen cointegration test Sample: 1985Q1 2005Q3 Included observations: 83 Trend assumption: No deterministic trend (restricted constant) Series: LNNSEKUSD LNCPI_USSE LNY_SEUS LNTOT_SEUS NFA_SEUS Lags interval (in first differences): 1 to 3 Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Trace) Hypothesized No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Trace Statistic 0.05 Critical Value Prob.** None * At most 1 * At most 2 At most 3 At most 4 0.427051 0.252907 0.164417 0.138233 0.055842 102.4536 56.22615 32.02618 17.11723 4.769332 76.97277 54.07904 35.19275 20.26184 9.164546 0.0002 0.0318 0.1056 0.1282 0.3097 Trace test indicates 2 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Maximum Eigenvalue) Hypothesized No. of CE(s) None * At most 1 At most 2 At most 3 At most 4 Eigenvalue Max-Eigen Statistic 0.05 Critical Value Prob.** 0.427051 0.252907 0.164417 0.138233 0.055842 46.22749 24.19997 14.90895 12.34790 4.769332 34.80587 28.58808 22.29962 15.89210 9.164546 0.0015 0.1646 0.3826 0.1667 0.3097 Max-eigenvalue test indicates 1 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values 44 Table 14. The estimated real SEK/USD unrestricted model Vector Error Correction Estimates Sample: 1985Q1 2005Q3 Included observations: 83 t-statistics in [ ] Cointegrating Eq: CointEq1 qt 1 1.000000 yt 1 -1.253421 [-1.37556] t 1 1.222797 [ 2.43515] bt 1 -0.142756 [-0.91365] Constant -2.056432 [-57.1279] Error Correction: Adjustment coeff. qt 1 qt 2 qt 3 yt 1 yt 2 yt 3 q t yt t bt -0.124461 [-2.82573] 0.018874 [ 2.67165] 0.008044 [ 0.52320] 0.014644 [ 0.51270] 0.270349 [ 2.31960] -0.014144 [-0.75664] 0.015654 [ 0.38478] 0.182530 [ 2.41499] -0.016937 [-0.14393] 0.004447 [ 0.23561] -0.005554 [-0.13520] 0.030153 [ 0.39513] 0.392245 [ 3.53430] -0.018475 [-1.03786] -0.118550 [-3.06013] 0.013855 [ 0.19250] 1.684907 [ 2.11584] 0.025671 [ 0.20099] 0.074889 [ 0.26941] -0.697160 [-1.35000] 0.946670 [ 1.18578] 0.172823 [ 1.34965] -0.307933 [-1.10498] -0.653517 [-1.26228] -1.889067 [-2.62575] -0.034710 [-0.30080] 0.262028 [ 1.04339] 0.423850 [ 0.90847] 45 t 1 -0.358333 [-0.97282] 0.031580 [ 0.53454] 0.228351 [ 1.77600] 0.530422 [ 2.22055] 0.030354 [ 0.08149] 0.005104 [ 0.08543] 0.125631 [ 0.96620] 0.233551 [ 0.96683] 0.574684 [ 1.62930] -0.007307 [-0.12916] -0.280459 [-2.27789] -0.249025 [-1.08870] 0.401559 [ 2.52597] 0.011859 [ 0.46508] -0.109977 [-1.98185] 0.558570 [ 5.41812] -0.457066 [-2.65153] 0.018615 [ 0.67327] 0.091866 [ 1.52674] 0.436390 [ 3.90378] 0.129938 [ 0.78507] -0.010912 [-0.41106] -0.008449 [-0.14625] -0.459735 [-4.28325] DUMMY92_4 0.218089 [ 5.27036] -0.011917 [-1.79547] -0.025851 [-1.78967] 0.022862 [ 0.85194] DUMMY93_1 0.136390 [ 2.77252] 0.014325 [ 1.81549] -0.038009 [-2.21343] -0.085596 [-2.68311] DUMMY95 -0.045599 [-3.84033] 0.002025 [ 1.06342] 0.006198 [ 1.49537] 0.001185 [ 0.15395] 0.587697 0.495390 0.084447 0.035502 6.366783 168.1829 -3.667057 -3.200774 -0.001763 0.049978 0.284021 0.123727 0.002172 0.005694 1.771879 320.0837 -7.327318 -6.861035 -0.002167 0.006083 0.393588 0.257824 0.010290 0.012393 2.899063 255.5397 -5.772040 -5.305758 0.000300 0.014385 0.586723 0.494198 0.035514 0.023023 6.341258 204.1301 -4.533255 -4.066972 0.004210 0.032372 Determinant resid covariance (dof adj.) Determinant resid covariance Log likelihood 2.68E-15 1.14E-15 956.9135 t 2 t 3 bt 1 bt 2 bt 3 R-squared Adj. R-squared Sum sq. resids S.E. equation F-statistic Log likelihood Akaike AIC Schwarz SC Mean dependent S.D. dependent 46 Table 15. Forecast evaluation: SEK/EUR benchmark model Panel A. Real exchange rate: unrestricted model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 ˆ VEC 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 0.764 1.847 2.661 3.406 3.996 4.849 5.219 4.820 4.289 3.932 3.545 3.405 0.636 1.517 2.213 2.792 3.178 3.861 4.066 3.653 3.024 2.462 1.857 1.505 2 ˆ RW 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 2 ˆ VAR 0.663 1.620 2.266 2.816 3.143 3.764 3.902 3.436 2.735 2.081 1.379 0.924 0.623 1.556 2.310 2.945 3.085 3.573 3.629 3.503 3.298 3.407 4.019 4.995 0.519 1.135 1.811 2.421 2.642 2.921 2.878 2.671 2.545 2.460 2.705 3.109 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.47 (-0.92) 1.62 (-1.20) 1.47 (-1.32) 1.41 (-1.23) 1.51 (-1.09) 1.66 (-1.35) 1.81 (-1.55) 1.80 (-1.54) 1.69 (-1.09) 1.60 (-0.00) 1.31 ( 1.00) 1.10 ( 1.11) 1.23 (-0.33) 1.19 (-0.15) 1.20 ( 0.07) 1.16 ( 0.16) 1.30 (-0.06) 1.36 (-0.19) 1.44 (-0.26) 1.38 ( 0.07) 1.30 ( 0.68) 1.15 ( 1.08) 0.88 ( 1.22) 0.68 ( 1.25) 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.44 (-0.68) 1.75 (-1.15) 1.54 (-1.11) 1.40 (-0.99) 1.39 (-0.83) 1.20 (-1.13) 1.26 (-1.37) 1.37 (-1.67) 1.55 (-1.95) 1.70 (-3.06) 1.71 (-4.49) 1.64 (-4.34) 1.20 (-0.48) 1.28 (-0.66) 1.21 (-0.48) 1.15 (-0.21) 1.19 (-0.18) 1.20 (-0.11) 1.26 (-0.22) 1.37 (-0.42) 1.55 (-1.00) 1.70 (-1.64) 1.71 (-2.13) 1.64 (-2.27) Panel B. Real exchange rate: restricted model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 ˆ 2 VEC ˆ 0.749 1.988 2.794 3.397 3.681 4.287 4.590 4.789 5.125 5.794 6.856 8.201 2 -adj. VEC ˆ 0.609 1.572 2.324 2.865 2.991 3.423 3.577 3.614 3.786 4.280 5.155 6.322 0.519 1.135 1.811 2.421 2.642 2.921 2.878 2.671 2.545 2.460 2.705 3.109 2 RW ˆ 2 VEC -adj. 0.679 1.814 2.541 3.061 3.199 3.660 3.811 3.848 4.018 4.529 5.450 6.676 ˆ 2 VAR 0.623 1.556 2.310 2.945 3.085 3.573 3.629 3.503 3.298 3.407 4.019 4.995 Panel C. Real exchange rate: restricted model with real interest rate differential Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 ˆ 2 VEC 0.656 1.663 2.476 3.164 3.549 4.141 4.206 3.967 3.846 3.958 4.391 5.446 ˆ 2 -adj. VEC ˆ 0.558 1.437 2.258 2.919 3.219 3.717 3.713 3.383 3.175 3.232 3.587 4.560 0.519 1.135 1.811 2.421 2.642 2.921 2.878 2.671 2.545 2.460 2.705 3.109 2 RW ˆ 2 VEC -adj. 0.619 1.590 2.391 3.074 3.423 3.989 4.023 3.747 3.574 3.631 3.996 4.983 ˆ 2 VAR 0.561 1.411 2.149 2.857 3.117 3.638 3.608 3.225 2.870 2.632 2.816 3.576 47 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.26 (-0.41) 1.47 (-1.28) 1.37 (-1.42) 1.31 (-1.58) 1.34 (-1.86) 1.42 (-2.40) 1.46 (-3.23) 1.49 (-2.68) 1.51 (-1.71) 1.61 (-2.09) 1.62 (-1.70) 1.75 (-2.12) 1.17 (-0.65) 1.18 (-0.70) 1.15 (-0.75) 1.11 (-0.57) 1.14 (-0.71) 1.14 (-0.70) 1.17 (-0.78) 1.23 (-1.01) 1.34 (-1.42) 1.50 (-2.11) 1.56 (-2.30) 1.52 (-2.44) Panel D. Nominal exchange rate: restricted model with real interest rate differential Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 ˆ VEC 0.630 1.476 1.968 2.553 2.977 3.523 3.540 3.116 2.742 2.384 2.232 2.456 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 0.536 1.308 1.805 2.354 2.707 3.180 3.127 2.622 2.185 1.794 1.552 1.675 2 ˆ RW 0.490 1.107 1.745 2.342 2.594 2.845 2.762 2.548 2.319 2.140 2.118 2.264 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 2 ˆ VAR 0.606 1.439 1.943 2.528 2.949 3.500 3.523 3.103 2.731 2.373 2.220 2.441 0.576 1.391 2.056 2.742 3.199 3.733 3.710 3.230 2.764 2.343 2.173 2.366 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.29 (-0.65) 1.33 (-0.69) 1.13 ( 0.23) 1.09 ( 0.43) 1.15 ( 0.11) 1.24 (-0.25) 1.28 (-0.32) 1.22 ( 0.25) 1.18 ( 0.89) 1.11 ( 1.59) 1.05 ( 1.87) 1.08 ( 2.48) 1.09 (-0.67) 1.06 (-0.43) 0.96 ( 1.37) 0.93 ( 2.46) 0.93 ( 1.90) 0.94 ( 1.81) 0.95 ( 1.81) 0.96 ( 1.52) 0.99 ( 0.44) 1.02 (-0.42) 1.03 (-0.67) 1.04 (-1.10) NOTE. Cases when the Clark-West test statistic is significant at the 10 percent level or better have been shaded. 48 Table 16. Forecast evaluation: SEK/USD benchmark model Panel A. Real exchange rate: unrestricted model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 ˆ VEC 1.547 3.923 7.289 12.227 19.323 27.951 35.670 42.826 50.717 57.611 64.375 70.646 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 1.255 3.111 5.799 10.023 16.407 24.322 31.417 37.823 45.117 51.235 57.146 63.346 2 ˆ RW 1.862 4.760 8.258 13.246 19.916 27.660 35.443 43.204 51.402 58.889 64.803 68.936 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 2 ˆ VAR 1.478 3.810 7.062 11.859 18.733 27.106 34.476 41.333 49.061 56.116 62.582 68.528 1.513 3.944 7.106 11.405 17.752 25.992 34.149 41.761 50.792 58.400 65.245 71.479 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 0.83 (2.09) 0.82 (1.60) 0.88 (1.18) 0.92 (0.95) 0.97 (0.70) 1.01 (0.50) 1.01 (0.49) 0.99 (0.55) 0.99 (0.53) 0.98 (0.55) 0.99 (0.53) 1.02 (0.39) 1.02 ( 0.39) 0.99 ( 0.43) 1.03 ( 0.07) 0.92 (-0.55) 0.97 (-0.83) 1.01 (-0.69) 1.04 (-0.15) 1.03 ( 0.16) 1.00 ( 0.52) 0.99 ( 0.52) 0.99 ( 0.52) 0.99 ( 0.54) 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 0.73 (2.76) 0.75 (1.94) 0.78 (1.49) 0.79 (1.46) 0.79 (1.46) 0.82 (1.34) 0.84 (1.27) 0.85 (1.29) 0.89 (1.04) 0.93 (0.88) 0.98 (0.72) 1.06 (0.36) 0.90 (2.62) 0.90 (2.18) 0.91 (1.95) 0.91 (1.76) 0.89 (1.95) 0.87 (2.07) 0.87 (2.00) 0.88 (1.71) 0.90 (1.41) 0.94 (1.01) 0.97 (0.74) 1.02 (0.40) Panel B. Real exchange rate: restricted model Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 ˆ VEC 1.364 3.561 6.458 10.423 15.809 22.695 29.778 36.731 45.955 54.754 63.226 72.983 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 1.126 2.911 5.299 8.735 13.546 19.826 26.212 32.364 40.675 48.409 55.643 64.240 2 ˆ RW 1.862 4.760 8.258 13.246 19.916 27.660 35.443 43.204 51.402 58.889 64.803 68.936 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 2 ˆ VAR 1.315 3.415 6.151 9.880 14.932 21.397 28.073 34.608 43.143 51.346 58.851 67.436 1.513 3.944 7.106 11.405 17.752 25.992 34.149 41.761 50.792 58.400 65.245 71.479 Panel C. Real exchange rate: restricted model with real interest rate differential Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 ˆ 2 VEC 1.145 2.090 2.855 4.036 4.989 5.824 7.120 9.234 11.863 15.970 19.594 25.966 ˆ 2 -adj. VEC 0.742 0.761 0.021 -0.963 -3.075 -6.119 -9.540 -12.979 -15.994 -18.652 -20.268 -20.477 ˆ 2 RW 1.862 4.760 8.258 13.246 19.916 27.660 35.443 43.204 51.402 58.889 64.803 68.936 ˆ 2 VEC -adj. 0.912 1.367 1.295 1.355 0.706 -0.472 -1.155 -0.986 -1.503 -0.124 -0.551 0.893 ˆ 2 VAR 1.292 2.592 4.017 6.583 10.592 16.125 22.155 29.509 39.080 48.222 57.438 70.118 49 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 0.61 (2.74) 0.44 (2.72) 0.35 (2.58) 0.30 (2.56) 0.25 (3.14) 0.21 (3.41) 0.20 (3.58) 0.21 (3.62) 0.23 (3.63) 0.27 (3.61) 0.30 (3.52) 0.38 (3.18) 0.89 (2.84) 0.81 (2.22) 0.71 (2.10) 0.61 (2.06) 0.47 (2.44) 0.36 (2.62) 0.32 (2.63) 0.31 (2.58) 0.30 (2.65) 0.33 (2.52) 0.34 (2.49) 0.37 (2.42) Panel D. Nominal exchange rate: restricted model with real interest rate differential Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 ˆ VEC 1.297 2.441 3.382 4.796 5.528 6.284 7.999 10.030 12.139 16.684 22.311 31.766 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 0.940 1.347 1.122 0.810 -0.883 -3.290 -5.634 -8.685 -11.666 -13.977 -15.042 -15.053 2 ˆ RW 1.696 4.395 7.764 12.666 18.994 26.294 33.997 41.719 49.463 57.038 63.054 67.513 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 2 ˆ VAR 1.110 1.927 2.366 3.111 2.951 2.563 3.325 4.424 4.628 7.596 10.269 15.525 1.172 2.224 3.290 5.246 8.018 12.139 17.353 24.374 32.915 42.863 54.619 70.822 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 0.76 (1.66) 0.56 (2.21) 0.44 (2.52) 0.38 (2.74) 0.29 (2.81) 0.24 (2.91) 0.24 (3.34) 0.24 (3.37) 0.25 (3.24) 0.29 (3.18) 0.35 (3.06) 0.47 (2.87) 1.11 (0.40) 1.10 (0.63) 1.03 (0.91) 0.91 (1.10) 0.69 (1.74) 0.52 (2.11) 0.46 (2.21) 0.41 (2.38) 0.37 (2.58) 0.39 (2.55) 0.41 (2.57) 0.45 (2.50) NOTE. Cases when the Clark-West test statistic is significant at the 10 percent level or better have been shaded Table 17. Forecast evaluation: approximate nominal SEK/TCW exchange rate Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 ˆ 2 VEC 0.739 3.791 6.272 8.769 11.061 12.863 13.420 11.687 9.347 6.970 5.526 5.635 ˆ 2 -adj. VEC ˆ 0.286 1.994 3.287 4.715 5.716 6.532 6.239 4.731 3.602 2.421 1.322 1.400 0.425 0.984 1.568 2.220 2.755 3.394 3.750 4.069 4.450 4.704 5.052 5.568 2 RW ˆ 2 VEC -adj. 0.590 3.526 6.013 8.449 10.577 12.236 12.671 10.814 8.206 5.596 3.745 3.300 ˆ 2 VAR 0.563 3.230 6.154 9.160 11.975 14.293 15.283 13.898 12.031 9.412 8.273 9.181 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.74 ( 0.89) 3.85 (-1.37) 4.00 (-1.50) 3.95 (-1.58) 4.01 (-1.49) 3.79 (-1.28) 3.58 (-0.98) 2.87 (-0.28) 2.10 ( 0.37) 1.48 ( 1.00) 1.09 ( 1.66) 1.01 ( 1.79) 1.31 (-0.30) 1.17 (-0.55) 1.02 ( 0.24) 0.96 ( 1.07) 0.92 ( 1.56) 0.90 ( 1.89) 0.88 ( 2.04) 0.84 ( 2.13) 0.78 ( 2.24) 0.74( 2.00) 0.67 ( 2.22) 0.61 ( 2.72) NOTE. Cases when the Clark-West test statistic is significant at the 10 percent level or better have been shaded Table 18. Forecast evaluation: implicit nominal USD/EUR exchange rate Horizon 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2 ˆ VEC 1.767 2.964 3.883 5.698 7.104 8.933 12.047 15.035 18.310 24.063 31.361 42.240 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 1.437 2.172 2.126 2.346 1.614 0.514 -0.174 -1.923 -3.641 -4.640 -3.703 -1.730 2 ˆ RW 1.756 4.320 7.206 11.621 17.240 23.826 31.460 39.105 46.532 54.432 60.373 64.292 2 -adj. ˆ VEC 2 ˆ VAR 1.620 2.523 2.914 4.029 4.598 5.315 7.518 9.607 11.030 15.262 19.650 26.351 1.697 3.055 4.155 6.355 9.514 14.363 20.845 28.972 38.704 51.028 64.728 82.164 2 2 / ˆ RW ˆ VEC 2 2 / ˆ VAR ˆ VEC (t-value) (t-value) 1.01 (0.75) 0.69 (1.62) 0.54 (1.74) 0.49 (1.83) 0.41 (2.27) 0.37 (2.47) 0.38 (2.61) 0.38 (2.74) 0.39 (2.73) 0.44 (2.64) 0.52 (2.43) 0.66 (2.13) 1.04 (0.46) 0.97 (1.06) 0.93 (1.34) 0.90 (1.35) 0.75 (1.86) 0.62 (2.10) 0.58 (2.12) 0.52 (2.26) 0.47 (2.45) 0.47 (2.46) 0.48 (2.46) 0.51 (2.35) NOTE. Cases when the Clark-West test statistic is significant at the 10 percent level or better have been shaded 50 Figure 1a. Graphs of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: the real effective exchange rate, relative output, and the terms of trade. LNTCWR D_LNTCWR 5.0 .12 4.9 .08 4.8 .04 4.7 .00 4.6 -.04 4.5 -.08 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 92 LNY 94 96 98 00 02 04 98 00 02 04 00 02 04 D_LNY .06 .012 .008 .04 .004 .02 .000 -.004 .00 -.008 -.02 -.012 -.04 -.016 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 92 LNTOT 94 96 D_LNTOT 4.72 .06 4.68 .04 4.64 .02 4.60 .00 4.56 -.02 4.52 4.48 -.04 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 51 88 90 92 94 96 98 Figure 1b. Graphs of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: net foreign assets, trade balance and differential between 3-month interest rates in Sweden and its trading partners. NFA D_NFA .3 .08 .2 .06 .1 .04 .0 .02 -.1 .00 -.2 -.02 -.3 -.04 -.4 -.06 -.5 -.08 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 92 EXIM 94 96 98 00 02 04 98 00 02 04 00 02 04 D_EXIM .09 .04 .08 .03 .07 .02 .06 .01 .05 .00 .04 -.01 .03 -.02 .02 -.03 .01 -.04 .00 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 92 94 96 I_SE_TCW 8 6 4 2 0 -2 86 52 88 90 92 94 96 98 Figure 1c. Graphs of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: the nominal effective exchange rate and the relative consumer price level. LNTCWN D_LNTCWN 5.0 .16 .12 4.9 .08 4.8 .04 4.7 .00 4.6 -.04 4.5 -.08 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 LNCPI_TCWSE 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 02 04 D_LNCPI_TCWSE .12 .02 .01 .08 .00 .04 -.01 .00 -.02 -.04 -.03 -.08 -.04 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 Figure 2. Recursive estimates of the eigenvalue with 95% confidence bands – benchmark model. 53 Figure 3. Cointegration relations for the real SEK/TCW benchmark model. Panel A. Unrestricted model .12 .08 .04 .00 -.04 -.08 -.12 -.16 -.20 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 Panel B. Restricted model. .15 .10 .05 .00 -.05 -.10 -.15 -.20 86 88 90 Panel C. Restricted model with interest rate differential. .12 .08 .04 .00 -.04 -.08 -.12 -.16 -.20 -.24 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 54 00 02 04 Figure 4. Recursive estimates of the eigenvalue with 95% confidence bands – alternative model. Figure 5. Cointegration relations for the real SEK/TCW alternative model. Panel A. Unrestricted model .15 .10 .05 .00 -.05 -.10 -.15 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 Panel B. Restricted model. .15 .10 .05 .00 -.05 -.10 -.15 -.20 86 88 90 55 Panel C. Restricted model with interest rate differential. .10 .05 .00 -.05 -.10 -.15 -.20 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 56 00 02 04 Figure 6a. Real SEK/TCW exchange rate and 1-8 quarter forecasts: BM model with restrictions (corresponding to Table 6, Panel B). 150 145 140 135 130 125 120 jun -9 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 -9 -0 -0 -0 -0 -0 -0 cccccccn n n n n n e e e e e e e u u u u u u j j j j j j jun d d d d d d d Figure 6b. Real SEK/TCW exchange rate and 1-8 quarter forecasts: BM model with restrictions and real interest rate differential (corresponding to Table 6, Panel C). 150 145 140 135 130 125 120 jun -9 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 -9 -0 -0 -0 -0 -0 -0 cccccccjun jun jun jun jun jun jun de de de de de de de 57 Figure7a. Graphs of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: the real SEK/EUR exchange rate, relative output, and relative terms of trade. LNRSEKEUR D_LNRSEKEUR 2.28 .12 2.24 .08 2.20 2.16 .04 2.12 2.08 .00 2.04 2.00 -.04 1.96 -.08 1.92 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 LNY_SEEU 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 00 02 04 00 02 04 D_LNY_SEEU .08 .020 .06 .015 .04 .010 .02 .005 .00 .000 -.02 -.005 -.04 -.010 -.06 -.08 -.015 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 LNTOT_SEEU 92 94 96 98 D_LNTOT_SEEU .10 .03 .02 .05 .01 .00 .00 -.05 -.01 -.10 -.02 -.15 -.03 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 58 88 90 92 94 96 98 Figure 7b. Graphs of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: relative net foreign assets, nominal SEK/EUR exchange rate and relative consumer price level. NFA_SEEU D_NFA_SEEU .3 .08 .2 .06 .04 .1 .02 .0 .00 -.1 -.02 -.2 -.04 -.3 -.06 -.4 -.08 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 LNNSEKEUR 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 00 02 04 00 02 04 D_LNNSEKEUR 2.3 .16 .12 2.2 .08 2.1 .04 2.0 .00 1.9 -.04 1.8 -.08 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 LNCPI_EUSE 92 94 96 98 D_LNCPI_EUSE .16 .02 .12 .01 .08 .00 .04 -.01 .00 -.02 -.04 -.03 -.08 -.04 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 59 88 90 92 94 96 98 Figure 8a. Graphs of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: the real SEK/USD exchange rate, relative output, and relative terms of trade. LNRSEKUSD D_LNRSEKUSD 2.4 .20 2.3 .15 2.2 2.1 .10 2.0 .05 1.9 1.8 .00 1.7 -.05 1.6 -.10 1.5 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 LNY_SEUS 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 00 02 04 00 02 04 D_LNY_SEUS .20 .010 .16 .005 .000 .12 -.005 .08 -.010 .04 -.015 .00 -.020 -.04 -.025 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 LNTOT_SEUS 92 94 96 98 D_LNTOT_SEUS .08 .04 .03 .04 .02 .00 .01 .00 -.04 -.01 -.08 -.02 -.03 -.12 -.04 -.16 -.05 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 60 88 90 92 94 96 98 Figure 8b. Graphs of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: relative net foreign assets, nominal SEK/EUR exchange rate and relative consumer price level. NFA_SEUS D_NFA_SEUS .5 .12 .4 .08 .3 .2 .04 .1 .0 .00 -.1 -.2 -.04 -.3 -.08 -.4 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 LNNSEKUSD 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 00 02 04 00 02 04 D_LNNSEKUSD 2.4 .20 2.3 .15 2.2 .10 2.1 2.0 .05 1.9 .00 1.8 -.05 1.7 1.6 -.10 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 88 90 LNCPI_USSE 92 94 96 98 D_LNCPI_USSE .08 .02 .01 .04 .00 .00 -.01 -.04 -.02 -.08 -.03 -.12 -.04 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 61 88 90 92 94 96 98 Figure 9. Graphs of endogenous variables in levels and first differences: Differentials between 3-month interest rates in Sweden and Euroland and between Sweden and the US. I_SE_EU I_SE_US 6 16 5 12 4 3 8 2 4 1 0 0 -1 -2 -4 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 86 62 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 Figure 10. Real SEK/EUR exchange rate and 1-8 quarter forecasts: BM model with restrictions and real interest rate differential (corresponding to Table 15, Panel C). 11 10 9 8 7 jun -9 8 c de 8 -9 jun -9 9 99 cde jun -0 0 1 2 3 4 5 00 01 02 03 04 -0 -0 -0 -0 -0 cccccn n n n e e e e e u u u u j j j j jun d d d d d Figure 11. Real SEK/USD exchange rate and 1-8 quarter forecasts: BM model with restrictions and real interest rate differential (corresponding to Table 16, Panel C). 11 10 9 8 7 jun -9 8 c de 8 -9 jun -9 9 99 cde jun -0 0 1 2 3 4 5 00 01 02 03 04 -0 -0 -0 -0 -0 cccccjun jun jun jun jun de de de de de 63