American Consortium on European Union Studies (ACES) Cases on Transatlantic Relations, No. 1 European Integration and Transatlantic Air Services Agreements: Who Has the Authority? by Michael J. Harrison This case was written for Prof. C. Randall Henning of the School of International Service at American University and Editor of ACES Cases on Transatlantic Relations Nos. 1-3. Michael J. Harrison is a graduate student at American University, one of the institutional members of the ACES consortium. They wish to acknowledge Christopher Ross, Martin Staniland, Matthew Finston and Jeffrey Saunders for extensive and helpful comments on drafts. Any errors or omissions that might remain are the author’s alone. Copies of the case can be downloaded free of charge, and information on other cases in this series can be found, at the ACES website: www.american.edu/aces/pages/publications.html. Copyright © 2003 American Consortium on European Union Studies Editor’s Note This case is one of a series on transatlantic relations developed by the American Consortium on European Union Studies (ACES), a center organized by five universities in the Washington D.C. area. Teaching essential concepts and principles concerning the politics and economics of transatlantic relations is the central purpose of the case series. Each case explores its particular topic as a specific instance of more general patterns of conflict and cooperation between the European Union and the United States. European integration, EU and U.S. policymaking, and their consequences for transatlantic conflict and negotiation are thus basic themes in the series. The multiplicity of layers of policy authority on each side of the Atlantic, and shifts in the location of that authority, also feature prominently in these cases. Each case thus conveys information on specific problems in order to provide a factual foundation for students to discuss broader principles as well as the particular policy dispute. These cases are written to assist instructors of upper-level undergraduate and graduate courses in government, business and economics in general and are configured for courses in International Relations, Foreign Economic Policy and European studies in particular. We welcome your feedback on the individual cases and the series as a whole. C. Randall Henning Copyright Policy Permission to use, copy, and distribute this case or excerpts from this case is granted provided that (1) this copyright and permission notice appears in all reproductions (excerpts of up to two paragraphs need only reference the case in full); (2) use is for noncommercial educational purposes only; (3) the manual or excerpts are not modified in any way; and (4) no figures or graphic images are used, copied, or distributed separate from accompanying text. Requests beyond that scope should be directed to the Executive Director of the American Consortium on European Union Studies (ACES). 1 Introduction Disagreements over airline services have been a persistent source of transatlantic conflict for several decades. Numerous bilateral agreements between EU member states, on the one hand, and the United States, on the other, effectively segment the internal European airline services market along national lines. Several powerful actors within Europe – including the European Commission and some member states and airlines – are pressing for completion of the single European market for airline services. In a landmark decision in 2002, the European Court of Justice (ECJ) ruled that central aspects of the bilateral agreements with the United States violated member states’ obligations under the European treaties. By requiring the renegotiation of these agreements, yet leaving the institutional responsibility for conducting these negotiations unspecified, the decision created great uncertainty in airline markets. Government authorities and private airlines on both sides of the Atlantic were forced to reassess their strategies and interests with respect to deregulation and European integration. At the same time, the ECJ decision opened the door to the possibility of a truly free market in airline services across the Atlantic. Overview From its inception through the creation of the monetary union, the European Union has had the central goal of deepening integration among its members. One of the cornerstones of this deeper integration, the 1986 Single European Act (SEA), sought to streamline rules and standards among members in order to create a single market for goods and services, labor and capital. While governments were generally successful in implementing the reforms mandated under the SEA by 1992, their drive to remove barriers and harmonize policies in the airline industry, among a few other sectors, was slower than their progress overall. The European Commission sought to gradually harmonize rules regarding air travel in three separate packages, the last of which was fully implemented in 1997. These packages liberalized the market for intra-European air travel; but the European market remained fragmented as a result of the rules regarding international air travel (i.e., travel outside Europe), particularly travel to the United States, on which many European airlines depend for a large portion of their revenue. Under the rules of the 1944 Chicago Convention, states agreed to negotiate detailed rules – such as which airlines are allowed to fly into which airports and how often – and codify these rules through bilateral air services agreements (ASAs). The United States thus has bilateral ASAs with nearly every European country, as do European governments with other countries around the world. As the European Union grew from six members to 15 members, these bilateral ASAs with the United States and other countries impeded the completion of the single European market for air travel. Because ASAs recognize airlines on the basis of “substantial ownership and effective control,” they are recognized as national – rather than European – entities. Thus, for example, while Air France is allowed to fly to the United States from France under its bilateral ASA, the German airline Lufthansa is not allowed to fly to the United States from France even though EU rules would allow such a flight. Many EU member states have historically pursued a “national champion” strategy with respect to airlines, occasionally investing in, retaining partial or full ownership, and providing 2 state aid to their flag carriers. Such EU members, particularly smaller states, rely on their bilateral ASAs with other countries to keep their national airlines flying and are thus reluctant to allow the European Commission to negotiate an ASA with the United States on behalf of all EU members. Such an agreement could mean smaller national airlines would be crowded out by dominant airlines like British Airways and Lufthansa. In negotiating separate bilateral ASAs with the United States, EU member states have, in effect, agreed to discriminate against airlines from fellow member states, protecting their flag carriers from competition and preventing the completion of the single European market for air travel. Further complicating the issue is the number of EU members that have signed “open skies” agreements with the United States that essentially liberalize all trade in airline services. As of 2003, 11 EU members – all but Britain, Greece, Ireland and Spain – have open skies agreements; the remaining four are much more restrictive agreements, the most egregious of which is the Bermuda II agreement between Britain and the United States. Under Bermuda II, for example, only four airlines – two American and two British – are allowed to fly between the United States and London’s Heathrow Airport, one of the world’s biggest centers of international air travel. While the European Commission would prefer to see a more liberalized aviation regime – what has come to be called an "open aviation area" – between the European Union and the United States, it must work to overcome the opposition of many member states. In November 2002, the European Court of Justice (ECJ), the highest court in the European Union, ruled that bilateral ASAs were illegal because they required EU member states to discriminate against other member states’ airlines on the basis of nationality. The decision precluded any further signing of bilateral ASAs by EU member states, with the United States or with any other country. The European Commission is pushing for member countries to allow it to negotiate on their behalf, in the interest of pooling negotiating leverage, particularly for talks with the United States. The existing arrangement of bilateral ASAs, the Commission argues, allowed the United States to “pick off” member states one at a time, concluding agreements that may have been beneficial to the individual member states but were detrimental to the European Union as a whole. The United States has not denied this “divide and rule” strategy of concluding open skies agreements with smaller EU member states as a means for exerting pressure on larger ones. The ECJ decision presents the challenge of the untangling of a dense web of over 200 bilateral ASAs with 22 separate governments in such a way that satisfies not only all EU member states, but also the United States, home of the most lucrative market for air travel in the world.1 This case lays out the dilemmas inherent in the system of bilateral ASAs in the European Union, particularly the European Commission’s desire to complete the single European market for air travel in the face of recalcitrant member states and a United States that is reluctant to overhaul the transatlantic air travel regime at a time when many of its own airlines are struggling financially. The first section of this case explains the existing market and regulatory structure of the airline industry. The second section discusses the contrasting approaches to airline deregulation in the United States and the European Union. The third section looks specifically at the effect of 1 Dinan (1999), p. 362. 3 bilateral ASAs on the EU single market, details the recent ECJ decision and the European Commission and U.S. viewpoints, and examines the steps that need to be taken to negotiate and implement a new transatlantic regime. The final section considers the viewpoint of several different airline alliances and national governments as a launching point for further discussion of negotiating dynamics associated with transatlantic air travel. Structure of the Market for Airline Services Sir Adam Thomson, the late chairman of defunct British Caledonian Airways, once remarked, “A recession is when you have to tighten your belt; depression is when you have no belt to tighten. When you’ve lost your trousers – you’re in the airline business.” Making money in the international air travel market is notoriously difficult. This is due to the complex set of regulations by which airlines must abide, high costs of entry, and intense competition from other airlines in more liberalized markets. Cost and Revenue Structure of the Airline Industry Airlines must take a number of variables into account in determining how to best serve their markets. They must decide what type of aircraft would be most efficient in terms of costs per passenger mile, how frequently to offer service, and whether demand is so high as to require nonstop service or to connect two city pairs through a hub. Given an expected amount of demand for travel between two points, airlines also face issues such as whether to offer a few flights on high-capacity aircraft each day or several flights on smaller aircraft each day, based on the aircraft available in the airline’s fleet. Airlines have to focus on the load factor, or the percentage of seats that are filled on an aircraft, and costs of operating a flight, including landing fees, fuel costs, labor (including flight crew and ground crew) costs of leasing the aircraft, and costs for maintaining the aircraft. Since these costs are spread among paying passengers and the distance traveled, costs are measured as a function of revenue passenger miles (RPM). Airlines must decide what fares to charge passengers, given higher per-mile costs on shorter flights and lower per-mile costs on longer flights, and given the number of competitor airlines offering service and their fares. Airlines achieve economies of scale by flying fuller aircraft (higher load factors) over longer distances. 2 Traffic, Revenue and Profit for selected U.S. and European airlines, 2001 Revenue Passenger 2 Fischer (1997), p. 70. Revenue Net Profit or Loss 4 Airline Miles (million) United (US) 187,686 American (US) 170,883 Delta (US) 163,683 Northwest (US) 117,658 British Airways (UK) 106,270 Continental (US) 98,374 Air France (France) 94,415 Lufthansa (Germany) 93,605 Southwest (US) 71,591 KLM (Netherlands) 57,848 Iberia (Spain) 41,297 Alitalia (Italy) 36,524 Swissair (Switzerland)* 32,981 Virgin Atlantic (UK) 30,198 SAS (Norway, Sweden, Denmark) 23,295 Sabena (Belgium) 15,320 Finnair (Finland) 12,800 TAP Air Portugal (Portugal) 10,457 Aer Lingus (Ireland) 9,554 Olympic (Greece) 8,428 Austrian (Austria) 8,140 Ryanair (Ireland) 9,844 Easyjet (UK) 5,126 Luxair (Luxembourg) 1,061 Source: Air Transport World, “2001 World Airline Report” *Filed for bankruptcy; now known as Swiss International Air Lines -- Data not available (million $) 16,138 18,963 13,879 9,905 12,176 8,969 11,024 14,687 5,555 5,744 4,160 4,698 --4,989 -1,477 1,091 --1,911 543 525 264 (million $) -3,771.0 -2,470.0 -1,117.0 -888.0 -161.0 144.0 206.8 -277.7 631.1 -82.0 4.3 6.2 ---108.8 -11.7 18.1 ---78.2 141.7 58.0 10.3 Considering all these variables, it is easy to see how, when airlines depend on a load factor of 60 percent to 70 percent just to break even,3 even a slight downturn in passenger traffic can have a devastating effect on an airline’s profits. In the competitive market environment fostered by increasing deregulation and open skies bilateral ASAs, airlines have increasingly turned to hub-and-spoke networks and code-sharing alliances to streamline operations, guarantee sufficient passenger flow and maximize profits. Hub-and-Spoke Networks More than any other operational aspect, the system of flying passengers to hub airports in order to efficiently move them to their destinations has become the definition of how the airline system works. By routing flights between city pairs through a hub, an airline can leverage – through permutation – the number of city pairs it can serve without being exposed to the risk of operating less-profitable routes between two small cities.4 Prior to the increased use of hubs, airlines tended to use smaller-capacity aircraft to serve more cities in point-to-point fashion, a less efficient means of operation. Consider an example in which an airline serves three airports in one area and three airports in another area. Providing direct service between all six airports would require 18 flights in all (nine each way). However, by routing the airports in each area through a hub airport, the 3 4 Fischer (1997), p. 69. Hanlon (1996), p. 71. 5 same six airports can be served with only 12 total flights.5 The increased efficiency of hub-andspoke networks is multiplied when taking into consideration the massive multi-hub networks of major international carriers such as American or United. Hubs also make it possible for smaller airlines such as U.S. Airways to conduct international operations out of nontraditional ports of entry – in U.S. Airways’ case, Pittsburgh, Charlotte, N.C., and Philadelphia – by feeding passengers to the hub via spoke routes from, say, Chicago, Detroit, and Washington. Thus, U.S. Airways is able to advertise service from Washington to Frankfurt even though it actually operates the international segment of that flight from Pittsburgh to Frankfurt. Aside from the efficiency aspect of hub-and-spoke operations, the large costs inherent in setting up hub airports create high barriers to entry for new airlines and lead to a snowball effect by which hubs are exploited to their maximum at the expense of less lucrative routes between smaller, non-hub airports.6 Airlines must pay for landing slots, defined by the International Air Transport Association as “… the scheduled time of arrival or departure available, allocated to an aircraft movement on a specific date at an airport.”7 These landing slots are among the most precious assets of an airline, as they preserve market share by preventing other airlines from usurping routes; the airports will not allow airlines to land or take off without a slot, except in an emergency. As more airlines begin to adopt a hub-and-spoke strategy, many of the largest airports are facing capacity pressures, forcing slots to be rationed in some cases. 8 In these cases, protecting existing slots from competitor airlines becomes increasingly important as operations are further concentrated at hub airports. Code-Sharing Alliances Hand in hand with the emergence of hub airports as the dominant strategy for airline operations is the emergence of code-sharing alliances, particularly between U.S. and European airlines. Code-sharing alliances allow one airline to offer tickets that connect to flights operated by its code-sharing partners, giving European airlines access to their partners’ U.S. route networks and vice-versa. The move toward code-sharing alliances has been seen as a next-best alternative to industry consolidation, as mergers that would increase foreign ownership of a merged airline to more than 25 percent remain illegal under U.S. laws.9 Approval of codesharing alliances can be sped up by U.S. authorities granting antitrust immunity, which is often given as a quid pro quo for countries concluding open skies bilateral ASAs with the United States. This was the case when the United States granted antitrust immunity to the alliance between Northwest Airlines (NWA) and Dutch airline KLM after the Netherlands concluded an open skies bilateral ASA with the United States in 1992.10 Nearly every major U.S. and EU airline is part of a code-sharing alliance. In addition to the NWA-KLM alliance, major U.S.-EU code-sharing alliances include Skyteam (Delta Airlines, Alitalia and Air France), Star Alliance (Austrian Airlines, Lufthansa, Scandinavian Airline 5 Fischer (1997), p. 43-44. Staniland (1996), p. 5. 7 Kyrou (2000), p. 72. 8 Hanlon (1996), p. 133. 9 Staniland (2003), p. 9. 10 Staniland (2003), p. 15. 6 6 System and United Airlines), Qualiflyer (Swiss, Sabena of Belgium and TAP of Portugal), and Oneworld (American Airlines, Aer Lingus of Ireland, British Airways, Finnair and Iberia of Spain). Most of these alliances include other international partners, further expanding the global networks of these five major alliances. Through code-sharing alliances, European airlines gain access to their U.S. partner’s hubs in the United States, while U.S. airlines gain access to European hubs. A U.S. airline is then able to “feed” its hubs with its domestic network, fly passengers to Europe, and allow its partner to fly those passengers to other European destinations beyond the European hub via spoke routes, minimizing the need to offer point-to-point transatlantic service. The NWA-KLM alliance demonstrates how airlines can exploit the extensive domestic networks of alliance partners. NWA has hubs at the nontraditional ports of entry of Detroit, Minneapolis and Memphis, and KLM has its hub at Schiphol Airport in Amsterdam. With 201 airports in the United States and Canada feeding NWA’s hubs and 107 airports in Europe feeding Amsterdam, NWA/KLM needs only three transatlantic routes – Detroit-Amsterdam, Minneapolis-Amsterdam and MemphisAmsterdam – to boast connecting service between 21,708 cities in the United States and Europe.11 Coordinated marketing campaigns on both sides of the Atlantic and more efficient use of resources creates synergistic effects, making code-sharing alliances highly profitable for airlines.12 Code-sharing alliances also generate positive effects for consumers. A 2003 study found that international fares on airlines that were part of alliances were 8 percent to 17 percent lower than on non-code-sharing flights.13 Additionally, struggling airlines from European countries with small domestic markets have increasingly seen code-sharing alliances as a strategy for preventing the loss of market share to larger competitors. This strategy has been adopted by Finnair, SAS and Aer Lingus, all of which have forged alliances with major European and U.S. code-sharing partners.14 Differences between U.S. and EU airlines Two stark differences fundamentally define the strategies of European airlines vis-à-vis U.S. airlines: First, European airlines are more dependent on long-haul international routes as a portion of their total revenue, and second, the European market is segmented both geographically and politically. The dependence of European airlines on international routes can be traced to the historical evolution of airlines. In the United States, substantial domestic networks tend to precede expansion into the international realm.15 In the EU, however, emphasis is first placed on intercontinental routes, and airlines gradually branch into intra-European and domestic service. In 1990, for example, 8.9 percent of the passengers on U.S. carriers were traveling internationally, compared with 55 percent of passengers on European carriers, due in large part 11 Staniland (1996), p. 18. Staniland (2003), p. 9. 13 Brueckner (2003), p. 105-118. 14 Staniland (2003), p. 22-23. 15 For many years, Pan Am dominated international travel to and from the United States. The demise of Pan Am was brought on, by many accounts, by Pan Am’s lack of a system of hubs to feed its international flights from the United States. See Staniland (1996), p. 8. 12 7 to the fact that Europe is comprised of many small countries relative to the United States.16 In 1993, four major European airlines (British Airways, Lufthansa, Air France and KLM) relied on long-haul international routes for more than 80 percent of their total passenger traffic.17 Share of seats flown in November 2002 from the United States to selected countries Airline Total Seats U.S. Airlines American United Continental Delta US Airways Northwest European Airlines British Airways Virgin Atlantic Lufthansa Air France KLM U.S. Share Source: ECLAT Consulting --Data not available Britain 908,563 Germany 354,743 France 279,818 Netherlands 229,089 14.3% 10.9% 5.1% 4.2% 3.3% -- 3.6% 16.2% -11.5% 8.0% -- 11.1% 8.7% 6.7% 16.5% --- -6.8% 5.6% 5.9% -36.3% 38.1% 15.7% ---37.8% --51.4% --43.5% ---50.3% -48.9% ----32.5% 57.3% Higher levels of regulation on international routes provide greater opportunities for rentseeking behavior on the part of European carriers;18 European and domestic routes are less profitable because there is greater competition, but also because Europe is geographically smaller. While the average domestic flight in the United States covers 1300 km, the average European flight covers only 750 km.19 Aside from facing shorter, less profitable flights on European routes, national carriers have been slow to embrace the single market program, leading to a geographic segmentation of the markets. Even a large national market such as Germany or the United Kingdom pales by comparison to the sheer demand for air travel in the United States. Furthermore, over shorter distances, European airlines must compete with rail and road transport; Europe’s superb rail system provides a potent competitor within the EU travel market, while Amtrak’s spotty service record and dismal national network provides Americans with greater incentive to fly over short distances.20 As European carriers depend on international routes in order to remain financially solvent, the rules governing international air travel become increasingly important to national airlines. While U.S. airlines can depend on their domestic networks as a consistent source of revenue, a negotiating misstep by an EU member state’s government can cost its national airline dearly in the market for international air travel. With this in mind, the following section examines how the rules governing air travel have affected the strategies of airlines in the United States and the European Union. 16 Sinha (2001), p. 69. Staniland (2003), p. 8. 18 Sinha (2001), p. 69. 19 Sinha (2001), p. 69. 20 See Staniland (1996), p. 8. 17 8 The Chicago Convention The Chicago Convention represented a major push to codify international norms in the nascent but booming air transport industry. As air travel became increasingly popular, and as commercial aircraft increased in size and range, these fundamental changes in the industry dictated a parallel change in international rules. This need was particularly acute in the United States, which was prepared to shift from a more protectionist stance to accepting a more liberalized, expansionist regime.21 Thus, an invitation went out in 1944 to members of the United Nations to a conference that would “agree so far as possible upon principles of a permanent international structure for civil aviation and air transport.”22 One of the more interesting aspects of the Chicago Convention is that the United States was rebuffed – mainly by British opposition – in its pursuit of a wide-ranging multilateral agreement to liberalize trade in airline services and subject fares, routes and capacity to determination by market forces. The resulting agreement meant that trade in airline services would be governed through a framework of bilateral ASAs.23 The new rules had the effect of discouraging competition, and particularly led to the development of the single “national champion” airline for European countries. The convention provided incentives for high degrees of collusion among airlines, as agreements allowed fares to be regulated and split capacity on given routes, rather than leaving operations and fares subject to market determination.24 In addition to undermining competition and efficiency in the airline industry, the Chicago regime contributed to the concentration of airlines at hub airports, where grandfather rights prevented airport authorities from selling slots at market value. Particularly following U.S. deregulation, this gave airlines incentives to build their operations around key airports where their slots were guaranteed.25 Although the Americans failed in implementing a multilateral ASA, there were two important outcomes of the Chicago Convention. First, it established the International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO), an arm of the United Nations that provides a forum for discussing technical and safety aspects of air travel.26 Second, it established the concept of freedoms, or privileges, of international air travel: The Eight Freedoms 1. “Innocent passage” refers to the right to fly over another state, through that state’s airspace, without landing. 2. The right to make a technical stop in another state, for the purposes of making repairs or refueling. 3. The right to take passengers and cargo from an airline’s home state to a destination in another state, as in a flight by American Airlines from New York to London. 21 de Murias (1989), p. 43. de Murias (1989), p. 45. The invitation also went to nations associated with the United Nations in World War II, as well as certain European and Asiatic neutral nations. 23 Morrison and Winston (1995), p. 147. 24 Sinha (2001), p. 68. 25 Sinha (2001), p. 68. 26 Dobson (1995), p. 20. 22 9 4. The right to pick up passengers and cargo in another state and bring them to a destination in an airline’s home state, as in a flight by American Airlines from London to New York. 5. Also known as “beyond rights,” the right to pick up passengers and cargo in another state and take them to a destination in a third state, other than the airline’s home state, as in an American Airlines flight from New York to London that picks up additional passengers in London before traveling on from London to Frankfurt. 6. Also known as “behind feed,” the right to pick up passengers and cargo in another state, bring them to the airline’s home state, then transfer them to flights to a third state, as in an American Airlines flight from London to Mexico City by way of New York.27 7. The right to carry passengers and cargo between two states, neither of which is the airline’s home state, as in a direct flight by American Airlines from London to Mexico City. 8. Also known as “cabotage,” refers to the right to carry passengers and cargo between two points within a single state, especially in a state other than the airline’s home state, as in a British Airways flight from New York to Los Angeles. This is distinguished from “consecutive cabotage,” in which the domestic leg of the trip is an extension of an international trip, as in a British Airways flight from London to New York to Los Angeles.28 The signatories of the Chicago Convention readily accepted the first two freedoms, innocent passage over a foreign country and the right to make a technical stop in a foreign country, but third, fourth and fifth freedoms were left subject to bilateral ASAs.29 Sixth and eighth freedoms were protected by national governments for their domestic carriers to prevent foreign competition, while most states denied foreign airlines from making seventh freedom flights. Even in 2003, very few bilateral ASAs with the United States allow sixth or seventh freedom flights, and none allow cabotage. Restrictive Bilateral ASAs – Bermuda II and Agreements With Greece, Ireland and Spain The ECJ’s November 2002 ruling dates back to a case filed by the European Commission in 1998, four years after Britain entered negotiations to liberalize aviation markets with the United States. Although the talks broke down, the Commission was nonetheless enraged that a member state would conduct negotiations that the Commission assumed were within its realm of competency. At issue was the Bermuda II treaty, signed by Britain and the United States in 1977, which is widely regarded as one of the most restrictive bilateral ASAs in the world. Bermuda II stands in stark contrast to open skies agreements between the United States and other EU member states. While “open skies” agreements generally allow unfettered access by a 27 Some experts challenge the idea of sixth freedom flights, arguing it is actually a coordination of two flights under third and fourth freedoms. 28 Adapted from Dobson (1995), p. x. The concept of “freedoms” predated the Chicago Convention, but at Chicago signatories agreed to the “five freedoms of the air,” the third fourth and fifth of which would be subject to bilateral ASAs. 29 Dobson (1995), p. 20. 10 national carrier of that member state to transatlantic routes to the United States, Bermuda II strictly regulates access to Heathrow Airport in London, allowing only two British airlines – in 2003, British Airways and Virgin Atlantic – and two U.S. airlines – American and United – to operate routes between the United States and London’s Heathrow Airport.30 Heathrow Airport is the last great frontier for U.S. carriers, the glittering jewel in the crown of European aviation. As Thomas Petzinger puts it: “Much more than an airport, Heathrow is a crossroads that links the Middle East with North America, Africa with South America, Europe with Asia and every other continent. Heathrow is to the planet Earth what Chicago, Dallas, or Denver is to the United States. ... [T]he whole world changes planes at Heathrow.”31 Bermuda II came about after the British denounced the 1946 Bermuda I treaty, which was considered by the UN’s International Civil Aviation Organization to be a model for bilateral ASAs for the years to come. Bermuda II, conversely, can be seen as an example of what not to do in negotiating bilateral ASAs.32 Faced with an eleventh-hour decision between suspending U.S. airline service to Britain and agreeing to the rigid provisions of Bermuda II, the Carter administration acquiesced. Quite simply, the United States had in fact gotten a raw deal: the number of routes from the United States to Heathrow was cut from eight to two, capacity was too rigidly controlled, and U.S. carriers were granted only minimal fifth freedom, or beyond rights, to fly to other European destinations from Heathrow. These restrictions came from the U.S. unwillingness to grant cabotage rights to British carriers to fly to other cities in the United States after landing at a gateway airport. Fifth freedom rights are of little use to British carriers – and indeed all EU carriers – due to the dearth of commercially viable destinations in other North and South American countries.33 An outstanding bargaining instrument for the British, Bermuda II gave the British effective control over the speed of air services liberalization on the eve of domestic U.S. deregulation – and the United States has been trying to renegotiate ever since.34 This epic fight, essentially over access to Heathrow Airport, spilled over into the 1990s as the United States and Britain attempted – and failed – multiple times to devise a more liberalized bilateral ASA. By preventing the United Kingdom from renegotiating Bermuda II, the European Commission essentially retained the Heathrow trump card in any future negotiations with the United States. The U.S. agreements with Greece, Ireland and Spain are less restrictive than the Bermuda II agreement, and deal with a much smaller amount of air traffic. The U.S. agreement with Greece, for example, places limits on fifth freedom flights, the number of airports served, the number of carriers on certain routes, and sets price restrictions. The agreement with Ireland 30 Done (2002). Virgin Atlantic was designated following the demise of British Caledonian in 1987, while American and United bought the rights formerly held by Pan Am and TWA in 1991. 31 Petzinger (1995), p. 377. 32 Dobson (1995), p. 140. 33 British Airways would be loath to offer, for example, service from Heathrow to Mexico City or Buenos Aires via New York; much more lucrative would be an allowance to fly beyond New York to another destination within the United States, say, Dallas or Los Angeles – what is referred to as consecutive cabotage. See Dobson (1995), p. 128. 34 Dobson (1995), p. 140. 11 requires a separate non-stop U.S. flight to or from Shannon for every U.S. flight to or from Dublin, in effect forcing U.S. carriers to serve Shannon Airport with the same frequency as Dublin Airport.35 These three agreements stand as additional examples of restrictive bilateral ASAs, particularly when compared to open skies bilateral ASAs that have been signed by the other 11 EU member states with the United States. Open Skies Bilateral ASAs Following airline deregulation in the United States in 1978, the United States embarked on a series of “open market” ASAs with countries in Europe, Asia and Latin America. While these agreements substantially liberalized transatlantic air travel, particularly with the Netherlands, Belgium, Germany and Luxembourg, structural changes in the airline industry were creating incentives for further liberalization. Between 1987 and 1993, passenger traffic between the United States and foreign destinations increased 47 percent, while domestic U.S. traffic increased only 6 percent.36 Industry consolidation in the United States had created a number of carriers with large domestic networks, and these carriers began to look toward international markets for expansion. By the early 1990s, a series of “open skies” bilateral ASAs between the United States and EU member states marked the end of what few restrictions remained on transatlantic air travel.37 Open skies agreements – signed with 11 EU member states, as well as Iceland, Norway and Switzerland – effectively deregulated travel between the United States and those countries. The agreements allowed for unlimited frequency of flights from any U.S. city to any point in the other country, with no restrictions on fares. Additionally, the agreements allowed for unlimited fifth freedom rights, or beyond rights, allowing airlines to pick up passengers in the other country and fly to a third country.38 Finally, these agreements allowed for unlimited codesharing alliances and other commercial arrangements.39 Open skies ASAs still include a number of restrictions on unbridled open-market competition. First, open skies agreements allow a state to reject flights by an airline that is not “substantially owned and effectively controlled” by the state with which the agreement has been signed. This “nationality clause” is the main issue at hand in preventing the coexistence of open skies ASAs with the EU single market for air transport, but it serves a purpose similar to rules of origin in other trade arrangements: it prevents a third country from receiving preferential treatment to which it would not otherwise be entitled.40 Second, open skies agreements prohibit seventh freedom flights between two countries, neither of which is the airline’s home country; this is also an issue in the drive to complete the EU single market, as such rights would allow the German airline Lufthansa to fly from Paris to New York, for example, as EU single market rules would allow. Third, open skies agreements prohibit any type of cabotage, or flights between two points within a foreign country. Finally, open skies agreements allow for “Fly America” requirements, which dictate that U.S. government officials must fly on U.S. airlines; however, 35 Brattle Group (2002), p. 1-8. Brattle Group (2002), p. 1-4. 37 Brattle Group (2002), p. 1-5. 38 The third country must also agree to allow fifth freedom flights, in addition to the two parties allowing fifth freedoms in the bilateral ASA. 39 Brattle Group (2002), p. 1-5. 40 Brattle Group (2002), p. 1-6. 36 12 officials may still fly internationally on a foreign airline with which a U.S. carrier has a codesharing alliance.41 The results of open skies bilateral ASAs have been increased competition among U.S. and foreign airlines, lower fares, increased transatlantic passenger traffic, further concentration of airlines at hub airports, and increasing proliferation of multinational alliances such as codesharing alliances.42 Open skies agreements have eliminated most restrictions on international air travel, but have maintained a number of rules that prevent the United States and the European Union from negotiating an agreement that would complete the single European Market and move toward an open aviation area with the United States. Deregulating Airline Services Once one of the most-regulated industries in the world, the airline industry has enjoyed increasing levels of liberalization over the past 35 years, beginning in the United States. While U.S. deregulation took a more “big bang” approach, eliminating all rules at once, EU deregulation took place gradually in three phases, each meant to bring the industry one step closer to the single market envisioned by the Single European Act. The United States and the European Union also approach competition policy differently, with the EU necessarily taking a harder stance on state aid to airlines, as national governments continue to hold substantial stakes in their airlines and therefore take an interest in ensuring the viability of their national champions. The United States has focused more on preventing foreign ownership of airlines, largely to protect the domestic market from foreign competition. Deregulation in the United States In 1978, the United States passed the Airline Deregulation Act, which greatly enhanced competition among airlines within the world’s largest air travel market. The three immediate effects of deregulation in the United States were a sharp increase in the number of carriers, a decrease in most fare prices and a decrease in the market share of major airlines. Seven years after deregulation, the number of U.S. airlines had risen from 36 to over 120.43 Fare prices dropped for 78 percent of U.S. passengers, particularly for those traveling 800 miles or more, as regulations that subsidized short-haul fares at the expense of long-haul fares were discontinued.44 However, fare prices for trips less than 800 miles tended to increase – sharply for the shortest flights – leading to some consumer dissatisfaction with deregulation.45 Finally, the market share of the five largest U.S. carriers fell from 69 percent in 1978 to 57 percent in 1985. However, industry consolidation brought the market share of the top five carriers back up to 70 percent by 1995, as airlines discovered methods for exploiting the deregulated U.S. system, one of which was the concentration of operations at hub airports.46 Yet the deregulated U.S. airline regime has also allowed a number of niche players, the best known of which is Southwest Airlines, to thrive by serving regional markets and smaller airports at lower costs. 41 Brattle Group (2002), p. 1-7 and 1-8. Brattle Group (2002), p. 1-5. 43 Hanlon (1996), p. 37. 44 Morrison and Winston (1995), p. 19. 45 Morrison and Winston (1995), p. 19. 46 Hanlon (1996), p. 38. 42 13 EU Deregulation and the European Single Market Although the principle of the common European market was established as early as 1957 with the Treaty of Rome, substantial progress was lacking until the 1986 Single European Act, with which the EU sought to “eliminate in their entirety ... internal frontier barriers and controls” by the end of 1992.47 The underpinnings of exactly how internal barriers to trade would be eliminated were laid down by the European Commission’s White Paper in 1985, a compilation of over 280 directives to be adopted by EU member states. With regard to trade in airline services, the Commission chose to tackle a highly regulated market in three stages; packages adopted by the Council of Ministers in 1987, 1990 and 1992 gradually liberalized the EU internal air travel market.48 Prior to the single market program, the EU air travel market was characterized by a “national champion” ideology among member states, by which the national airline, if not completely state-owned, was protected from competition through arrangements that regulated market shares for each airline, fixed fares, limited capacity, and provided for state subsidies, all of which contributed to widespread inefficiencies among EU carriers and high consumer costs.49 The Council packages increased competition on fares, increased access to routes for all EU carriers, applied EU competition rules to airlines, and granted the right of cabotage within other member states for any EU carrier.50 The third (1992) package was the most important, providing the Commission the right to intervene to prevent predatory fare pricing, or to set maximum or minimum fares; cabotage rights on domestic routes within EU member states were the last part of the package to be implemented, effective April 1, 1997.51 Another key provision of the third package was the transformation of all EU-owned airlines, regardless of their home member state, into “Community air carriers” with equal rights and responsibilities under EU laws.52 As in the United States, deregulation in the European Union has resulted in lower fares for consumers, and an increase in the number of – specifically low-cost – carriers. The European Commission found several benefits of the deregulation packages in a 1999 analysis, including improved productivity among EU airlines, an overall doubling of the number of airlines operating flights in the European Union, overall increases in employment in the sector, increased competition resulting in a 10 percent to 25 percent decrease in average fares, and an increase in the overall number of routes flown.53 Contrasted with the more “big bang” approach to deregulation in the United States, the gradual approach to airline deregulation in the EU has, by many accounts, given an advantage to airlines at the expense of consumers, as airlines were able to gradually adjust to different aspects of liberalization.54 One interesting aspect of airline deregulation in the EU has been the increase in competition among airports. As low-cost carriers begin to utilize under-used airports, these airports realize higher levels of passenger traffic, increasing the market value of slots.55 47 Dinan (1999), p. 354. Dinan (1999), p. 362. 49 Dinan (1999), p. 362. 50 Dinan (1999), p. 362. 51 Sinha (2001), p. 73-74. 52 Commission of the European Communities. (2002b), point 6. 53 Commission of the European Communities (2002b), point 8. 54 Sinha (2001), p. 77-78. 55 Sinha (2001), p. 76. 48 14 While the rest of the EU single market was completed in 1992, the single market for air travel has taken much longer – while EU-wide cabotage went into effect in 1997, the single market for international travel is still incomplete as a result of the bilateral ASA regime. A partial explanation for the longer timeframe allotted to the airline industry lies in the substantial state ownership of EU airlines. The two largest EU airlines, British Airways and Lufthansa, were completely privately held by 2003. However, Lufthansa had been 37 percent owned by the German government until 1997. Aer Lingus of Ireland, Olympic Airways of Greece, and TAP of Portugal are 100 percent government-owned. The French government held a 94.2 percent stake in Air France in 1996, but reduced that stake to 53 percent in 1999 and to about 20 percent in 2002.56 Finnair (60.7 percent), KLM (38.2 percent), Sabena of Belgium (33.8 percent), and Austrian Airlines (51.9 percent) complete the picture of an industry in which national governments had major incentives to intervene and protect as long as possible before EU-wide competition policies came into effect.57 Competition Policy EU competition policy aims to prevent market-distorting practices by dominant players; applying competition policy to the airline industry was a key component of the EU deregulation packages. While maintaining many of the features of U.S. antitrust policy, EU competition policy also serves an important goal in moving toward a single market for air travel: by breaking down barriers to increased competition among member states, the European Union takes on the appearance less of 15 national markets and more of a single, integrated European market.58 Indeed, until the 1986 ECJ Nouvelles Frontières decision that applied competition rules to air transport, national governments had actually been sanctioning the types of collusive practices that would be outlawed in the single market.59 EU competition policy is defined by (re-numbered) Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty of Rome. Article 81 “prohibits agreements and concerted practices ... that prevent, restrict, or distort competition and that affect trade between member states,” while Article 82 prohibits the abuse of a dominant (monopoly) market position.60 Articles 87 and 88 deal specifically with state subsidies and state-owned enterprises. Authority over competition policy is the realm of European Commission Directorate General for Competition, who can issue decisions without needing approval from the Council or being subjected to a qualified majority vote. EU competition policy has been fractured as a result of the bilateral ASA regime, which the European Commission argues creates legal uncertainty among EU airlines. Essentially, the Commission does not wield the same authority with respect to international air transport as it does with matters related to internal EU air transport, undermining the effectiveness of competition policy.61 56 BBC News (2002). Government ownership figures from Staniland (2003), p. 3. 58 Dinan (1999), p. 380. 59 Sochor (1991), p. 184. See also Kyrou (2000), p. 68-70. 60 Dinan (1999), p. 381. 61 Commission of the European Communities (2002b), point 26. Particularly with regard to code-sharing alliances, the Commission has had to rely on the tenuous legal basis of Article 85; however, the Commission in February 2003 57 15 The European Commission also holds authority over the approval of mergers and acquisitions. While U.S. regulations prevent cross-border mergers between U.S. and EU airlines for the time being, any such merger would be subject to strict scrutiny by U.S. antitrust authorities and DG Competition in Brussels to ensure that competition would be preserved. This is especially important in the context of negotiating an EU-U.S. open aviation area, under which the elimination of rules on foreign ownership in the United States could result in a flood of applications for mergers between U.S. and EU carriers. The “national champion” nature of EU carriers often leads to conflicts between member states and the Commission over airline subsidies. Such was the case in 1994, when the French government notified the commission that it intended to inject $3.42 billion into state-owned Air France. Air France, in the wake of EU airline deregulation and as the conspicuous European carrier without a U.S. alliance partner at the time, was losing money – $680 million in 1993 alone.62 Although the Commission approved the capital injection by the French government, it set conditions on the injection to ensure that market distortions would not result, including “rationalization” of Air France’s workforce and the stipulation that the government would be prohibited from allocating additional state aid to its ailing airline.63 The Air France case was controversial; six other member states, led by the United Kingdom, won an appeal against the Commission over the Air France subsidies in the ECJ. However, Air France was not required to repay the subsidy.64 The chances of the Commission approving state aid to another state-owned airline in the future are thus highly unlikely – EU airlines must now face competition on their own. While the Commission and most member states have condemned the practice of offering direct subsidies to airlines, EU officials are quick to point out that U.S. airlines received $2.3 billion in government aid in May 2003. The aid, given to airlines to help deal with reduced demand coming as a result of the war in Iraq and Severe Acute Respiratory Syndrome (SARS), significantly padded the 2003 second-quarter earnings of U.S. airlines. For example, Delta, the third-biggest U.S. airline, reported earnings of $184 million, but received government aid of $251 million. Government aid of $209 million contributed to the $227 million in profits for No. 4 Northwest, while No. 5 Continental posted profits of $79 million following $111 million in aid.65 Ownership Regulations Under U.S. regulations, any airline operating point-to-point service within the United States must operate with a certificate issued by the U.S. Department of Transportation. One of the requirements for obtaining a certificate is U.S. citizenship, defined by three separate statutes: 1. The company must be incorporated in the United States. proposed changes that would address alliances with non-EU carriers. See Commission of the European Communities (2003). 62 Dobson (1995), p. 228. 63 Dinan (1999), p. 387, and Dobson (1995), p. 229. 64 Dinan (1999), p. 387. 65 Bloomberg News (2003). 16 2. The company must have a president and two-thirds of the board of directors who are U.S. citizens. 3. The company must ensure that no less than 75 percent of its voting stock is owned by U.S. citizens.66 Ostensibly, the rule limiting foreign ownership of an airline operating within the United States to 25 percent is necessary out of national security concerns. Currently, U.S. airlines participate voluntarily in a program called the Civil Reserve Air Fleet (CRAF), under which U.S. airlines provide a specific number of aircraft and crew to transport military personnel and supplies in an emergency capacity. In return, the U.S. government procurement of air services consists of the Fly America program, which gives U.S. carriers exclusive access to the peacetime business of U.S. government officials. It maintains these programs in order to preserve legal leverage over airlines – if an airline were to violate its terms under the CRAF program, the U.S. government could revoke its operating license.67 In practice, however, the national security argument does not hold up, as a European airline operating within the United States would be subject to the same regulations as a U.S. airline, and the foreign-owned airline would remain subject to Exon-Florio provisions.68 Under Exon-Florio, the U.S. Department of Treasury can block transactions or investments by foreign entities that threaten national security.69 Thus, the limitation on foreign airline ownership can be seen more as a means to protect U.S. airlines from foreign competition and prevent foreign airlines from enjoying cabotage in the U.S. domestic market. The rules regarding citizenship of airlines are also built into even the most liberal open skies bilateral ASAs between the United States and EU members. The nationality clause present in every bilateral ASA with the United States requires that an airline be “substantially owned and effectively controlled” by the state signing the ASA. British Airways’ German subsidiary, Deutsche BA, may operate cabotage flights within Germany or to any European airport; it may not fly to the United States under the U.S.-Germany bilateral ASA because it is effectively controlled by the parent, a British company. Under European law, a non-European entity may own up to 49.5 percent of an airline operating within the European Union.70 However, in order to be considered a European “Community carrier,” the airline must be 51 percent owned by EU nationals. The U.S. foreign ownership limitation on airlines is currently being challenged by DHL Airways, a U.S. subsidiary of the German company Deutsche Post, which operates air cargo services within the United States.71 DHL is under investigation by the U.S. Department of Transportation at the behest of UPS and FedEx, U.S. air cargo companies that stand to lose a substantial amount of market share should DHL be allowed to operate its services within the 66 Mead (2003), p. 2. Brattle Group (2002), p. x. 68 Brattle Group (2002), p. xi. 69 U.S. Department of Treasury Office of International Affairs (2003). 70 Dombey and Done (2001). 71 Mead (2003), p. 2. 67 17 United States. Again, this tends toward the proposition that the U.S. regulation exists to limit competition and protect domestic airlines, rather than to protect national security. The nationality clause built into bilateral ASAs and the U.S. foreign ownership limitation on airlines act as non-tariff barriers to the U.S. market for air services.72 These rules also stand in the way of completing the single European market in air travel, by requiring European airlines to operate flights to the United States from their home country only. Yet the EU members that have signed bilateral ASAs with the United States are powerless to protest these rules; even a powerful member state like France, Germany or Britain has little leverage against the United States when negotiating on its own. Further, the current regime of bilateral ASAs provides insulation to smaller EU member states that wish to protect their national champion airlines’ share of the transatlantic market, by preventing other airlines from operating out of their home airports, as EU rules would allow. The European Commission contends that only a concerted effort will apply sufficient pressure on the United States to make allowances that will complete the single European market in air travel. Bilateral ASAs and the EU Single Market The implications of the European Court of Justice’s decision of November 5, 2002, extend beyond the eight member states named in the case for signing bilateral ASAs with the United States, to the bilateral ASA regime as a whole. More broadly, the ECJ decision speaks to the need for a common external policy in the realm of air transport. The Commission views the ECJ as an opportunity to redress the illegalities outlined by the decision, but also as a chance to make changes in the interest of “creating additional opportunities for the European aviation industry and giving European consumers a broader choice of service.”73 Why do Bilateral ASAs Violate the Single Market Principle? Following three packages of reforms to create a single market for air transport in the European Union, which were modestly successful in liberalizing intra-EU air travel, airlines in the European Union remain fragmented along national lines. The resulting growth patterns among EU airlines reflect growth in home markets only, rather than growth through investment in other member states or through mergers and acquisitions.74 This is a violation of the right of establishment, which allows any EU firm to establish operations in the territory of any EU member state, under Article 43 of the EC Treaty. The existence of nationality clauses in bilateral ASAs prevents EU carriers with operations in the territory of a member state from operating to a third country in accordance with the terms offered to a carrier that is a national of the member state in question.75 This violates the principle of non-discrimination, which considers all EU firms to be recognized as “community” firms, rather than being recognized as nationals of a particular member state. The European Court of Justice Decision 72 The European Union, through its foreign ownership limitations, maintains a similar non-tariff barrier that prevents U.S. airlines from being treated as “community carriers.” 73 Commission of the European Communities (2003), Point 25. 74 Commission of the European Communities (2002b), point 9. 75 Commission of the European Communities (2003), point 11. 18 Since attempts to complete the single European market for air transport began in earnest between 1987 and 1992, the European Commission had taken issue with bilateral ASAs that contained clauses that recognized European carriers only along national lines. In response to a flurry of activity on bilateral ASAs between the United States and EU member states, the Commission wrote a letter in November 1994 stating that such negotiations could only legally be carried out at the EU level.76 In early 1995, during the run-up to the completion of the third package of single-market reforms in 1997, the United States completed open skies bilateral ASAs with Belgium, Austria, Luxembourg and Finland, and was working on two more with Sweden and Denmark. Concurrently, the United States and Britain were also in negotiations to find an alternative to the restrictive Bermuda II agreement.77 On July 17, 1995, the Commission sent a formal letter to the United Kingdom notifying them that the amendment to the Bermuda II agreement reached on July 5, 1995 – which switched the U.S. carriers allowed to fly into Heathrow Airport from Pan Am and TWA to United and American – violated Article 43 of the EC Treaty. Article 43 provides for non-discrimination in the treatment of firms from any EU member state, regardless of where that firm is established and the nationality of the owners of the firm, and allows the right of any EU firm to establish operations in any EU member state, subject to the same rules as any firm established in that member state.78 The United Kingdom argued that because the nationality clause in Bermuda II that was seen as a violation of Article 43 was actually an extension of the nationality clause built into the Bermuda I agreement, which was concluded before the United Kingdom entered the European Union in 1973, it could not be found in violation of Article 43.79 Unswayed by the British argument, the European Commission filed a complaint with the European Court of Justice on December 18, 1998, against the United Kingdom, Denmark, Sweden, Finland, Belgium, Luxembourg, Austria and Germany over bilateral ASAs they had concluded with the United States. Although the other seven member states against which action was brought, unlike the United Kingdom, had negotiated open skies bilateral ASAs rather than more restrictive regimes, the Commission argued they were nonetheless in violation of Article 43 of the EC Treaty, by virtue of nationality clauses contained within those agreements. In the interim between the Commission filing suit and the ECJ ruling on November 5, 2002, including talks that began as late as August 15, 2002, Britain and the United States continued to attempt an open skies alternative to the Bermuda II agreement, further enraging the Commission. While open skies talks broke down less than a month later, the British were still pushing for a more limited liberalization of Bermuda II. The Commission issued a stern warning to Britain and other countries in October that no agreements were to be reached while the legality of such agreements was being deliberated by the ECJ.80 76 European Court of Justice (2002). Reuters (1995). 78 European Court of Justice (2002). 79 European Court of Justice (2002). The United Kingdom based its line of argumentation on Article 307 of the EC Treaty, which allows member states to uphold treaties concluded with outside states that were concluded prior to entry into the European Union. 80 Dombey (2002a). 77 19 The ECJ found in favor of the European Commission, which argued – among other things – that nationality clauses within the agreements violated the principles of the single market. It was this line of argumentation that the ECJ found most convincing in its decision: “... [B]y concluding and applying an Air Services Agreement signed on 23 July 1977 (the Bermuda II Agreement) with the United States of America which allows that non-member country to revoke, suspend or limit traffic rights in cases where air carriers designated by the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland are not owned by it or its nationals, the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland has failed to fulfill its obligations under ... the EC Treaty.”81 The ECJ applied the “AETR” principle, under which the European Union acquires external competence when it is able to exercise internal competence “where the international commitments fall within the scope of the common rules.”82 Additional rules that have resulted in changes to the transport section of the Acquis are also subject to EU competence, as the Commission elaborates: “In subjects where Member States have agreed that it makes sense to adopt common rules within the Community, they must draw the consequences and work through its institutions when discussing such matters with foreign countries.”83 In short, member states must cease and desist from negotiating any further agreements or amendments to existing agreements, as such agreements are within EU competence. The decision against the United Kingdom is consistent with the decisions against the other seven countries that had signed bilateral ASAs, and covers all bilateral ASAs in place between all EU member states and all third countries, so long as the agreements contain a nationality clause or otherwise infringe “Community exclusive external competence.”84 Thus, the Commission was victorious in preventing the further use of bilateral ASAs by member states, but fell short of its greater goal of placing negotiating authority for the entire EU under the Commission Directorate General for Transport and Energy, led by Loyola de Palacio. Under the ECJ decision, neither EU member states nor the Commission has “free rein” to conclude bilateral ASAs.85 Commissioner Palacio nonetheless heralded the ECJ’s decision the following day: “This is a historic decision that is going to have some enormously positive consequences for the consolidation of the European aviation industry.”86 The European Commission Viewpoint In the context of the single European market for air services, the Commission had a valid argument to deliver to the ECJ against bilateral ASAs with the United States. The Commission feels that bilateral ASAs give an unfair advantage to non-EU carriers that are protected in their home markets: “Nationality-based rules hamper competition between European Community airlines and effectively prevent the European industry from consolidating into economically 81 Excerpted from European Court of Justice (2002). Commission of the European Communities (2002b), point 29. 83 Commission of the European Communities (2002b), points 31 and 33. 84 Commission of the European Communities (2002b), point 38. 85 Commission of the European Communities (2002b), point 42. 86 Dombey (2002b). 82 20 stronger, international businesses.”87 The argument continues, “Such allocation of traffic rights by nationality … effectively prevents any EU airlines with global ambitions from establishing international operations in an EU member state other than its own.”88 The Commission sees bilateral ASAs as giving U.S. carriers operational advantages within the EU market, without granting “rights of equivalent value” to EU carriers in the U.S. market.89 One of these advantages is the right to fly fifth-freedom flights beyond the destination country to a third country. “These fifth freedoms are of relatively little value on the American side of the Atlantic, given that there are relatively few viable onward destinations. However, in parts of the world where there are many international markets in close proximity, such as the EU, they are more useful.” Fifth freedom rights effectively give U.S. carriers access to the intra-EU market, while EU carriers have no such access to the U.S. domestic market, where such flights would be considered cabotage.90 A strong argument can also be made that in the interest of gaining greater concessions from the United States, the member states of the EU should pool their negotiating leverage – rather than allowing the United States to “pick off” member states one at a time – by granting negotiating authority to the European Commission.91 This “community approach” has additional benefits. First, it prevents mixed signals from reaching third countries like the United States, as the views of EU member states may diverge on certain aspects of reforming the bilateral ASA regime.92 Second, such an approach prevents the possibility of the United States unilaterally rebuffing an individual member state that carries little political weight in the eyes of U.S. officials.93 Third, it prevents competition among member states in attempting to accentuate certain aspects of reforms while downplaying others, to the advantage of individual member states; this would result in “an incoherent patchwork of international market access opportunities.” Further, the member state that was most successful in implementing measures consistent with the EU single market would face the greatest competition from other EU airlines without necessarily receiving additional market access in return.94 Finally, the community approach would allow the Commission to undertake comprehensive negotiations on a number of issues that prevent the smooth operation of the single market for air transport, rather than tackle the issues one at a time.95 In late January 2003, Director General for Transport and Energy Francois Lamoureux sent a sharply worded letter to EU member states threatening legal action “should any member state decide to make unilateral amendments of their agreements with the U.S.”96 The letter continued, “Our aim should first be to reach agreement among ourselves within Europe and then to further our objectives vis-à-vis international trading partners and then begin a coordinated 87 Commission of the European Communities (2002a), point 6. Commission of the European Communities (2002a), annex 5. 89 Commission of the European Communities (2002a), point 10. 90 Commission of the European Communities (2002b), point 14. 91 Commission of the European Communities (2002a), point 15. 92 Commission of the European Communities (2003), point 38. 93 Commission of the European Communities (2003), point 39. 94 Commission of the European Communities (2003), point 40. 95 Commission of the European Communities (2003), point 44. 96 Dombey (2003b). 88 21 community approach to the outside world.”97 The Commission followed that communiqué with a proposal on February 26 that would strip negotiating power from member states in an attempt to move forward with EU-wide negotiations with the United States. The proposal leaves the existing bilateral ASAs in place until an EU-wide agreement has been negotiated by the Commission, eliminating at least some of the legal uncertainty created by the ECJ decision.98 On June 5, 2003, the Council agreed to give the Commission a mandate to negotiate on ASAs on behalf of all member states, a victory the Commission had been seeking for over a decade.99 Convening the ministers of transportation of all of the member states, the Transport Council passed a package consisting of three measures. First, the mandate gives the Commission the authority to open negotiations with the United States, in the interest of working toward an EU-U.S. open aviation area, to replace existing bilateral agreements agreed by member states. Second, the Council authorized the Commission to open negotiations on EU-wide agreements with third countries to replace existing bilateral agreements. Third, the Council drafted a regulation to allow member states to continue to negotiate and implement bilateral ASAs with third countries “with a view, inter alia, to reducing the vulnerability to legal challenge of their existing bilateral agreements.”100 Reflecting a political compromise between the Commission and member states over negotiating prerogatives, the third measure has the practical benefit of providing for member states to assist the Commission in renegotiating the hundreds of bilateral ASAs with third countries to bring them in line with the ECJ decision -- an “immense and extraordinary task” for which the Commission lacks adequate resources.101 The mandate gives the Commission authority to establish a new framework for external relations in the aviation sector, based on the principles outlined in the ECJ decision, “offering pragmatic solutions to the many difficult political and legal questions raised by these judgments.” On the mandate to open community-level negotiations with the United States, the Council “envisages a comprehensive liberal agreement allowing carriers from both the European Union and the United States to provide air services on a fair and equal basis.” Guidelines for negotiations cover “market access, ownership and control, leasing, convergence on the application of competition rules, safety, and institutional arrangements” but were not fully disclosed.102 The U.S. Viewpoint U.S. officials insisted immediately following the ECJ decision that the bilateral agreements remained in effect, regarding the agreements as binding until nullified by both parties.103 “The current agreements remain in force as the legal basis for air services between the U.S. and individual member states,” said a U.S. official in the Financial Times.104 At the same time, however, the ECJ decision sparked dialogue between U.S. officials in the State Department and the European Commission. 97 Fuller (2003b). Meller (2003). 99 Dombey (2003a). 100 Council of Ministers (2003). 101 European Union (2003). 102 Council of Ministers (2003). 103 Dombey (2002b). 104 Dombey and Done (2002). 98 22 The United States initially offered only to remove the nationality clauses that restrict the agreements to national airlines, in order to eliminate parts of the agreements the ECJ ruled were the responsibility of the European Union as a whole. “If Air France, for example, wishes to buy KLM or Alitalia and operate under the Dutch or Italian open skies agreement with the United States, this would allow them the right to do that,” said U.S. Deputy Assistant Secretary of State for Transportation Affairs John Byerly. He called these concessions “a major move,” adding, “This would open the door and remove a cited impediment to European consolidation of airlines – if that’s what they want to do.”105 Director General Lamoureux referred to such concessions in his letter to EU members as a “minimalist proposal that fails to recognize the fundamental rights” of the EU treaty.106 In fact, the concessions offered by Byerly would not have resolved the inconsistencies cited by the ECJ; the agreements would still have been in violation of Right of Establishment rules outlined in the EC Treaty. The United States has been seen by the European Union as a staunch defender of its own airlines, similar to the national-champion mindset of many of its EU counterparts. Examples abound, not the least of which is the more than $17 billion in aid and loan guarantees U.S. airlines have received since Sept. 11. The biggest perceived threat to U.S. airlines arising from the completion of the single European market for air travel would be consolidation among European carriers that might result in a major new competitor such as a combined British-KLM Airways, which were prevented from merging in 2000 over complications arising from bilateral ASAs.107 U.S. airlines could, however, potentially reap benefits from airline industry consolidation, particularly if cross-border mergers are allowed under a new air services regime such as an EU-US open aviation area. Such consolidation could provide a much-needed capital injection to ailing U.S. airlines. As an initial step in this direction, the U.S. Department of Transportation in May 2003 proposed to raise the limit on foreign airline ownership from 25 percent to 49 percent, bringing the United States in line with EU ownership regulations.108 With its new authority to negotiate with the United States, the European Commission is aiming to conclude an EU-wide agreement with the United States, which is likely to include cabotage rights for EU carriers within the United States and the elimination or relaxation of the foreign ownership limitations on both sides of the Atlantic. While the primary goal of talks on a new aviation regime will be to bring bilateral ASAs into conformity with the ECJ decision, the broader goal is the liberalization of trade in airline services between and within the EU and United States under an EU-U.S. open aviation area. While a liberalized aviation regime has its proponents in the United States, labor unions, in particular, are loathe to open the U.S. market for air travel, arguing that foreign competition on domestic routes would lead to widespread job losses. However, there is probably little reason to believe European airlines would attempt to compete on already-saturated routes in the United States. The Air Transport Association, the U.S. airline trade association, announced its support for the Bush administration’s move to raise the foreign ownership limit to 49 percent, an initial 105 Fuller (2003b). Dombey (2003a). See also Fuller (2003a). 107 Landler (2002). 108 Done (2003). 106 23 step toward liberalization. “This change has the potential to create greater access to the global capital marketplace for U.S. airlines and could bring U.S. foreign-investment regulations in line with those of other countries, including those of the European Union,” said Air Transport Association President and CEO James C. May.109 United Airlines CEO Glenn Tilton has also come out in support of liberalization: “The future of our industry is in multilateral ‘Open Skies’ agreements ….” He continued, “We must also break down barriers to consolidation and access to global capital. That’s why we strongly support the [Bush] administration’s proposal to raise the Cold War-era caps on foreign investment from 25 to 49 percent.”110 Airlines’ Perspectives KLM At other airports in Europe, congestion and capacity restrictions prevent one carrier from dominating, but KLM has exploited Schiphol Airport, the only major airport in the Netherlands, and set up perhaps the most efficient hub-and-spoke system in Europe.111 Given the miniscule nature of demand for domestic travel in a small country like the Netherlands, KLM really had no choice other than to capitalize on the central location of Schiphol Airport by seizing as much of the European market for travel into Amsterdam as possible. Through its code-sharing alliance concluded in 1989 with Northwest Airlines, KLM is able to serve nearly every U.S. destination from over 100 European airports. The government of the Netherlands has supported KLM in its attempt to corner the market in travel to and from Amsterdam, both diplomatically and financially. The Netherlands was the first EU member state to sign an open skies bilateral ASA with the United States in 1992; with the creation of the EU single market, it has prepared for additional competition by intensifying efforts to build up a European network to feed Amsterdam for more profitable transatlantic flights.112 Its dependence on its code-sharing partner in the United States produces a conflict, however. While it would also prefer to cooperate with other European carriers to exploit the single market, most European carriers have their own U.S. partners, forcing KLM to remain loyal to NWA lest it lose market share in Europe or in Amsterdam to other EU carriers.113 It was thus not surprising that the Netherlands argued alongside other individual member states before the ECJ to preserve the system of bilateral ASAs, rather than siding with the Commission.114 British Airways The United Kingdom has followed a much different tack in the bilateral ASA system. Although it has attempted to renegotiate its bilateral ASA with the United States, the restrictive Bermuda II agreement remains in force. The ECJ decision ensures the agreement will not be renegotiated without participation by the Commission. As a result of Bermuda II, only two U.S. carriers are allowed to fly to Heathrow Airport in London, while others must use Gatwick 109 Air Transport Association (2003). Tilton (2003). 111 Graham (1995), p. 158. 112 Staniland (2003), p. 14. 113 Staniland (2003), p. 15. 114 European Court of Justice (2002). 110 24 Airport, perceived by many as less convenient. The U.S. share of transatlantic traffic to Britain has decreased steadily, from 46.1 percent in 1994, to 41.9 percent in 1995, to 37.8 percent in November 2002. The British government has thus fought to preserve the bilateral system in part because of the protection it offers to the lucrative U.S.-UK market, a market that made up 34.9 percent of all transatlantic travel in 1995.115 British Airways also avoids the British domestic market, choosing instead to dominate in transatlantic routes and in service to European airports to the east and south of the United Kingdom, as well as routes to other worldwide destinations in Africa, the Middle East and India.116 It is thus also dependent on its bilateral ASA with the United States, not because of the access it allows, but because of the access it restricts. British Airways has in its code-sharing partner, American Airlines, access to one of the two most extensive U.S. hub-and-spoke networks – it even attempted, despite all the regulatory restrictions, a merger with American Airlines as recently as 2002. While British Airways has supported the move toward a single market in the EU, it has major concerns with handing negotiating authority to the European Commission, partially because of the bargaining chip represented by Heathrow Airport. A negotiated agreement between all of Europe and the United States would likely result in a loss of British Airways’ market share at Heathrow, and the United Kingdom would not be able to guarantee that additional access to the U.S. market would compensate for this loss.117 The Low-Cost Carriers – Southwest, Ryanair and Easyjet Conspicuously absent from the transatlantic market for air travel are the low-cost carriers: Southwest in the United States and Ryanair and Easyjet in Ireland and the United Kingdom, respectively. Expanding to international travel would require a considerable capital outlay by Southwest, which currently serves only the U.S. domestic market with shorter-range aircraft unable to fly across the Atlantic. But Southwest’s strategy, shared by Ryanair and Easyjet, of serving smaller airports with smaller, more efficient aircraft and relying substantially less on expensive hub-and-spoke networks, offers an interesting opportunity. A liberalized ownership regime might allow Southwest, the most profitable U.S. airline, to merge with a low-cost carrier in the United Kingdom or elsewhere in Europe, and offer service to London’s Gatwick Airport and other under-utilized European airports. While Southwest has established a more point-topoint network in the United States, it could still offer competitive international service through a merger with Easyjet or Ryanair, much like the NWA-KLM alliance, with relatively few transatlantic flights and with only a couple of long-haul aircraft. However, the track record for low-cost international carriers, in the tradition of Freddie Laker’s Skytrain and the short-lived People Express, may suggest that Southwest, Ryanair and Easyjet should maintain their current structures. Conclusion The European Commission, in its desire to complete the single European market for air travel, has succeeded in the initial step of gaining a mandate from member states to negotiate a new air services agreement with the United States and third countries. The EU, while seeking primarily to being the transatlantic aviation regime into accordance with the ECJ’s November 5, 115 Staniland (1996), p. 6. Staniland (1996), p. 11. 117 Staniland (1996), p. 12. 116 25 2002, decision, will likely be pressing for the completion of a liberalized EU-U.S. open aviation area, which would go beyond even existing open skies agreements. If past bilateral negotiations are any indicator, talks between the United States and the European Union will be long and arduous. Since most U.S. carriers can already operate fifth freedom flights between EU member states, the Commission cannot consider intra-EU cabotage as a bargaining chip to offer the United States. Short of playing hard-ball in negotiations with the United States, for example by threatening to suspend these fifth freedom privileges, the Commission can offer little more than liberalization of the restrictive bilateral ASAs with Britain, Greece, Ireland and Spain, which would allow increased access by U.S. airlines to London’s Heathrow Airport, an avowed goal of the United States. The European Union may have to appeal to the precarious financial situation faced by many U.S. airlines in 2003 – many have not yet recovered from the travel downturn that began with the attacks of September 11, 2001. The relaxation of foreign ownership limitations would open foreign capital markets to U.S. airlines. The Brattle Group estimates that an EU-U.S. open aviation area would result in an additional 17 million passengers a year, increased employment in the United States and Europe, and consumer benefits of $5 billion.118 The United States holds its own bargaining chips, including an end to the “Fly America” government procurement program and allowing forms of domestic U.S. cabotage, key objectives of the European Union. Questions for Discussion 1. What interests and institutions are the driving forces behind centralizing authority over air services agreements within Europe? What actors resist this centralization? What is the scope and significance of the decision of the European Court of Justice? 2. Describe the central dilemma faced by governments and airlines in the wake of the ECJ decision. What changes have to be made to the regime of bilateral ASAs to bring the agreements into accordance with the decision? What were the central reasons the Transport Council decided to delegate negotiating authority to the European Commission? 3. As the chief executive officer of a European airline, what should be your strategy with respect to European policy? What should be your business strategy? How does your strategy differ depending on whether you are a high-cost, state-owned airline in one of the smaller member states versus a large, lower-cost, private airline in a large member state? 4. Identify the preferences of the United States with respect to transatlantic air services agreements and further liberalization. Differentiate between airlines, consumers and regulators. Which airlines would stand to gain and lose from an EU-U.S. open aviation area? How would consumers gain or lose from such an agreement? What position should the U.S. government adopt? 118 Brattle Group (2002). 26 5. Consider the negotiating arrangements for a new transatlantic accord. How does the consolidation of negotiating authority under the Commission affect the negotiating leverage of the United States? As the Transport Council will have to ratify any agreement, how would voting procedures (consensus, unanimity, qualified majority) probably affect the outcome? 6. Given the balance of concessions that each side could offer the other, what do you believe is the most likely outcome from these negotiations? Is a full EU-U.S. open aviation area possible or realistic? References Air Transport Association. (2003). “Air Transport Association Statement on Foreign Ownership of U.S. Carriers.” Press Release. 13 June. Available at www.air-transport.org. BBC News. (2002). “France to cut stake in national airline.” 29 July. Available at http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/business/2159767.stm Bloomberg News. (2003). “Aid Enables Airlines to Return to Profit.” Los Angeles Times. 18 July. p. C3. Brattle Group. (2002). “The Economic Impact of an EU-US Open Aviation Area.” Report prepared for the European Commission Directorate-General Energy and Transport. Available at http://www.europa.eu.int/comm/transport/air/international/index_en.htm Brueckner, Jan K. (2003). “International Airfares in the Age of Alliances: The Effects of Codesharing and Antitrust Immunity.” The Review of Economics and Statistics. 85(1):105-118. Commission of the European Communities. (2002a). “Background note -- The ‘Open Skies’ Court Cases.” 29 January. Retrieved from LexisNexis Academic Universe. Commission of the European Communities. (2002b). “Communication from the Commission on the consequences of the Court judgements of 5 November 2002 for European air transport policy.” 19 November. COM (2002) 649 final. Commission of the European Communities. (2003). “Communication from the Commission on relations between the Community and third countries in the field of air transport.” 26 February. COM (2003) 94 final. Council of Ministers. (2003). Press Release 9686/03 (Presse 146). 2515th Council Meeting – Transport, Telecommunications and Energy – Luxembourg, 5 June. de Murias, Ramon. (1989). The Economic Regulation of International Air Transport. Jefferson, NC: McFarland. 27 Dinan, Desmond. (1999). Ever Closer Union, 2nd Edition. Boulder, CO: Lynne Reinner. Dobson, Alan P. (1995). Flying in the Face of Competition: The Policies and Diplomacy of Airline Regulatory Reform in Britain, the USA and the European Community 1968-94. Brookfield, VT: Ashgate. Dombey, Daniel. (2002a). “UK warned by Brussels over ‘open skies’ deal.” Financial Times. 18 October. Dombey, Daniel. (2002b). “Long haul ahead in ‘open skies’ struggle.” Financial Times. 6 November. Dombey, Daniel. (2003a). “Brussels escalates dispute on ‘open skies.’ ” Financial Times. 31 January. p. 10. Dombey, Daniel. (2003b). “Brussels wins EU mandate to agree aviation deals with US.” Financial Times. 6 June. p. 9. Dombey, Daniel and Done, Kevin. (2001). “Brussels fights for right to arrange air deals.” Financial Times. 8 May. p. 12. Dombey, Daniel and Done, Kevin. (2002). “Ruling paves way for EU airline consolidation.” Financial Times. 6 November. p. 1. Done, Kevin. (2002). “Over and out for marathon talks on open skies accord.” Financial Times. 12 September. Done, Kevin. (2003). “US proposes airline law reform.” Financial Times. 23 May. p. 1. European Court of Justice. (2002). Commission of the European Communities v United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. Case C-466/98-67. 5 November. European Union. (2003). “New Era for Air Transport: Loyola de Palacio welcomes the mandate given to the European Commission for negotiating an Open Aviation Area with the US.” Press Release IP/03/806. 5 June. Fischer, Roland. (1997). Time Sensitivity of Passengers and Market Structure in the Airline Industry: A Model of International Air Transport. New York: Peter Lang. Fuller, Thomas. (2003a). “Europeans Told to Avoid U.S. Accords On Airlines.” International Herald Tribune. 30 January. p. W7. Fuller, Thomas. (2003b). “EU to fight bilateral ‘open skies’ deals.” International Herald Tribune. 31 January. p. 13. 28 Graham, Brian. (1995). Geography and Air Transport. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Hanlon, Pat. (1996). Global Airlines: Competition in a Transnational Industry. Oxford: Butterworth-Heinemann. Kyrou, Dinos. (2000). Lobbying the European Commission: The Case of Air Transport. Burlington, VT: Ashgate. Landler, Mark. (2002). “Europe’s Highest Court Voids Air Treaties With the U.S.” The New York Times. 6 November. p. C1. Mead, Kenneth M. (2003). Letter to Rep. Don Young, Chairman, House Transportation and Infrastructure Committee. 4 March. Available at http://dmses.dot.gov/docimages/pdf85/235460_web.pdf Meller, Paul. (2003). “Europeans Propose to End ‘Open Skies’ Deals.” The New York Times. 27 February. p. W1. Morrison, Steven A. and Winston, Clifford. (1995). The Evolution of the Airline Industry. Washington, DC: Brookings. Petzinger Jr., Thomas. (1995). Hard Landing: The Epic Contest for Power and Profits That Plunged the Airlines into Chaos. New York: Random House. Reuters (1995). “U.S. and Britain to Resume Aviation Talks.” The New York Times. 10 April. p. D12. Sinha, Dipendra. (2001). Deregulation and Liberalisation of the Airline Industry: Asia, Europe, North America and Oceania. Burlington, VT: Ashgate. Sochor, Eugene. (1991). The Politics of International Aviation. Iowa City, IA: University of Iowa Press. Staniland, Martin. (1996). “Open skies -- fewer planes? Public policy and corporate strategy in EU-US aviation relations,” European Policy Paper Series, No. 3 (August). Center for West European Studies, University of Pittsburgh. Staniland, Martin. (2003). “Surviving the Single Market: The Dilemmas and Strategies of ‘Small-Country’ Airlines.” European Union Center and Center for West European Studies, University of Pittsburgh, Working Paper No. 4. Tilton, Glenn. (2003). “Remarks at the Aero Club.” Washington, DC. 24 July. U.S. Department of Treasury Office of International Affairs. (2003). “Exon-Florio Provision.” Available at http://www.ustreas.gov/offices/international-affairs/exon-florio/