Feminist Economics Challenges Mainstream Economics Diane Elson, PhD, Professor, University of Essex (UK) and Senior Scholar, Levy Economics Institute, Bard College, (USA) In this presentation I will discuss some of the ways in which mainstream macroeconomics has been extended by gender analysis; and some of the ways in which feminist economists, taking heterodox macroeconomics as a starting point, are seeking to challenge mainstream macroeconomics. I want to distinguish between extending the mainstream paradigm and challenging the mainstream paradigm. The paradigm can be extended by adding new features, filling in gaps, and replacing simple assumptions by more complex assumptions. I think that feminist economics can be more ambitious than that. We can and should seek to challenge the fundamental assumptions of the mainstream. And begin to develop alternative forms of analysis and policy. I will draw upon the macroeconomics I learned as a student in Oxford, at St Hilda’s college in the late sixties; a macroeconomics witch drew inspiration from Keynes, Kalecki, and Marx; and was grounded in an appreciation of the importance of institutional context and of history. I would particularly like to salute the women who taught me macroeconomics at Oxford, especially Nita Watts, Fellow of St Hilda’s College. I will also draw upon the research of the International Working Group on Gender and Macroeconomics, and informal international network of women and men, co-ordinated by Niluer Vagatay, Cren Grown, Rania Antonopolous, Sergy Floro and myself. The Group produced two special issues o World Development (November 1995 and July 2000) and has for the last two years organized a summer school on gender, macroeconomics, and international economics at the University of Utah. I will define the scope of macroeconomics broadly, to consider analysis that looks at the economy as a whole, as distinct from microeconomics, which analyses the economic behaviour o individuals, households and enterprises; and meso economics, which analyses the operation of mediating institutions such as markets and state agencies. Feminist economics has, to date, produced more analysis of the operations of economies at the micro and meso level. The programme for the 2004 IAFFE conference contains many more sessions on micro and meso economics than on macroeconomics. Nevertheless, there is a growing body of feminist research that has produced the following critiques of mainstream macroeconomics: mainstream macroeconomics is gender blind It is based on an incomplete understanding of how economies work. This promotes the introduction of policies which disadvantage women, especially poor women; macroeconomics should recognise and incorporate the unpaid domestic work that is vital for social reproduction (the reproduction of the whole society, including the day-to-day and intergenerational reproduction of labour power); macroeconomics should incorporate gender inequality variables. Feminist economists have done empirical and conceptual work to incorporate social reproduction and gender inequality variables in macroeconomic analysis. So also have some mainstream economists. I will discuss examples of each. Mainstream analysis macroeconomics that incorporate gender We learnt in a Conference presentation by Irene van Staveren that macroeconomists in the Netherlands have incorporated the unpaid domestic work of caring for family members in the model that is officially used to analyse macroeconomic policy. They have modelled the supply and demand for this labour in much the same way as the supply and demand of paid work, with one important exception. The performance of unpaid work is assumed to generate utility for the provider as well as for receiver; but the performance of paid work is assumed to generate utility only for the receiver. Irene challenged this on the grounds that both paid and unpaid work can generate both utility and disutility for the provider; and there is no good reason to assume that unpaid work uniquely generates utility for the provider. Because women so often do unpaid care work out of love, does not mean that they always love doing it! Another area in which mainstream economists have engaged with gender is in the analysis of the determinants and benefits of economic growth. World Bank economists David Dollar and Roberta Gatti have run cross-country and time series regressions and come to the conclusion that growth is food for gender equality and gender equality is good for growth. In other words, all is for the best in the best o all possible worlds. But Dollar and Gatti examine only a restricted range of gender inequality variables, focusing on education and not on the labour market. This is in line with the major focus of the World Bank policy advice which argues that investing in the education of girls promotes benefits for all. World Bank economists have also incorporated gender into the model of the small dependent economy that underpins the design o structural adjustment models. Collier treats gender as a market imperfection that hinders the reallocation of female labour from the production of non-tradables to the production of tradables in low-income subSaharan African economies. Gender is in this view a barrier to successful structural adjustment. Gender as a market imperfection also provides the theoretical framework for recent research by Black and Brainard at the US National Bureau for Economic Research on the impact of international trade on the gender wage gap in the USA. They find that import competition has reduced discrimination against women in the US labour market, a result given considerable prominence by Jagdish Bhagwati, Professor of Economics at Columbia University, in his recent book on the benefits of globalisation. Contrasting examples of feminist macroeconomics Feminist economics that challenges the mainstream dose not see gender as just another market imperfection. It takes a more structuralist view of economies, as incorporating persistent asymmetries in power and knowledge. Stephanie Seguino finds no convulsive evidence to support the view that women do better in countries that grow faster. Moreover, using cross-country and time series regression analysis she finds evidence that gender inequalities in the labour market has facilitated economic growth in semi-industrialised countries. Underpinning this last result is a more structuralist model in which low female wages stimulate industrial investment, in a profits-led process of growth. Sandy Darity offers a different understanding of gender in a lowincome Sub-Saharan African economy. He models gender not as a market imperfection but as a relation of power which structures how the agricultural sector responds to structural adjustment. He brings to light the contradictory interrelation between gender and structural adjustment. If women have sufficient bargaining power to resist demands on them to supply more labour to produce export crops controlled by their husbands, there will be a weak supply response to structural adjustment policies. If they do not have sufficient bargaining power and do re-allocate their labour from locally consumed food crops, which they control, to export crops which their husbands control, then there is a more elastic supply response in tradable production, but food security is likely to suffer and the nutritional status of women and children may deteriorate. A number of feminist economists have a very different take on gender wage gaps and globalisation. Ebru Kongar mounts a direct challenge to the work of Black and Brainard. She acknowledges that the gender wage gap has narrowed in the USA in the period of increased import competition, but points to a very different explanation: not reduction of discrimination against women, but a process in which import competition has resulted in downward pressure on male wages, and downward pressure on female employment in tradables Kongar’s model does not assume that labour markets clear rapidly and that full employment is the norm. Gunseli Berik finds that gender wages gaps worsened in South Korea and Taiwan in the period of expansion of manufactured exports while improving slightly when there was a contraction of manufactured exports, due to a decline in male wages. From the real economy to the capitalist money economy A limitation of all of the analysis discussed so far, whether mainstream or feminist, is that it abstracts from the specificities of capitalist monetary economies. It is grounded in ‘real economy’ models, in which finance is not specifically modelled. It is therefore of limited help in responding to the challenge issued to me by a former finance minister of Chile, in the summer of 2002: “I can see how gender analysis can be useful to Ministers of Education and Health, and even Ministers of Agriculture and Industry, but I do not see why it is relevant to Ministers of Finance. It would not have helped me when I was Minister of Finance”. To respond to that challenge, one needs to bring finance specifically into the analysis. Korkut Erturk, Nilufer Cagatay and I have been working together on ways on doing that. We propose and analysis based on the interrelation of three domains: finance, production and social reproduction. All three domains are considered to be ‘bearers of gender’ in the sense that they are structured through social relations which are gendered, implicitly, if not explicitly. We propose an understanding of the macro-economy in terms of the interrelation of these domains. In the period of the Keynesian consensus (1950s and 1960s), production dominated, with social reproduction and finance at the service of production. This was founded upon heterodox macroeconomics. It was not assumed that economic agents would automatically respond to price signals emerging from markets in ways that produced growth and full employment. International trade and financial links were managed in the service of the objectives of full employment and national development. Social reproduction was articulated to the other domains through systems of wage determination, social protection social insurance (for the formal sector); and systems of patronage and clientilism (for the agricultural and informal sectors); all o which were based on the assumption what men were the breadwinners and women were dependent housewives who would carry on doing the necessary unpaid work without any support from public policy. Feminist analysis re-emerged towards the end of this period to challenge the articulations that placed women in a position of dependency. Ministers of Finance did not see the relevance of this analysis because they assumed that the unpaid work would be done regardless of their policies, and their attention focused on the medium term dynamics of how to maintain the appropriate level of aggregate demand to ensure full utilization of the capacity of the paid economy. Since the mid ‘70s this has been overturned and the Washington Consensus has emerged, putting finance in the dominant position, with production at the service of finance and social reproduction at the service of both. The Washington Consensus assumes that economic agents will respond to price signals emerging from markets in ways that produce full employment and growth. Economic problems are assumed to set mainly from public policies which distort prices. Thus international trade and finance must be liberalized. it is recognised that markets may be imperfect and incomplete, so there is some role for public policy to make markets perfect and complete. This has resulted in changes of the articulation of social reproduction and production, demonstrated in some detail for the case of Australia in a Conference paper by Ray Broomhill and Rhonda Sharp. Social reproduction is increasingly articulated to the other domains through individuals participating in ‘flexible’ labour and credit markets. However, much of the male breadwinner mode of articulation persists for poor people. In better-off households unpaid domestic work has been replaced by paid domestic work, often done by migrant women. But the system is still heavily reliant on the unpaid work of women in poor and average households; and it is still largely assumed that this work will be done regardless of public policy. Finance Ministers do not see the relevance of gender analysis because they make this assumption; and because they are too busy dealing with the very short run dynamics o the domain of finance, in which large movements of currency can move in and out of a country overnight. A feminist alternative would make social reproduction the dominant domain, with production and finance acting to serve it. The macroeconomic policy objective would be decent work for all, with an equal sharing of unpaid work between women and men, supported by public policy which recognises the importance of this work. In analysing how to move to this alternative from where we are no, we argue that feminist macroeconomics will need to build on and extend heterodox macroeconomics, while challenging neoliberal macroeconomics. Heterodox macroeconomics points to intrinsic limits to the ability of the money mechanism to co-ordinate capital accumulation that set from within the money mechanism itself, in the context o a necessarily uncertain world. Feminist heterodox macroeconomics shares the starting point that monetary contracts are necessarily incomplete and contradictory; that, to use Polanyi’s language, money is a fictitious commodity that ultimately rests on non-market relations for its value. But feminist heterodox macroeconomics also insists that the domain of social reproduction also constitutes an unsurpassable limit to the ability of the money mechanism to coordinate capital accumulation. The fact that social reproduction is not co-ordinated by markets and is not governed by the profit motive is not the result of purely contingent problems of missing and imperfect markets that could be remedies by extending and improving markets. The absence o markets and the profit motive in this domain is an essential aspect of the functioning of a capitalist monetary economy. Such an economy is based on the large scale availability of free labour, both free from servitude and free from access to the means of production, except via the sale of labour power. Commercialisation of the production and nurture of human beings does of course take place in capitalist economies (surrogate motherhood for cash, babies for adoption via sale, paid care services) but production of people on the same basis as the commercial production of chicken, pigs and cows would call into question the whole operation of a free labour market and the legitimating myths of capitalist monetary economies. Polyani went some way to identifying this problem when he referred to labour as a fictitious commodity. Contracts in a capitalist money economy are necessarily incomplete nof only because of the characteristics o the domain of finance, but also because of the characteristics o the domain of social reproduction. Moreover the capitalist monetary economy adjust not only through “forced savings,” in which poor consumers are priced out of markets for consumption gods, but also through “forced unpaid labour” in which social norms lead women and girls to attempt to maintain family consumption by doing more unpaid work to produce nonmarket substitutes. There are limits, however, to the ability of women and girls to do this. Beyond narrow limits, substitution is not possible, with the result that human capabilities and social networks deteriorate. This reduces the productive capacity of the economy. This is indeed a problem for Finance Ministers, but if the rules of international trade and finance force their attention to be focused on the problems of the next 24 hours, they will not have time to consider the problems of the next 24 years. The fast dynamics of hyper-liberalised finance tend to obscure the slower dynamics of social reproduction. This is changing in some parts of the world, as major changes take place in the organisation of social reproduction through the ageing of the population structure in the North and the ravages of HIV-Aids in many countries of the South. Heterodox macroeconomics recognizes that economic growth and fluctuations are not independent, and that fluctuations in demand lower the overall productive capacity of the economy. They have not yet recognized that changes in the domain of social reproduction also lower the overall productive capacity of the economy. More work needs to be done to develop quantitative feminist heterodox analysis that would reveal the significance of these interactions. In the Conference session on feminism and postkeynesian economics, Haroon Akram-Lhodi made the interesting suggestion of doing this by building on the work of Kalecki. Feminist macroeconomics can also build on the work of Marx, who recognized that the problems of capitalist monetary economies cannot be reduced to insufficient aggregate demand, and stem from the dynamics of production that is governed by profit. A feminist macroeconomics can show that the dynamics of production that is NOT governed by profit (ie social reproduction) is also relevant. Feminist macroeconomic policy Feminist economists are beginning to work on alternative policies. For instance, valuable work has been published by Isa Bakker and Brigitte Young on the critique of macroeconomic policy rules (including balanced budget laws, asymmetric inflation targets for central banks, rules on debt to GDP ratios and budget deficit to GDP ratios). Caren Grown and Stephanie Seguino have produced a paper on a feminist-Kaleckian approach to policy. We must build on this work to show in what ways a feminist approach goes beyond the alternative polices proposed by heterodox macroeconomics. This, for me, is the appropriate task of extension and completion, while seeking to undermine the paradigm of mainstream macroeconomics. Note: This piece originally appeared in 'Feminist Economics Challenges Mainstream Economics' edited by Bina Agarwal, Special issue of the newsletter of the International Association for Feminist Economics, Vol.14, No. 3, 2004 International Association for Feminist Economics ©