YASHWANTRAO CHAVAN ACADEMY OF DEVELOPMENT ADMINISTRATION Comments on the findings of the First Independent Review of BRGF by the World Bank and the associated general issues 1) Viability of BRGF funding for bridging the infrastructure gap: The Bank has observed that BRGF may not be able to make a dent on the infrastructure gap. BRGF constitutes only 0.4% of the GoI budget and yet its share in the discretionary funds received by PRIs is in the range of 50-90%. This clearly reflects an extreme poverty of discretionary funding to the local governments. Apart from Central funding, it may be necessary for the States to seriously think of providing discretionary funds to PRIs / ULBs. Currently, the State funding to the local governments is entirely tied (with some exceptions in some States). One option is to strengthen the budgetary share of District Plan Schemes (on the lines of Maharashtra) and make it mostly untied for PRIs, ULBs and DPCs. But even in Maharashtra, currently the size of District Plan Schemes is only Rs. 2500 Crores compared to the State Plan worth Rs. 37000 Crores. Further, even this tiny proportion of district plan funds is mostly tied to a predetermined menu of district schemes. Suggestions: i) It is time to seriously think towards a consolidated fund of a district, a reasonable part of which could be discretionary / untied. ii) Apart from Central funding like BRGF & NREGA, it is necessary for the States to pass on more discretionary funds to districts – may be through increasing the share of District Plan Schemes in the State budget. iii) There must be a system of consolidating district’s own revenues, which currently get fragmented across PRIs, ULBs, revenue administration, etc. iv) The district credit plan and the sources of private / bilateral / international funding could be merged with the district fund. v) MLA / MP funds could also be consolidated into the district fund. 1 vi) The common pool of discretionary / untied funds of a district could therefore include the funding from BRGF, NREGA, Central Finance Commission, State Finance Commission, District Plan Schemes, MP / MLA funds, District Credit Plan, district’s share of own revenues, private / bilateral funding, etc. vii) Additionally, the district level budgets for capacity building, InformationEducation-Communication (IEC), community mobilization, awareness creation, etc., available under the various programmes of the Centre / States could be pooled into the district fund and a common strategy of IEC / capacity building could be drawn up. This will save a huge amount of repetition of efforts and wastage of funds on account of disconcerted efforts of different departments besides also striking a better convergence of programmes. viii) It is necessary to fully appreciate the fact that ‘gap-filling’ is a generic approach / strategy and not a specific budget category. In this sense, the approach of BRGF can, and should, be extended to all other discretionary / untied funding available in the district. This will make BRGF a ‘viable approach’ to bridging of infrastructure gap. 2) Participatory and integrated planning: The viability of BRGF as bridging grant is further marred by a lack of genuine participatory planning, which prevents its integration with other sector outlays. True bottom-up planning is a great rarity even within the individual sectors / programmes. It is extremely unusual to come across CDAP or NREGA plans (or any sector plans for that matter) that have followed a genuinely participatory process. Integrated planning can happen only at the lowest spatial levels such as villages / urban wards through a common participatory process encompassing various programmes such as NREGA, CDAP, SSA, NRHM, etc., which can then converge on key gaps to be filled through BRGF. Though the Integrated District Planning Manual has clearly mentioned the need for a common process of planning the message has not traveled through the government machinery as yet. Different sectors / departments follow their own ad-hoc schedules of planning. Even if genuine participatory processes get initiated, by chance or exception, it soon becomes botheration to communities because different programme machineries 2 approach the communities turn by turn to organize PRAs. In absence of the fundamental elements of decentralization and integrated planning, a gap-filling fund like BRGF can potentially pose a disaster. Ill equipped, the local governments as well as line departments can see great convenience and escape in dumping more and more needs into BRGF. Sectors can start shrugging off their respective responsibilities and try to hide behind BRGF. Thus, BRGF can eventually emerge as ‘super sector’ and ‘super scheme’ overwhelming all existing sector outlays. Suggestions: i) The Centre as well as States should issue directions to all districts to have a common time table annually for the community level participatory process of planning. Once integrated grampanchayat / municipal ward plans are ready, then the further task of sector wise consolidation, scrutiny and resource allocation can happen at the convenience of respective sectors / departments subject to the overall schedule of DPC planning. However, a common and synchronous process of community level participatory planning remains a fundamental condition. ii) The technical support structures and other related machineries of different line departments should be pooled together to support the common planning process at the community level. 3) Capacity building: Participatory and integrated processes of community-based planning remain the crux of BRGF in particular and district planning in general. The conceptual perspectives, methodologies, operational strategies and skill-sets required for making this a reality have been hitherto unknown in the top-down paradigm of planning in India. Most State / local governments are clueless on how to go about this aspect. Unfortunately, even many SIRDs and State training institutes are not well equipped to do the right kind of capacity building to facilitate tru participative planning at the lowest spatial levels. The cascade model of training consisting of a hierarchy of master trainers only facilitates great dilution and distortion of the whole training process. A lack of innovation in the conventional ‘classroom approach’ to 3 training acts as a repellent on PRI / ULB members who cannot stand the long hours of information bombardment through poor lectures from the under-skilled trainers. The real needs of capacity building never get addressed because there is a permanent disconnect between training and actual planning processes on ground. Most SIRDs themselves need a complete overhaul to be able to take on the challenge of capacity building in the realm of decentralization. Suggestions: i) Considering the enormous volumes of funds being spent (and largely wasted) on poorly designed and administered training / capacity building activities not only under BRGF but under an arena of other sector programmes involving bottom-up planning – it may be worth setting up ‘Regional Centres of Excellence in Decentralization’ to act as support systems to SIRDs and other State / regional / local training institutions involved in the capacity building of ground level functionaries of districts / PRIs / ULBs. ii) All States (including SIRDs) need to be directed to draw up a common strategy of training / capacity building to support the common process of community based participatory planning as suggested earlier. There is no logic in organizing one set of trainings under NREGA, the other under BRGF and yet another under TSC - all talking about the same PRA activities at the village level. In this way the training / capacity building budgets available under different sectors could also be pooled together. Apart from Central funds for training / capacity building the huge IEC budgets available with the State departments could also be pooled into a common strategy so as to optimize the resources availability for training / capacity building. iii) The training should be increasingly hands-on and process based. The training modules on integrated village planning developed in Maharashtra are such that a five-day process of participatory planning actually gets carried out during the training itself. This means that there could be a common process, and therefore a common budget, for both capacity building and actual planning as far as the lowest spatial levels, i.e., villages and urban wards are 4 concerned. Though the sector wise consolidation activities at higher levels will have to be supported by a different strategy of training involving more sector-specific inputs. 4) Delays in fund flows / transfers: Routing purely discretionary funds meant for local governments through the State machineries constitutes a fundamental paradox. If BRGF funds are discretionary then why the States have a control over their flow to the local governments? The same question also applies to the role of HPCs in sanctioning / approving BRGF plans. Suggestion: It would be thus necessary to explore the ways of direct fund transfers to the local governments even if that requires a Constitutional Amendment. Otherwise, BRGF is destined to end up as ‘yet another’ outlay with precisely the same handicaps as those faced by the existing non-discretionary / tied outlays. 5) Programme management: Thinking of an isolated programme management framework for BRGF is yet another paradox of a fundamental nature. Adding hierarchies of BRGF functionaries to an already existing mess of sector hierarchies will only worsen the problem of mismanagement of programmes and will add to the chaos. Suggestions: i) If BRGF is to bridge gaps in the outcomes of various sector programmes then it follows logically that there has to be a common programme management framework under the district planning as a whole. Under this common framework the outcomes assessment of sector programmes should provide regular feed-back to BRGF so that the key gap get identified and bridged. Again such an integrated framework must begin at the lowest spatial units, i.e., villages and urban wards. There are tested ways of setting up community based participatory mechanisms of programme management and monitoring that culminate into periodic social audits. 5 ii) Once the necessary integration and convergence in programme management is achieved at the community level then it will automatically flow upwards to create bridges across the sector machineries. iii) Under BRGF it is more crucial to think of linking together the sector wise programme machineries including the technical support structures rather than singing the same old tune of inadequate staff and unfilled vacancies. ***** 6