S USTAINING P OST -C ONFLICT E CONOMIC R ECOVERY : L ESSONS AND C HALLENGES BCPR Occasional Paper 1 October 2005 2 Sustaining Post-Conflict Economic Recovery: Lessons and Challenges1 Précis The experience of the development community, as detailed in this paper, suggests that post-conflict recovery is not sustainable unless national actors—governments and civil society— acquire the lasting means to make the key social and economic decisions necessary for addressing longer-term challenges. While the international community might provide guidance on such decisions in the short-run, long-term engagement must be nationally owned and managed. Experience has also confirmed that post-conflict transition cannot be segmented neatly into humanitarian, recovery and reconstruction phases. Rather, all the challenges are distinct but intermixed, much like the colours of a rainbow. From the very outset, therefore, international assistance should be provided with a view to building the capacities of national actors for informed, consensual, participatory, and accountable decision-making across the whole range of issues. I. The Challenges of Sustainable Post-Conflict Economic Recovery Re-creating a viable economy after prolonged violent conflict remains one of the most serious challenges of development. Some countries have emerged from such conflict and succeeded within a few years to re-position themselves within a normal development trajectory.2 However, a larger number has had great difficulty jumpstarting the economy. For example, Sierra Leone, a once viable economy, is still largely dependent on international assistance after the expenditure of nearly 3 billion dollars in six years of UN peacekeeping. Haiti presents another example. Instability fuelled in part by a failure to catalyze economic recovery has meant that over the past ten years the international community has been called in ten times to assist in peacekeeping operations. While a degree of political stability seems to have been achieved in 1 This paper was prepared by UNDP’s Bureau for Crisis Prevention and Recovery, drawing on the experiences of the UN system in supporting post-conflict recovery over the past two decades. The principal authors were John Ohiorhenuan (Coordinator) and Chetan Kumar; the team included Eva Busza, Peter Batchelor, Francesca Cook, Gita Swamy and Jan von der Goltz. Zephirin Diabre, Kalman Mizsei, Hebert M’cleod, Spyros Demetriou, Sam Barnes, Jamal Benomar, Barbara Barungi, Christina Carlson and Gana Fofang provided additional inputs and comments on an earlier draft. Kemal Dervis and Kathleen Cravero provided guidance. 2 A “normal development trajectory” does not mean that all development challenges have been overcome. Rather, it is a return to so-called “steady state”, where a country has re-established the capability to make and implement economic decisions and priorities as part of a largely self-sustaining process of economic governance. 1 Bosnia-Herzegovina, Timor Leste and Kosovo, they have not yet successfully established themselves as viable self-sustaining economies. In the immediate aftermath of a violent conflict, a range of international actors rushes in to help stabilize the situation and address the immediate challenges of relief and recovery. Useful as this assistance often is, it is widely understood, even if not often explicitly stated, that external engagement would be limited in duration. Sooner or later, national actors would have to take on the responsibility for peace building, recovery and reconstruction. Countries emerging from violent conflict face extraordinary constraints mobilizing the resources urgently required for relief, recovery and economic reconstruction. Often critically short of almost all expertise, newly established authorities have to deal simultaneously with several major challenges. They must preserve the peace and safeguard security; resettle internally displaced persons and re-integrate excombatants; rehabilitate essential infrastructure and key public institutions; revive the public finance regime and assert control over key national assets; generate employment opportunities and restore private investors’ confidence; and establish mechanisms for transitional justice and the rule of law. However, even with several decades of international post-conflict assistance, the implications of these extraordinary constraints have yet to be fully reflected in the design of such assistance. First, it bears restating that the post conflict economy is not simply a “normal” economy that happens to be in great distress. In particular, the perverseness of signals and incentives that is the legacy of violent conflict indicates a long transition to “normalcy” and extraordinary creativity in policy design and sequencing. Second, we now understand that the process of returning to a normal development situation is one of overlapping stages, like colours in a rainbow, rather than a series of segmented steps that unfold neatly one after another. Third, despite wide recognition of the need for an exit strategy based on the gradual transfer of skills and responsibilities to national partners, such a strategy is rarely deployed. This paper emphasizes that external assistance in the post-conflict setting requires a strategic framework that explicitly recognizes that these lessons indicate an integrated approach from the very beginning. Section II, surveying familiar terrain, identifies some of the main pathological characteristics of the post-conflict country. Section III highlights some of the specific policy challenges facing national actors in sustaining economic recovery. Section IV suggests some ways in which international actors can support national actors to reconstruct the institutions and processes required to overcome the pathological legacy of conflict. The concluding section restates the main message and highlights the particular relevance of development actors. II. The Post-Conflict Economy: Some Stylized Facts The phrase “post-conflict states” is used here to refer to countries that have recently emerged from a period of prolonged violent conflict. The result of such violence is, typically, a seriously compromised economic, social and physical infrastructure. Clearly the challenges of post-conflict economic recovery are unique to every different country. 2 However, there are certain commonalities that can be found to some degree across the different categories of post-conflict states. These include: economic regression, the deterioration of infrastructure, social decay, disintegration of governance mechanisms and processes, and institutional degradation. Several types of post-conflict environments may be identified. At one extreme are countries where the violence was so overwhelming that the state essentially collapsed. Countries such as Liberia, Bosnia-Herzegovina, Democratic Republic of Congo, Sierra Leone, and Somalia would seem to belong here. At the other extreme are countries such as Guatemala, Sri Lanka, and the Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia that have emerged with their political and economic structures largely intact. The stylized facts presented here might be present only to a limited degree in these countries, and primarily in areas directly affected by conflict. The challenges may also be resolved within a relatively short time, depending on resource commitment and political will. Between these extremes are countries such as Sudan, El Salvador, Mozambique, Angola, Cote d’Ivoire and Burundi, where violent conflict has affected large portions of the territory and physical decay is significant, but where the state and its basic infrastructure have remained essentially intact. There are also countries like Haiti and Guinea-Bissau, where full-scale organized violent conflict might not have erupted and hence the state is more or less intact. It is the case, however, that recurrent periods of violent tension have nevertheless left these countries in a similar situation. Economic Regression Almost by definition, conflict involves the diversion of resources from production to destruction. The conflict’s economic legacy further includes capital flight, destruction of existing assets and a corresponding reduction in economic production. Furthermore, the distorted system of asset acquisition and resource use in conflict situations bequeaths to the post conflict period a pathological system of incentives and a highly disabling environment for legitimate private sector investment. Capital flight can be particularly difficult to reverse when hostilities end. Furthermore, markets have been severely compromised; from village produce exchanges to national commodity and financial exchanges. Consequently, capital mobilization is an uphill task. Moreover, whatever is left of entrepreneurial talent tends to become engaged in catering to the service economy generated by a large international presence (e.g. Cambodia and East Timor). With the wholesale destruction of legitimate economic activity, parallel economies emerge among which are illicit ones that frequently boost the fortunes of the warlords and provide livelihoods for their constituents. Given the enormous challenges to reviving legal economies in the aftermath of violent conflict, these parallel economies constitute a continuing lure. In Afghanistan and Haiti, the drug trade provides a primary source of income for many individuals and factions. In Guatemala, several years after the conclusion of the civil war, some disaffected elements of the military have allegedly become involved in a growing and lucrative drug economy. In the Balkans, despite intermittent successes in curbing it, a parallel economy continues to flourish centered on illicit human trafficking and smuggling. Organized criminal groups establish “controlled” markets based on coercion. Extortion and protection rackets accepted 3 under duress by local populations in the absence of the rule of law divert important resources away from economic activity. Even after the ostensible end of conflict, insecurity and violence obstruct the launch of reconstruction efforts, resumption of basic services (such as electricity, water, and gas) the re-establishment of government authority and administrative services at the local level, as well as private and international investment. The need to remain mobile for security reasons means that most of the population is incapable of long-term planning and investment, and this creates strong disincentives for the return of the displaced. High rates of armed violence (whether socially or economically motivated) increase uncertainty (in terms of both lack of market information and access) and makes trade and production erratic. In the immediate post-conflict phase, jump-starting the economy is also greatly complicated by the simple fact that the state often has no revenue to pay for even such basic expenditures as salaries. In addition, disagreements over who has legitimacy and authority among key political stakeholders further exacerbate the situation by undermining people’s confidence in the state, and encouraging a reluctance to pay the dues of citizenship. Such contestation has been has been evident at a central level in Liberia, Sierra Leone, and Haiti. In Afghanistan and the DRC, the struggle is located more in the context of center-periphery relations where dominant local actors resist central authority. In other less extreme but potentially equally damaging instances, consensus on basic governance structures may exist but key actors may not support the government’s economic programme. In Guatemala, for instance, lack of buy-in from key actors has thwarted the state’s ability to collect revenues. Without a revenue base, stimulating economic recovery through public expenditures becomes an impossible dream. Infrastructural Deterioration As a deliberate strategy, opposing combatants destroy strategic infrastructure such as water, sewage, electricity, telecommunications and transport facilities. Even the education and health sectors are often not spared and central and commercial banks are routinely looted. The physical legacy of conflict also includes damaged homes and communities, and highly compromised natural environments. Sizeable areas of total devastation can be quite common as was the case in Angola, Southern Sudan, Mozambique and Afghanistan. Frequently, large areas of land have been rendered inaccessible by landmines and other unexploded ordnance. The wholesale physical destruction of key ministries combined with a lack of human capacity leads to a postconflict situation where minimal social and public services are being delivered. Social Decay The collapse of social cohesion and trust is one of the most pernicious legacies of conflict. The brain drain that violence occasions often creates large holes in the social fabric. But more important, conflict leads to the erosion of social capital and gives rise to high levels of personal and social insecurity. The social pathology of conflict is immediately manifest worldwide in the large numbers of returning refugees, internally 4 displaced persons and demobilized combatants. UNHCR estimates that there were 9.2 million refugees, 5.6 million internally displaced, and 1.5 million returnees at the beginning of 2005. Afghanistan alone received almost one million returnees from Iran and Pakistan in 2004. Large numbers of demobilized combatants have created for Liberia and Sierra Leone a serious problem of chronically unemployed or “unemployable” youth with few basic skills other than those of violence. The easy availability of weapons and the continuing influence of warlords and former combatants increase criminality, often attracting the unemployed youth, and worsening the security environment. Conflict further destroys the bonds of trust and social exchange as well as the community-level networks of social and economic exchange that have developed over decades or centuries. This breakdown of trust constrains the reconstitution of commerce and economic activity. Indeed there have been instances (such as in Rwanda and Cambodia) of conflict transforming social capital into a virulently malevolent force with extreme exclusionary characteristics. In such situations short- to medium-term post-conflict “transitional recovery” assistance provided by the international community does not easily yield sustained positive outcomes. In Bosnia-Herzegovina, for instance, the so-called Republika Srpska remains isolated from the rest of the country by a cordon sanitaire of fear and suspicion, and has not been able to benefit significantly from the economic activity generated through international largesse. On the other hand, we should recognize that the breakdown of traditional networks and alliances often opens up possibilities for generating new positive exchanges in the post conflict era. Disintegration of Institutions and Governance Processes Already weak pre-conflict matrices of authority, accountability and transparency are frequently further eroded by conflict and replaced by a culture of impunity and corruption. The period immediately preceding a conflict frequently gives rise to the most destructive dynamics: as national cohesion and consensus break down and tensions increase, public officials begin to ignore the governance norms and structures which previously provided, at least to some degree, the “rules of the game” necessary for the effective functioning of the institutions of the state. They focus instead on their personal or parochial interests. Their ability to do so is facilitated by the degeneration of social control that expands incentives for opportunism and corruption. Unfortunately, this behavioural switch tends to be enduring, with serious implications for the legitimacy of the state. Social and political actors, seeing such pervasive corruption and parochial favoritism, further lose trust in the ability of the state to deliver just policies. The consequent increase in transaction costs becomes one of the biggest obstacles to sustained recovery as in Sierra Leone, according to some observers. The collapse or de-legitimization of governance structures contributes directly to widespread institutional breakdown—both a precipitating cause of conflict and one of its most onerous outcomes. The depreciation of social capital already carries serious economic consequences by weakening the voice and exit mechanisms that facilitate 5 market homeostasis. Conflict further severely damages property rights, compromises regulatory institutions, undermines economic policy and social insurance systems, and weakens dispute resolution mechanisms. In particular, it erodes the underlying system of rule of law, which is essential for resolving economic disputes. An almost generic feature of post-conflict situations, even in the medium-term, is the absence of a reliable judiciary that resolves disputes in a prompt and transparent manner. While the causes may vary from country to country, practically no post-conflict situation seems to have found the means to ensure a sustainable revival of the judicial system, or to protect it from political intrusion and corruption. In many instances, the situation is complicated by fundamental differences among the concerned actors on the roles and functions of the judiciary, as well as on the basic precepts of a legal code. Taken together, these pathologies paint a picture of an economy with a most severe case of fragmented and incomplete markets and imperfect information, with all the challenges that these imply. Indeed, the post-conflict economy is frequently a very large number of mini-economies with limited interaction. This structural deficiency plus pervasive informational asymmetries result in extremely high transaction costs and perverse economic outcomes. For instance, technically sound micro-credit schemes may wither in the absence of trust or local level social insurance. At the national level, even the most rudimentary macro-economic regime might not be implemented if consensus on the policy formulation process is lacking among key actors, or if the legitimacy of the decision-making authority is questioned. Similarly, sustained reform will not be possible if large swaths of the economy are dominated by illicit parallel economies, or in the absence of an agreed legal framework wherein economic disputes can be adjudicated. In short, one cannot perceive the post-conflict economy as easily amenable to management via the conventional policy levers: the market signaling mechanisms simply do not work. Similarly, it lacks the effective centralizing authority that makes the idea of pubic expenditure programming meaningful. These pathologies mean that even the best-planned and executed international assistance often does not yield sustainable results. It must be stressed too that these economic pathologies are mirrored in the social and political domains. III. Toward Sustainable Economic Recovery: Challenges Facing the Post-Conflict Leadership In pursuit of sustained economic recovery, newly established authorities must perform at least seven categories of functions as follows: create a secure environment for economic recovery; establish a coherent macroeconomic framework; institute an oversight system; diversify public investment; reconstitute social and human capital; foster decentralization, and establish rule of law. Creating a Secure Environment for Economic Recovery A core prerequisite for economic recovery is the establishment of a safe and secure environment. While limited economic activity can exist in dangerous and unstable environments, full-fledged economic development requires that people can move around safely, are not forced to waste time and energy on ensuring their own personal 6 safety, and have a degree of confidence in their ability to predict future economic developments. The latter is essential if they want to make business decisions based on estimates of risk and relatively reliable projections of economic and market trends. Thus the leadership must focus on “securing” development, through, in the short term, measures aimed at breaking the dynamics of violence (for instance through the disarmament and economic reintegration of armed groups and/or community policing arrangements), and in the long-term, strengthening justice and security, as well as implementing social and economic programmes targeting ‘high-risk’ groups or potential conflict triggers. Establishing a Macroeconomic Policy Regime No less than in a “normal” economy, a post-conflict state faces the key policy question of how to ensure macro-economic stability, generate employment and restore growth. It must therfore seek to immediately (re)establish systems for the management of public finance as well as monetary and exchange rate policy. The authorities must identify quick-yielding revenue measures and priority expenditures aimed at restoring basic infrastructure and services and jumpstarting the economy. They must re-establish a currency and create a system to manage money and credit, taking into account public and private sector financing needs. They must decide on a trade policy regime geared to restoring exports quickly. The post conflict reality imposes some very hard trade-offs. The need to control inflation and debt may dictate austerity measures, which may run counter to social policy priorities and popular expectations of a peace dividend. Further, too tight a budget can lead to deflation and unemployment, especially while private investment is still hesitant. Similarly, quick success in providing basic services is necessary to sharply differentiate war and peace, and create opportunities that encourage people to participate actively in the reconstruction process. On the other hand, scarce recovery and reconstruction funds may be more effective when used for export recovery, as this rebuilds the foreign exchange balance and makes more imported productive inputs available. Also, there are important trade-offs between the rapid resumption of public services, and cost recovery and sustainability. Quick results matter psychologically. However, it may be easier to institute and get people to accept the idea of cost recovery immediately after conflict than after a period of free services. Similarly, the new fiscal system must seek to avoid waste and gross inequities. Finally, in prioritizing public expenditures it would require special effort to avoid the easy option of simply replacing what was lost. Equally important, the authorities must avoid capitulating to the demands of the most influential groups. Otherwise, postconflict transformation would almost certainly reproduce pre-conflict inequalities and exclusion. Post-conflict macroeconomic policy must, therefore, seek also to address medium- to long-term structural adjustment and equity issues from the very beginning. These trade-offs require strategic decisions from concerned international actors as well as emerging national authorities. For instance, the traditional prescriptions for macroeconomic stability that emphasize fiscal austerity and anti-inflationary measures might not be applicable. Unless there is an abundance of resources from international assistance, domestic revenues and remittances, it may be necessary to embark on some deficit financing in order to meet immediate and critical socio-economic needs. 7 Considerable creativity may be called for in financing short-term budgetary and trade deficits and still avoiding longer-term liabilities. In addition to such obvious assistance as debt forgiveness, large grants and cheap loans from international partners, discipline and political will are needed to push for the necessary shifts from, for instance, military expenditure to health. Clearly too, it is essential to establish mechanisms for the effective and transparent utilization of proceeds from natural wealth such as oil and diamonds. Instituting an Oversight Framework for the Economy Rigorous oversight of the management of public finances and national resources and the establishment of robust systems of public control and oversight of the economy are necessary prerequisites for post-conflict economic recovery. These help to reduce the risk of imprudent or corrupt decisions. Thus, for example, financial intermediation needs supervision to avoid bad lending practices. Where large portfolios of nonperforming credit are accumulated, costly public bailouts often follow. Similarly, governments need to guard against the risk of monopolies emerging, particularly because conflict may have reduced the ability of citizens to organize as a possible countervailing force. Strong public control of revenues from natural resources is particularly critical especially where there is significant dependence on them. Some have argued that the most effective public control in these situations is to generate broad citizen participation in the management of these resources. Diversifying Public Investment Sustainable recovery will not happen unless the private sector can flourish. However, the public sector has a strong legitimate case in venturing (at least initially) into some “unorthodox” areas. First, significant public investment in rebuilding the social and physical infrastructure is known to have a “crowding-in” effect on private funds – by raising rates of return and through signaling effects. In addition, there may be a case for active state involvement in the small credit market. While it may be preferable, ultimately, to rely on private actors to provide credit to small businesses and small landholders, the private sector is unlikely to support small business credit, and the rebuilding of infrastructure, in the immediate post-conflict period. Accordingly, the public sector may have to directly provide these commodities, and/or provide extraordinary incentives. It is also important that public investment in the agricultural sector is not neglected because of its crucial role in restoring livelihoods and jump-starting exports. Activities which are vital to rehabilitating agriculture include re-claiming and de-mining land; resettling and re-training workers; repairing processing and transport equipment; reestablishing trade ties; providing access to credit; and managing foreign exchange properly. The diversification imperative also generates an opportunity to give more access to women and marginalized groups. On both demographic and equity grounds, the active participation of women in economic recovery must be nurtured. During conflict, women's contributions to economic production and livelihoods tend to increase and become more “visible”. However, post conflict, their work often reverts to being socially invisible, despite their essential contributions to the economy. Given that the 8 active male population has been greatly reduced, not nurturing women’s economic role is an unaffordable economic inefficiency. Reconstituting Social and Human Capital An essential prerequisite for economic recovery is the existence of a dynamic entrepreneurial class that can lead the development process. Unfortunately, conflict often causes a severe brain drain as highly qualified professionals flee their homes and seek haven in other countries. In order to reverse the exodus and restore the human capital deficit, governments must provide a secure environment for the return of refugees, IDPs and émigrés. A particular challenge is to overcome the resistance of their "home" communities to such return. Often, those who have remained behind during the conflict have objected to the return of people who have spent all or part of the war years abroad, especially when these people return with packages of international assistance. Moreover, steps must be taken to develop and rebuild leadership and management capacities throughout state structures. In the immediate aftermath of a conflict, reconstituting the state often begins, justifiably, with rebuilding, and reforming the police and the military, with a view to establishing discipline and civilian control. However, equal attention must be given to rebuilding a civil service and public administration that is able to resist corruption and political intrusion, and is able to facilitate key decisions without catering to parochial interests. Frequently the state looks to the military to fill this gap. While this may be a necessary short-term measure, it is not sustainable over the medium to long term. Instead, priority should be given to building a strong civilian developmental administration that can effectively regulate the private sector while generating the confidence necessary to attract investment and foster economic growth. Providing technical training to a new cadre of professionals is thus a pressing need that is often delayed or even overlooked. As a consequence, vital state capabilities are not restored. Fostering Decentralization A key issue in many post-conflict situations remains the extent to which the powers of the central government should be de-centralized in order to counter the inequities and structural imbalances that might have precipitated conflict in the first place. The rationale here is that the dispersal of key government functions to the provincial or local level allows for meaningful participation by a larger number of actors. It further reduces the stakes for a contest over centralized power. Another possible argument is that it may be easier to agree on the consensual management of resources and economic activities at the local and community level. Certainly, Somalia offers an extreme example of this. With the dispersion of national authority, local leaders have successfully developed their own mechanisms for providing basic services and security and generating significant levels of trade and economic activity. Lasting and successful decentralization can only be achieved as part of a longer-term effort to build consensus on and reform the system of governance. However, mediumterm international efforts to support decentralized economic management in countries as diverse as Sierra Leone, Somalia, and Guatemala suggest that a focus on the local 9 level does yield results in terms of sustainability of micro-enterprise, the provision of basic services, and the creation of safety nets for community members. In the mediumterm, when the ability of the national government to build its tax base and expand public services remains low, local governments are better able to collect contributions from community members—who see direct results for their money—in order to provide for basic services. However, local officials need to be supported in acquiring the systems and skills to deliver basic services in an inclusive and participatory manner, especially where such delivery was centralized prior to the conflict. Establishing the Rule of Law One particularly important sector of the state where capacities must be rebuilt is the justice sector. In the immediate post-conflict period, establishing the rule of law can assist in reducing inter-societal tensions by providing mechanisms through which perceived and real injustices can be addressed.3 Transitional courts and truth and reconciliation commissions are some of the mechanisms that have been effectively used in countries like Sierra Leone and South Africa to assist in the post-war settling of accounts. While transitional justice measures are an important first step, in many post-conflict situations they are not sufficient. Wholesale legal reform is often necessary to (re)establish the rule of law. This includes the creation of a functioning judiciary, and the establishment of a variety of mechanisms for adjudicating disputes. Experience has shown that some of the most successful reform processes have been based on developing legal frameworks that are a hybrid of western and traditional law. A functioning rule of law system is essential for the creation of a viable economy. Investors are reluctant to go where commerce is not regulated by transparent and predictable rules and undergirded by effective law enforcement. Reasonable security is of strategic concern not only to large companies and investors, but also to the small holders. They are unlikely to fully engage in productive activities if they fear that their rights to land and resources cannot be safeguarded against predatory behavior. IV Implications for International Assistance In the short run, and in the absence of the relevant capabilities on the part of the state, international actors perform many of the functions enumerated under Section III. However, the relative abundance of external resources carries a risk of eliciting dependency that must be resolutely resisted. An international “exit strategy,” or a return to normalcy, is therefore dependent on a transfer of effective decision making to national actors, and on ensuring effective coordination among the external players towards this objective. This transfer requires the re-building of the consensus building, policy formulation, and economic management capabilities of the state, taking into 3 At a recent workshop on post-conflict state-building cosponsored by UNDP and the World Bank (New York September, 2005), reformers who had played key roles in various transition stressed that deferring decisions on establishing the rule of law had negative repercussions on development and state-building in the medium to long term. 10 account the fact that the institutions that performed these functions in the pre-conflict situation were probably weak and contested. Indeed, perhaps the highest service that international assistance can provide to a post conflict country is to help reconstitute such capabilities as quickly as possible, and certainly once it seems that hostilities are likely to end.4 Several concrete steps can be taken in this regard: Supporting National Dialogue Processes: Irrespective of the genesis of a conflict, an immediate post-conflict task is creating the space for, and facilitating national dialogue.5 The challenge is to build consensus on the parameters of a new system of governance,6 essential for ensuring both stability and economic recovery, either through a new constitution or through a broader agreement than an initial pact or a truce among the warring parties. Such a process can take many forms, both modern and traditional. South Africa’s national constitutional dialogue and the Afghan constitutional loya jirga that led to the first elected government in decades are good examples. Letting National Actors Lead, Even in the Short Term: While a “national constituting process” is being facilitated, national actors should play a central role and lead where feasible, even the short-to-medium-term “needs assessments” that lead to donor pledging conferences. Such leadership strengthens their abilities for making key economic decisions. In a positive step forward, interim transitional authorities have led, despite large gaps in relevant capacities, such assessments in Afghanistan, Haiti, and Liberia. However, as transitional authorities do not necessarily represent a national consensus, some support may be needed to secure the participation of all relevant domestic actors [civil society, private sector, even (especially) former warring parties] in these assessment exercises. It is particularly important that, in their eagerness to push transition processes forward, external partners do not simply consult and make deals with a small (technocratic or political) elite. Such a move is likely to significantly disempower other important actors like parliament, civic groups, and the business community. Supporting “Process” Skills: The reality of drawn out violence is that the protagonists acquire a tendency to address issues in an aggressive, exclusionary, and authoritarian manner. It would be unrealistic to expect them to abandon these tendencies as soon as the conflict is declared formally over. Accordingly, former antagonists have to learn 4 See, for instance, “Reconstructing Governance and Public Administration for Peaceful Sustainable Development” UN, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, New York, 2004. A good example of an effective capacity-building program was a CIDA sponsored training program to develop a cadre of accountants, economists and engineers who could fill important posts in post-apartheid South Africa. 5 The Center for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS) in Washington DC has used the term “national constituting processes” to describe post-conflict efforts to build multi-stakeholder consensus. See CSIS white paper “Meeting the Challenges of Governance and Participation in Post-Conflict Settings,” August 2002. Also see, Orr, Robert, "Governing When Chaos Rules: Enhancing Governance and Participation," The Washington Quarterly - Volume 25, Number 4, Autumn 2002, pp. 139-152 6 OECD’s DAC Guidelines on “Helping Prevent Violent Conflict” (OECD, Paris 2001) lay emphasis on the strengthening pf peace processes, including through the building of partnerships between donors, the state, and civil society actors. 11 new process skills: negotiation, mediation, reaching consensus. The success of South Africa’s Mont Fleurs scenario exercise in the early 1990s and the recent efforts among participants in the Burundi peace process to reacquire skills of constructive engagement provide pointers towards addressing this gap. Institutions such as national networks of mediators and mediation commissions, often used for economic dispute resolution in more developed societies, could play a role in assisting protagonists in resolving contentious issues in a constructive manner. Supporting an “Infrastructure for Peace”: The erosion of skills for constructive mutual engagement also applies to society at large. Given residual tensions, post-conflict countries require, at all levels, an infrastructure of mechanisms, systems and processes for the resolution of day-to-day disputes before violent conflict re-emerges. Recurring violence or violent disputes can prevent the reconstitution of social capital vital for sustained economic recovery. However, appropriately equipped, religious and civic leaders, local authorities, and traditional leaders can all play constructive roles in creating an environment for the peaceful settlement of disputes. Indeed in some settings, traditional methods of resolving conflict may be the optimal approach. This environment will also make it easier for national leaders to build consensus on a new system for decision-making and governance. Linking reconciliation and economic recovery: The psychological wounds of war can prevent groups and communities from working together to build the economic capacities for lasting recovery. While special courts and tribunals target the leaders responsible for egregious war crimes and rights violations, these instruments do not address the challenges facing communities that have to receive former combatants and returnees who might have been responsible for some of their wounds, or the problems that workers from different groups and communities might encounter when brought together as colleagues in new ministries and institutions. One innovative approach to address these challenges involves “area-based development programmes,” such as those implemented in El Salvador (PRODERE), Crimea, Serbia and Montenegro, where community-led reconciliation efforts were integrated with recovery. Acquiring the Skills for Designing and Implementing Economic Policy: Competency in economic policy design, management, and implementation is also crucial. In Sierra Leone, the absence of skilled economists made it difficult for the national leaders to develop a poverty reduction strategy that met the challenging criteria established by the World Bank and International Monetary Fund. A more positive example can be found in Afghanistan. There, the “donor coordination office” created under the leadership of the transitional authorities, and staffed by qualified international and national professionals (including from the Diaspora because of the specific circumstances of Afghanistan) and led by a national, established implementation benchmarks for short-term assistance and fostered the acquisition of the required capabilities by other departments. It also harmonized guidelines for the submission of requests, and reporting on implementation, among donors. As a start in other postconflict countries, such an entity could constitute the core of an autonomous, national policy planning and implementation capacity once the international presence is drawn down. 12 Substituting international decision making, or giving international officials vetoes over domestic economic decisions, does not constitute a sustainable recovery strategy. What is required is a trained cadre of professionals who are either enticed back from the Diaspora or who are locally recruited and suitably trained. The critical functions they will perform range from the drafting of new legislation to the provision of independent oversight for public contracts and procurement. The “capacity building funds” utilized to address this competency gap in Georgia and Serbia and Montenegro constitute one innovative approach, and provide a pointer towards similar approaches in other countries. Re-establishing legitimate authority over natural resources: Lasting economic recovery requires the establishment of effective control over natural resources by peacetime authorities. Sanctions against illicit traffickers in precious commodities, and certification instruments such as the Kimberly process, are an important first step in establishing this control. However, the vital factor is the degree to which the new authorities are considered legitimate by different groups and, therefore, trusted to utilize natural wealth in the national interest. In Afghanistan, for instance, the current government, which has been established through a process considered legitimate by most Afghan groups, has had measured success in asserting its control over the country’s territory and resources. In Sierra Leone, on the other hand, the government now receives the bulk of the revenue generated from diamond mining. However, there is some disaffection due to the lack of an agreed-upon system for apportioning this revenue among different groups. There is also deep mistrust, due to endemic corruption, of the ability of the national authorities to serve as the guardian of this wealth. DRC also faces a similar challenge. The recent support provided to Sao Tome and Principe to establish a system for apportioning oil wealth on the basis of consensus and dialogue provides pointers towards similar support in other countries. These are the kinds of support that will ensure sustainable recovery. They allow the post-conflict country to acquire the capabilities critical for sound economic management and oversight. They ensure lasting recovery by nurturing a legitimate, participatory, and adaptive system for governance and economic decision-making. However, as indicated in Section II, the level of support will depend on how much of the basic institutions and decision-making processes survived the conflict. Senior officials who have led national post conflict recovery and reconstruction efforts often criticize international assistance for a lack of efficiency and effectiveness, and for the pursuit of objectives that sometimes run contrary to national interests and requirements. They claim that assistance is often not provided in true partnership with national actors and that international actors impose conditionalities that are at odds with national economic and social priorities. They also see accountability as running upwards to capitals and headquarters rather than downwards to national actors and their constituencies. Moreover, the delivery of assistance often entails high overhead and transactions costs. It imposes a heavy burden on fragile administrations with a bewildering array of reporting requirements. Quite often too, the services they provide either do not reflect local realities and solutions, or duplicate existing services. In addition, the many different types of international assistance are rarely planned within or aligned with a broader long-term strategy for progressive building national 13 capabilities. If international assistance is to effectively support countries emerging from conflict, the type and quality of support provided and the corresponding delivery mechanisms require significant improvement. 7 V. Conclusion The fundamental challenge for sustainable post-conflict recovery remains that of leadership. In the short-term, international actors often take the lead in providing both relief and recovery assistance. While this might be necessary, it is critical that national actors take the long-term lead in pulling together a system for political and economic governance. To this end they must acquire the capabilities for making key decisions on economic reform and the allocation of resources. It is particularly critical that national actors acquire this capability by the time the international role is drawn down. Some of the requirements of external assistance that have been identified, include support for “national constituting processes”; building an “infrastructure for peace” at the national and local levels; supporting key stakeholders in acquiring the relevant process skills; building capacities for economic management and the delivery of basic services; building the capacity of communities to sustain local economic initiatives, and providing for alternative adjudication of disputes while judicial reform is undertaken. Taken together, these measures will amount to significant capacity for national actors wherein they can make their own decisions on critical national issues. Currently, the design of international support for peace building usually does not target the building of such capacities. In peacekeeping operations, the focus is generally on humanitarian and short-term recovery activities for the duration of the operation. Issues of capacity are addressed in an ad hoc manner once the draw down of the international presence approaches. Because it takes time, the task of building such capacities should commence in the immediate aftermath of a conflict, alongside the provision of short-term humanitarian and recovery support. In addition to providing the basis for longer-term recovery, this capacity building can also have a positive shortterm political effect. By enabling the key actors to begin to engage each other on a more constructive and pragmatic basis, they may actually provide greater longevity to accords and cease-fire arrangements, which might otherwise unravel because of continuing fears and mistrust. The key message of this paper is that development assistance must be more systematically integrated from the earliest stage of post conflict support. For instance: Humanitarian actors provide short-term relief to individuals and communities, including returning refugees and IDPs. Using the window of this assistance, development actors such as the UN Development Group (UNDG) can begin to work with communities to build their capacities to sustain in the longer-term the economic activities generated through this short-term support. For instance, communities can be supported to more 7 There was remarkable convergence around these views among participants at the state-building workshop 14 effectively use existing resources, and to engage different groups in cooperative entrepreneurship. As a result, they may become better able to integrate returning former combatants, refugees, and IDPs in a sustainable manner. International peacekeeping operations as well as special purpose coalitions can establish security in the short-run through the disarmament and demobilization of former combatants, reviving and reforming the logistical and operational capacities of the security sector, and establishing civilian oversight of this sector. Concurrently, development actors can begin to assist with the development of a comprehensive framework for rule of law, first by supporting alternative means to adjudication, and then helping to build a capable judiciary once consensus has been obtained among key actors on the parameters of a system for governance. Multilateral development banks (MDBs) and international financial institutions (IFIs) may assist transitional authorities to revive public finances as well as institutions for economic management. Working with these institutions, development actors such as UNDP can assist transitional authorities in the preparation of Post-Conflict Needs Assessments (PCNAs). They can bring real value to these processes by supporting national actors to acquire the capacities to deliberate on, and participate in the preparation and implementation of these strategies. In fact, the UN Development Group, in collaboration with the World Bank, has developed participatory methodologies for “interim needs assessments” that support national actors in identifying critical recovery needs during the transitional period. Political support for peace building in the short run often involves mediation to obtain a break in the fighting, as well as follow-on mediation to ensure longevity for the cease-fire or accord. It also includes support for the constitution of transitional authorities, and for post-conflict elections heralding the formation of a government. Alongside this political engagement, development actors can assist the emergence of a viable longer-term framework for governance by providing technical support for “national constituting processes”, and by helping national and local actors develop an “infrastructure for peace” wherein disputes can be resolved peacefully before they erupt into violence. Human rights support in the immediate post-conflict period often involves systematic monitoring to ensure that parties to the conflict avoid human rights violations, and assistance for “truth and reconciliation” processes as public catharsis to help a country move beyond the agony of prolonged violence. Concurrently, development actors can help ensure the full and lasting impact of a reconciliation process on the ground by assisting national and local actors in acquiring the “process” skills for constructive engagement. Specifically, they can help these actors, especially civic 15 associations, traditional leaders, and women’s groups, acquire the skills and tools through which consensus can be built around divisive issues, and ways found for working together on common priorities despite the schisms generated by violent conflict. Bilateral actors and donors, especially members of “friends’ groups”, bring critical resources, from support for security sector reform to humanitarian financial assistance, to bear on a post-conflict situation. Development actors can help ensure that this assistance goes beyond a “donorrecipient” relationship to one of partnership based on common interests. While the commitment of a lead donor is critical, the multilateral component is indispensable. It brings with it the neutrality and trust that the most sensitive tasks require. Peace-building strategies should therefore involve the full participation of development actors from the very start of international engagement. While the emphasis of international support may vary over time, there are no distinct or discrete phases to post-conflict transitions. Rather, in each case a country and its people have to undertake several Herculean tasks concurrently in the face of extraordinary constraints. Humanitarian, livelihoods, human rights, and governance issues must be addressed simultaneously, even as the country struggles to lay the foundation for a well functioning economy. Emphasis must, therefore, be placed, from the beginning on building the national capacities to initiate and sustain economic recovery. Development actors, and particularly UNDP, have a critical support role in this endeavour. 16