WHAT DOES REALLY DRIVE THE STOCK MARKET? Accounting for the last 50 years. Michele Boldrin Adrian Peralta-Alva April 21, 2003 1 Long-run behavior of the stock of capital in relation to output We ask: is it consistent with ANY model of capital accumulation/valuation? We look at two measures: stock market valuations of firms which own such capital (X) market valuation of the physical capital, at replacement values (K) 2 Market value of corporate equity/Gross product of corporate business 2.15 1.95 1.75 1.55 1.35 1.15 0.95 0.75 0.55 0.35 1951 1956 1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 3 3.5 3.2 2.9 2.6 2.3 2 1.7 1.4 1.1 0.8 0.5 1951 1956 1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 Corporate capital stock / Gross product of corporate business Market value of corporate equity/Gross product of corporate business Market value of corporate equity + debt/Gross product of corporate business 4 Averages over long periods K/Y X/Y 1951-60: 1.92 1.40 1960-72: 1.72 1.61 1973-85: 2.00 0.82 1985-01: 1.67 2.5 Correlation(K,X) = -.73 Average X/K = .92 5 This makes no sense in the standard model In fact, it is hardly consistent with any model in which firms are made up by matching together physical capital, K, workers, L, and some kind of enterpreneurial or organizational factor, Z. In this case one would expect that X = Value (K+L+Z) > K Instead, in the data, the long-run evidence is that X = Value (K+L+Z) < K 6 ln [Gross product of corporate business(per capita)] 5.4 5.2 5 4.8 4.6 4.4 4.2 4 1951 1956 1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 7 Tobin’s q = X/K Market Value of Corporate equity / Replacement value of corporate capital 2.2 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 1952 1956 1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 8 It seems that, in the long-run, we have q = X/K < 1 which has interesting implications for people that like the cost-ofadjustment model … - costs of adjustment are negative, but wildly oscillating over time - organizational capital is also negative most of the time, but it was positive in the last two decades, and in the 1960s 9 Look at K/Y and X/Y separately. Are there models consistent with each of their behavior, independent from the other? To a first approximation, the answer is Yes. The ratio K/Y seems consistent with the standard capital-accumulation model if one allows for sudden and unexpected changes in underlying TFP growth rate. The ratio X/Y seems consistent (but to a lesser extent) with the Gordon/Lucas evaluation model, with drastic changes in the expected growth rate of dividends. 10 Per capita Gross Product of Corporate Business (Growth factors, relative to trend) 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 1951 1955 1959 1963 1967 1971 1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 11 Look more carefully at the two separate explanations. TFP PATTERNS 1960-1972 3.0% 1973-1985 1.1% -- 1.4% 1994-2000 2.5% -- 3.0% CORPORATE GDP PATTERNS 1960-1972 3.1% 1973-1985 2.3% 1994-2000 3.1% 12 Explaining K/Y movement with TFP movements u discount factor 0.96 , depreciation rate 0.08, c1 1 ; y A1 K L1 1 share of capital risk aversion 0.35, 0.7 In this model, K X , so no chances of explaining the differential behavior of the two ratios. t 1 t Concentrate on K/Y ratio as a function of , the growth rate of TFP factor A. K Y (1 r ) (1 ) 13 Results of simple calibration Normalize the K/Y ratio during the 1960-1972 period to equal one 1973-1985 1994-2001 MODEL (K/Y) = 1.14 (K/Y) = 1.12 DATA (K/Y) = 1.14 (K/Y) = 0.95 14 Explaining X/Y movements with profits movements Notice that what makes X/Y behave differently from K/Y must be a relative price effect. We call this the price of installed, or matched, capital, to keep the reference with the cost of adjustment model. Think about what this “price” could be in reality. Two sectors? Matching? Enterpreneurial rents? Animal spirits? Risk? Use the simplest model of dividend evaluations, with dividend set equal to the share of capital in corporate income. 15 The simplest model is Gordon’s which gives Pt 1 Dt r Dt t (1 )t In a general equilibrium context (Lucas’ tree model) we have r (1 ) So, the growth rate of TFP has a contrasting effect on the relative valuation of installed capital, depending on risk aversion. For risk aversion levels in (0,1), P increases with TFP growth. Question: if TFP growth rate drops as it did post 1972, do we get a realistic drop in P? 16 Percentage change in the price of capital 40 30 20 10 0 -10 -20 -30 -40 -50 -60 -70 -80 -90 -100 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 17 Question: if TFP growth rate increases as it did post 1992, do we get a realistic increase in P? Yes, No … It depends on how large the 1998-2000 bubble component was … Going back to the pre 1972 growth rate of corporate capital income gives us an almost two-fold increase in the price of capital, relative to its 1973-1985 level. But not a threefold! 18 Other approaches in the literature - q-theory … does not work - Hall organizational capital … a negative organizational capital? - McGratten-Prescott: taxes … timing is completely wrong, and cannot explain the differential behavior of x and k - IT-revolution, Jovanovic et al. Cannot explain behavior of x/k, cannot explain the stagnation from 1975 to 1986, cannot explain the big increase post 1986, cannot explain the fact that the value of equities in private and public firms behaved similarly post 1974, cannot explain the behavior of consumption since 1974 … - Increased uncertainty, two sector, putty-clay, etc …. Nothing seems to work! 19 1.11 1.1 1.09 1.08 1.07 1.06 1.05 1.04 1.03 1.02 1.01 1 0.99 0.98 0.97 0.96 0.95 0.94 0.93 1950 1954 1958 1962 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 Consumption per capita (excluding durables, relative to its 1950-70 trend) Moving Average of Consumption per capita (excluding durables, relative to its 1950-70 trend) 20 200201 200001 199801 199601 199401 199201 199001 198801 198601 198401 198201 198001 197801 197601 197401 1.2 197201 197001 196801 196601 196401 196201 196001 195801 195601 195401 195201 Total credit market assets held by the rest of the world (Relative to its 1952-71 trend) 197301 1.1 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 21 Federal funds rate 2001 1999 1997 1995 1993 1991 1989 1987 1985 1983 1981 1979 1977 1975 1973 1971 1969 1967 1965 1963 1961 1959 1957 1955 Interest rates 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 AA corporate bonds 22 - New listing effect: The market value of corporate equity to gross product of corporate business may change if the output produced in public firms, relative to that of private firms, changes. The value of private firms and the value of publicly traded ones has changed in the same proportion for the last 50 years. Thus, a measure of this effect would be the difference between the aggregate ratio VS and those for public and private firms t t Figures below illustrate that this effect can account for very little of the movements in the market ratio x from 1960 to 1985. From 1985 to 1999 the new listing effect becomes more important. Relative to their 1960-72 average, the market value of public and private firms had increased 50% by 1999, while VS roughly doubled. t t Thus, one half of the total increase in the market ratio x that started in the mid 1980's can by accounted by the new listing effect. But this leaves all the rest still unexplained. 23 Market value of corporate equity (Ratios relative to their 1960-1972 average) 2.2 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 1951 1954 1957 1960 1963 1966 1969 1972 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 Market value of corporate equity/Gross product of corporate business Market value of corporate equity/Corporate business receipts 24 2 1.9 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 1951 1954 1957 1960 1963 1966 1969 1972 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 Market value of domestic firms listed in compustat/Sales of domestic firms listed in compustat Market value of privately held firms / Sales (non traded, aprox calculation) Market value of corporate equity/Corporate business receipts 25 Are factor share really constant? Many people claim they are. Aggregate, economy-wide data are often used, including the public sector, small firms, etc, which are not valued by the stock market, But evidence is mixed when you look more carefully sector by sector. Evidence that factor shares do move quite a bit over time becomes strong when you zoom into the corporate sector. 26 CHANGES IN THE CAPITAL'S SHARE OF CORPORATE INCOME ( Average 1960-72=1 ) 1.06 1.05 1.04 1.03 1.02 1.01 1 0.99 0.98 0.97 0.96 0.95 0.94 1950 1953 1956 1959 1962 1965 1968 1971 1974 1977 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 27 Conclusion We seem to have a problem here. In fact, we seem to have a huge problem. Maybe markets are crazy … but lots of evidence suggest they are not Maybe markets are hyper-sensitive, and a bit myopic. Possibly so. … and, maybe, income distribution does matter for the stock market. 28