Solution Key: Homework 3 Economics 101 Chapters 7 & 8 1) a) Y/L = (K/L)1/2. b) Y = 20,000; labor productivity (and not marginal productivity) is defined as the ratio of output to labor (Y/L), labor productivity from per capita production function is Y/L= (40,000/10,000)1/2 = 2, to find labor productivity from the original production function first calculate Y = (40,000)1/2 (10,000)1/2 = (200)(100) = 20000, so Y/L = 20000/10000 = 2; yes c) From sf(K/L*) = dK/L* we have saving rate s = 0.2. d) Consumption is C = (1-s)Y and consumption per worker is C/L = (1-s)Y/L = 1.6. 2) a) Country A will have the higher level of output per worker (n + d)K/L f(K/L) (Y/L)A (Y/L) B sAf(K/L) sBf(K/L) (K/L*) B (K/L*) A K/L b) In the steady state the growth rate of output per worker will be zero in both country A and B 3) a) According to the convergence hypothesis, both the U.S. and China should converge to the same steady state level of output per person and then both stop growing. So both disparity in levels and growth rates should disappear in time. b) If China has a higher saving rate than the U.S., this would tend to make China’s steady state levels of capital and output per worker higher than the U.S. levels. But per capita growth rates still will eventually reach zero in both countries. c) If China has a higher population growth rate, it would tend to make China’s steady state levels of capital and output per worker lower than the U.S. levels. Per capita growth rates still go to zero. d) In this case, the levels of output per person in the two countries will converge to each other, and the rates of growth in per-person income both will converge to the rate of technological progress. e) With this endogenous growth model, the growth rates will remain constant at their current levels. So China’s level of output per person would eventually surpass that of the U.S. 4) a. The destruction of some of the country’s capital stock in a war would have no effect on the steady state, because there has been no change in s, f, n, or d. Instead, k is reduced temporarily, but equilibrium forces eventually drive k to the same steady-state value as before. b. Immigration raises n from n1 to n2 in the figure below. The rise in n lowers steady-state k, leading to a lower steady-state output per worker. c. The rise in energy prices reduces the productivity of capital per worker. This causes sf(k) to shift down from sf1(k) to sf2(k) in figure below. The result is a decline in steady-state k. Steady-state output per worker falls for two reasons: (1) each unit of capital has a lower productivity, and (2) steady-state k is reduced y (n2 + d)k (n1+ d)k sf(k) (n + d)k sf1 (k) sf2(k) k k d. A temporary rise in s has no effect on the steady-state equilibrium. e. Let’s make a distinction between population N and labor force L. The increase in the size of the labor force L does not affect the growth rate of the labor force, so there is no impact on the steady-state capital-labor ratio K/L or on the output per worker Y/L. However, because larger labor force implies higher total out put Y. Therefore with an increase in the fraction of working people in a population, national income and income per capita Y/N increases. 5a) In a solow growth model a rise in the rate of capital depreciation shifts up the (n + d)k line from (n + d1)k to (n + d2)k. The equilibrium steady-state capital-labor ratio, output per worker ratio is lower, so consumption per worker is lower There is no effect on the long-run growth rate of the total capital stock, because in the long run the capital stock must grow at the same rate (n) as the labor force grows, so that the capital-labor ratio is constant. b) In an endogenous growth model, the growth rate of output is Y/Y = sA – d, so the rise in the depreciation rate reduces the economy’s growth rate. Similarly, the growth rate of capital equals /K = sA – d, which also declines when the depreciation rate rises. Since consumption is constant fraction of output, its growth rate declines as well. So the increase in the depreciation rate reduces the long-run growth rate of the capital stock, as well as long-run capital, output, and consumption per worker. 6) a) False. Standard of living improves if income per capita grows. b) False. Since 1950 only OECD countries had converging GDP per capita. c) False. Increase in saving rate increases capital accumulation and hence the growth rate. But as capital labor ratio reaches the new steady state per capita growth rate converges to the rate of technological change. e) True. f) True. g) False. Evidence shows that there is convergence among OECD and some Asian countries. There is evidence of convergence among in states in the U.S. But is little evidence of convergence among other countries (i.e. countries in Africa, the Middle East and most countries in Latin America). h) Convergence among countries is mainly the result of technological progress. 7) Some poor countries grow more rapidly than affluent ones and some less. There is no general rule; the same for country size. 8) Any policy that leads to an improvement in efficiency can increase economic growth. Less developed countries can increase their growth by capital accumulation and acquisition of the best technology from advanced economies. The former can be achieved by high investment (and thus high saving rate) and the latter with high investment and high exports of manufactured goods. 9) Need to know what government expenditure is cut following the tax cut. Depending of the type and the timing of government the cut could hurt or help economic growth rate. 10) Increased depreciation of capital resulting from low-quality investment in the past reduces efficiency and thus the economic growth. Both type of depreciations lead to lower steady state level of k and y and lower transitory growth rate. In endogenous model the effect of lower efficiency on growth depends on saving rates. The higher the saving rate (and thus the investment), the higher the cost of low quality investment