ANTI-COMPETITIVE REGULATION OF PRIMARY SECTOR DAMAGES PRODUCTIVITY OF THE WHOLE ECONOMY Regulations that reduce competition in ‘upstream’ industries reduce productivity growth in ‘downstream’ industries, such as the manufacturing sector. That is the central conclusion of new research by Renaud Bourlès and colleagues, to be presented at the Royal Economic Society’s 2012 annual conference. Their study looks at policies, rules and regulations in 15 OECD countries between 1984 and 2007, broken down by sector. The research suggests that if competition in the primary sector is stifled by any measures, the prices they charge to their clients – firms in the manufacturing sector – will be higher. This in turn will lower the margins in the manufacturing sector and will reduce the incentives for manufacturing firms to increase productivity. As a result, multi-factor productivity – a measure of how effective companies are at using their inputs to produce one unit of output – in the manufacturing sector drops. The authors also find that the number of firms affected by anti-competitive practices in the manufacturing sector has increased over the period studied. Within this, the negative effects are strongest for the most technologically advanced companies. Raising multi-factor productivity is widely seen as essential for generating economic growth. The much-publicised difference in economic fortunes of euro zone countries, such as Germany and Greece, is at least partly caused by the different levels of overall productivity in these economies. More… This study analyses the effect of anti-competitive regulations in non-manufacturing industries (‘upstream’ industries) on the productivity growth of all industries that use the non-manufacturing inputs (‘downstream’ industries). It finds clear evidence that anticompetitive regulations in upstream sectors curb multi-factor productivity (MFP) growth downstream. These effects are nonlinear and depend on distance to technological frontier (defined as the most productive country in each sector). They are strongest for observations (country/sector/period triads) that are close to the global technological frontier, but remain generally negative for a large share of the data. Interestingly, the share of observations whose MFP growth suffers from anticompetitive regulations increased over time. This could be due to increased integration of the world economy in the context of the diffusion of new technologies. Measured at the average distance to frontier and average level of anti-competitive regulations, the effect of increasing competition by instantaneously and completely eliminating such regulations is to increase MFP growth by between 1% and 1.5% per year depending on the period covered. This is of course a purely illustrative case because it would represent an unrealistically ambitious reform agenda. More realistic scenarios, in which each country’s regulations are aligned on actual best practices, suggest smaller but still sizeable yearly gains in MFP growth. Competition – and policies affecting it – has been found to be an important determinant of productivity growth in recent empirical research. Evidence has generally supported the idea that competitive pressures are a driver of productivity-enhancing innovation and adoption. Most empirical studies of the competition-growth link focused on competitive conditions within each sector (or market) as drivers of firm or industry-level productivity enhancements. Yet to the extent that expected rents from innovation or technology adoption are underlying efforts to improve efficiency relative to competitors, focusing on within-sector competition misses an important part of the story. Indeed, these rents, and the corresponding within-sector incentives to improve productivity, may be reduced by lack of competition in sectors that sell intermediate inputs that are necessary to production. In other words, if there is market power in these upstream sectors and if firms in downstream industries have to negotiate terms and conditions of their contracts with suppliers, part of the rents expected downstream from adopting best-practice techniques will be grabbed by intermediate input providers. This in turn will reduce incentives to improve efficiency and curb productivity in downstream sectors, even if competition may be thriving there. Moreover, lack of competition in upstream sectors can also generate barriers to entry that curb competition in downstream sectors. For example, tight licensing requirements in retail trade or transport can narrow access to distribution channels. The influence of competition in upstream sectors for productivity improvements downstream is likely to be particularly relevant in developed countries where most industries are increasingly involved in global competition. Higher costs (or lower quality) of intermediate inputs indirectly frustrate efforts of firms that purchase these goods and services to improve efficiency in order to escape competition, because the expected returns from such efforts are shrunk. This study measures industry-level efficiency improvements and distance to frontier through a multifactor productivity (MFP) index. Using OECD industry statistics, the researchers construct MFP measures for 15 OECD countries and 20 sectors over the 1984-2007 period. They proxy competition upstream with detailed time series information on policies, rules and regulations that generate entry barriers upstream industries and measure the importance of these barriers for all industries that use the non-manufacturing inputs (‘downstream’ industries) by means of input-output relationships. ENDS ‘Do product market regulations in upstream sectors curb productivity growth? Panel data evidence for OECD countries’ by Renaud Bourlès, Gilbert Cette, Jimmy Lopez, Jacques Mairesse and Giuseppe Nicoletti