1 Sophia N. Antonopoulou THE PROCESS OF GLOBALISATION AND CLASS TRANSFORMATION IN THE WEST Article published in Democracy & Nature, Vol, 6, No 1, March 2000 2 THE PROCESS OF GLOBALISATION AND CLASS TRANSFORMATION IN THE WEST The post-war period marks a new stage of development of the international capitalist system, with its climax the current trend of globalisation. Western society is gradually rejecting its traditional characteristics, entering a new era of transition towards an as yet unclear future. Some hasten to salute the new epoch as one of unprecedented opportunities for economic growth and global communication, which the new technologies offer, the vision being the so called “global village”. Others see in these developments, as we do, the culmination of the most ruthless characteristics of capitalism, in a society which sees the welfare state as a useless luxury and recognizes almost no other principle of economic and social organization than the free play of the market forces and the unbridled antagonism, that the new philosophy of neo-liberalism and the policies of economic deregulation inaugurated. Moreover, international financial speculation turns the world into a vast global casino, sanctioned by governments, technocrats and bankers throughout the globe. Present day Western society is a society of uncertainty and agony for the ordinary man, the jobless, the elderly, the weak; the society of the two-thirds. At the other end of the spectrum, are famine and diseases for the masses of the Third World. But let us examine the social and economic characteristics of the new era and the processes of capitalist development, within which they were borne. When we have analysed these wider processes, we will come to focus on the new class structure, which these processes have brought to the fore. 3 I. The Global System The post-war period marks a new stage of development of the international capitalist system, characterised by the worldwide decentralisation of production and finance, the preeminence of financial speculation and information technology. In what follows we attempt to grasp these developments as manifestations of one and the same process of capitalist development, the so-called process of globalisation. During the post-war period, the export of capital from the advanced capitalist countries to the rest of the world has increasingly assumed the form of direct, and mainly industrial, investment undertaken by multinational corporations. This developed on a significant scale especially during the 1960s and onwards, and has led to the rapid industrialisation of the peripheral countries involved in this process. Indeed, several countries of the periphery have been drawn by multinational capital in the international market as industrial producers1. The establishment of industrial plants in peripheral countries by multinational corporations during this period was, in a number of instances, accompanied by the parallel process of the shutting down of corresponding plants in the traditional industrial sites of the advanced capitalist countries. Thus, taking into account both sides of the phenomenon, we may say that it amounted to the relocation of part of industrial production away from the advanced capitalist countries, or the ‘center’ of the system, to the Third World countries, or the ‘periphery’2, as considerable amounts 1 .See W.K. Paik, United States Relations With the Newly Industrialising Countries in the Pacific Basin, (New York and London : Garland, 1997). C. Bina and B.Yaghmaian, “Post-war Global Accumulation and the Transnationalisation of Capital”, Capital and Class, No 43, 1991. G.J.R. Linge, , (ed), Peripheralisation and Industrial Change, (London : Croom Helm, 1988). F.E.I. Hamilton (ed), Industrialisation in Developing and Peripheral Regions, (London : Croom Helm, 1986). 2 . By the end of the 1970s, the effects of this process, which has been described as the “deindustrialisation” of the central capitalist countries, were acutely felt. See G. Matsumoto, “Deindustialisation in the U.K.: A comparative Analysis With Japan”, International Review of Applied Economics, 10(2), 1996. N.Crafts, “Deindustrialisation and Economic Growth”, Economic Journal, 106 (434), 1996. B, Coriat and P.Petit “Deindustrialisation and Tertiarization : Towards a New Economic Regime ?”, in A. Amin and M. Dietrich (eds) “Towards a New Europe ?”, (Aldershot : 4 of European and American industrial capital migrated to the peripheral countries in pursuit of cheap labour and so-called tax heavens, on the one hand, and penetration of protected markets, on the other3. As multinational corporations have developed into the centres of organisation and control of world industrial production, selected branches of production, or selected phases of the manufacturing process of one product, are assigned to each country according to the ‘comparative advantage’ of each. This process has been greatly facilitated by modern technological developments, and made possible by cheap transport. Together these have rendered feasible the subdivision of the production process to sub-operations that can be assigned and carried out independently in different geographical locations. This geographical dispersal of manufacturing production may also be described as the decentralisation of the production process worldwide4. However, the design, engineering and marketing of the production units located all over the world, are separated and concentrated in the headquarters of the multinationals. Within this global organisation of production, even small firms worldwide, formally independent, are in fact integrated into the network Edward Elgar,1991). B. Blueston and B.Harrison, The Deindustrialisation of America: Plant Closing, Community Abandonment and the Dismantling of Basic Industry, (New York : Basic Books, 1982). 3 . A characteristic case of the mobility of multinational capital in pursuit of cheap labour is the American telecommunications company AT&T, that between 1970 and 1980 moved its telephone assembly production from Louisiana USA to Singapore and by the late 1980s switched again this time to Thailand. See A. Hoogvelt, Globalisation and the Postcolonial World, (London : Macmillan, 1997), p.126. 4 . For some spectacular cases, see A.Hoogvelt, Globalisation and the Postcolonial World, pp. 125-8. For the internationalisation of production see also, J. Kregel, Capital Flows: Globalisation of Production and Financing Development, (UNCTAD Review, O (0), 1994). Also, United Nations Conference on Trade Development; Programme on Transnational Corporations, World Investment Report 1993 : Transnational Corporations and Integrated International Production, (U.N. Sales No E.93. II. A. 14, New York : United Nations Publications, 1993). For an earlier exposition of this process see the classic work : F.Frobel, et al., The New International Division of Labour, (Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1980). 5 of the multinationals, through subcontracting, licensing and similar agreements 5. But decentralisation of production also takes place within the boundaries of one and the same national economy, where formerly integrated plants are increasingly putting out the manufacture of parts and components to subcontractors6. In this transnational organisation of production, the different plants in their different geographical locations form mere links in chains of operations performed by multinational corporations on a world level. In other words, the level of integration of the production process is no longer the national economy, but the multinational corporation functioning on a global basis. While in previous epochs an international market of commodities existed, today a global system of closely interconnected production units has been created as well. But while production itself is decentralised worldwide, its management and control is centralised in a few headquarters in the advanced capitalist countries. The formation of an international market for financial capital parallels this process7. This global system of production, commerce and finance, controlled by the advanced capitalist countries, is, according to our definition, the economic base of globalisation.8 5 . See A. Hoogvelt, Globalisation and the Postcolonial World, p.127, where a characteristic example is described: “The NIKE footwear company with annual sales of nearly $4 billion subcontracts 100 per cent of its goods production. NIKE itself currently employs only about 9000 people, while nearly 75000 people are employed by its independent subcontractors located in different countries mostly in the Third World……The subcontractors are all networked to the parent company”. 6 . See J.Thoburn and M. Takashina, Industrial Subcontracting in the UK and Japan, (Avenbury : Aldershot, 1992). 7 . See L. Oxelheim, Financial Markets in Transition: Globalization, Investment and Economic Growth, (London and New York : Routledge, 1996). E.Helleiner, States and the Re-emergence of Global Finance : From Bretton Woods to the 1990s, (Ithaca and London : Cornell Univ. Press, 1994). R. O’Brien, Global Financial Integration : The End of Geography, (London : Pinter, 1992). 8 . Cf. B. Fine, et al., “Addressing the World Economy : Two Steps Back”, Capital and Class, No 67, 1999. Globalisation, which became in the 1990s the explanatory concept of social change, has been defined in various ways. See I.Douglas, “Globalisation and the End of the State ?”, New Political Economy, vol. 2, No 1, 1997. R.J. Barry Jones, “Globalisation versus Community”, New Political Economy, vol. 2, No 1, 1997. P.Hirst and G.Thompson,, Globalizaton in Question, (London : Polity Press, 1996). J.Diskin, and T.Koechlin, “Liberal Political Economy and Global Capitalism”, Review of Radical Political Economics, vol. 26, No 3, 1994. R. Mansel, “European Telecommunications, Multinational Enterprises, and the Implication of ‘Globalisation’”, International Journal of Political Economy, vol. 23, No 4, 1994. For the term “internationalisation” instead of that of “globalisation”, as more pertinent to disclose the rule and predominance of the market in the present day global economic 6 The process of globalisation has been greatly boosted by the liberalisation of the markets, the gradual removal of all sorts of “restrictions” upon the free movement of capital and commodities worldwide, especially during the last two decades, when no-liberalism and monetarism have been universally adopted9. Integral to the worldwide mobility of capital today, is the preeminence of financial speculation in the advanced capitalist countries, especially in Europe, the USA and Japan. According to the Bank of International Settlements, speculation in buying and selling tradeable currencies reached in 1998 the volume of USD 1,5 trillion on average daily. This means that on an annual basis this volume surpassed USD 300 trillion. In the same year the value of world trade reached the volume of USD 5,3 trillion10. In other words, the turnover of speculation in the international currency markets was more than fifty times greater than the volume of world trade in 1998. In this context, it is not accidental that today the most important factor determining exchange rates are transactions in the international currency markets rather than trade or service transactions11. In 1997 the value of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of the USA reached the volume of USD 7,8 trillion, while that of the OECD countries as a whole reached the volume of USD 34,6 trillion12. That is to say, the turnover of speculataion in the international currency markets was more than thirty five times greater than the value of the GDP of the USA and more than eight times greater than the value of the GDP of the OECD countries as a whole in 1997. The volume of speculation in the international currency markets grows from year to year by leaps and bounds. Thus, according to the Bank of International Settlements, this volume reached the amount of and political situation, see T.Fotopoulos, Towards an Inclusive Democracy, (London and New York : Cassel, 1997) pp. 3-60. 9 . See T.Fotopoulos, Towards an Inclusive Democracy, esp. pp. 33-36 and 41-46. 10 . IMF, International Financial Statistics, (April, 1999). 11 . See H.Ungerer, “The European Monetary System and the International Monetary System”, Journal of Common Market Studies, v. xxxvii, 3, 1989, p.235. 7 USD 590 billion on average daily in 1989, USD 820 billion in 1992, USD 1,19 trillion in 1995 and USD 1,5 trillion in 1998. Thus, between 1989 and 1998 it grew by 254%. Speculation in equities and bonds is added to that in currencies. In 1995 the value of equity trading in the European stock exchange markets amounted to 2,7 trillion ECU, while that of bonds amounted to 14,9 trillion ECU13. In the same year the foreign trade of the European Union reached the volume of 1,1 trillion ECU14. It is also striking that a growing proportion of capital flows from the advanced capitalist countries to the developing countries in the 1990s represents “portofolio investment”, that is speculation, as compared to foreign direct investment (FDI). Thus in 1994, net portofolio investment from the advanced capitalist countries in the so called emerging capital markets of the developing countries reached the amount of USD 84 billion, and FDI the amount of USD 70 billion. Portofolio investment may change significantly from year to year, according to the conjuncture in the world capital markets. In 1996 the relation between speculation and FDI reversed. Nevertheless, portofolio investment reached the amount of USD 45 billion as compared to USD 91 billion of FDI 15. Therefore, financial speculation has attained unprecedented dimensions in the advanced capitalist countries, putting the stamp of parasitism on the economies of the West. This is precisely the base of what has been described as casino capitalism16. As several countries of the periphery are being drawn by multinational capital into the international market as industrial producers, and manufacturing production is decentralised worldwide, the traditional division of the world between a relatively few 12 . OECD, National Accounts, vol. I (1999). . Federation of European Stock Exchange, European Stock Exchange Statistics, (December, 1995). 14 . Eurostat, External and Intra-European Union Trade, No 6 (1997). 15 . M. Knight, “Developing countries and the Globalization of Financial Markets”, IMF Working Paper, 98/105, 1998, p.6. 13 8 countries specialising in industrial production, with the rest of the world concentrating on agricultural and raw materials production appears no longer valid. However, while this has been widely recognised17, the concrete content of the new international division of labour has not yet been defined. Our analysis so far, makes it possible to proceed to a definition according to which, the international capitalist system is gradually moving towards a division of the world between a few countries mainly preoccupied with the economic management and control of the world capitalist system, as well as with production of knowledge and technology, tending in the long run to retain mainly the production of industrial products with a high content of advanced technology, and the rest of the world involved mainly in raw-materials, agricultural and industrial mass production. It is worth quoting here the words of a German manufacturer, which express in clear and practical language the above trends: “…What we need is the consensus of all those involved –government, trade unions and firms- on the economic benefits of overseas involvement by firms…In the long run we can only retain highly sophisticated technology in the Federal Republic, that is, the manufacture of products with a high technology content. Simple mass production will become unprofitable here as 16 . See S.Strange, Casino Capitalism, (Manchester : Manchester Univ. Press, 1997). R. McIntyre, “The Political Economy and Class Analysis of International Capital Flows: US Industrial Capital in the 1970s and 1980s”, Capital and Class, No 43, 1991. 17 . See A.Hoogvelt, Globalization and the Postcolonial World. H.Mittelman, “Rethinking the International Division of Labour in the Context of Globalisation”, Third World Quarterly, vol. 16, 1995. A.C.Robles, French Theories of Regulation and Conceptions of the International Division of Labour, (London : Macmillan, 1994). S.Folke, et al., South-south Trade and Development : Manufacturers in the New International Division of Labour, (New York : St. Martins Press, 1992). G. van Liemt, Bridging the Gap :Four Newly Industrialising Countries and the Changing International Division of Labour, (Geneva : International Labour Office, 1988). J.Henderson and M. Castells, (eds), Global Restructuring and Territorial Development, (Sage, 1978). R. Jenkins, “Divisions Over the International Division of Labour”, Capital and Class, No 22, 1984. F. Frobel, et al., The New International Division of Labour. 9 wage costs are becoming too high. Everything under this threshold will have to be transferred abroad”18. However, this division of the world is currently only a trend. Whether it will mature into a clear-cut division understandably depends on a number of economic, social and political factors and processes. For instance, if the working masses in the peripheral countries succeed in organising themselves politically and claim better terms of remunaretion and conditions of labour, then as far as labour cost is concerned, the ‘comparative advantage’ of the peripheral countries will be diminished. But under the present circumstances this is extremely difficult, given the totalitarian regimes in power in many peripheral countries, on the one hand, and the widespread unemployment that scourges these same countries, on the other. Indeed, in most of the peripheral countries, unemployment creates an almost inexhaustible reserve army of millions of people struggling for sheer survival. As capital is accumulated on an ever increasing scale in the centre of the system, the world is more and more divided beween a few countries appropriating capital, means of production, and the rest of the world appropriating mere labour. The transfer of surplus value from the periphery to the centre more and more takes the form of an immediate hiring of peripheral labour by metropolitan capital invested in the periphery. The capitalist mode of production having expanded to the whole world, has now reproduced on a global scale its fundamental contradiction - namely, the separation of the producer from the means of production, the division between capital and labour. II. The Role of Information Technology in the Functioning of Global Capital. 18 . Cited by F. Frobel et al., The New International Division of Labour, p.282. 10 The execution of economic management and control on a world scale needs precisely information technology, that is, computers and modern high-tech telecommunications, which embrace the whole globe with an effective network and allow rapid transmission of information worldwide19. The transmission of information has been greatly facilitated by the development of digital and optic-fibers technologies that both increasingly improve quality and quantity, and that lower the cost of cable or satellite transmission of information of every kind (text-soundmoving pictures, separately or in combination-multimedia)20. As M. Castells and J. Henderson note, ‘...Only through an integrated system of telecommunications and computers is it possible at one and the same time both to integrate and to decentralize production, distribution and management, in a worldwide, flexible, interconnected system. The new telecommunications technologies are the electronic highways of the informational age, equivalent to the role played by railway systems in the process of industrialisation’21. The Annual Report of 1982 of the Westinghouse Corporation highlights the significance of information technology for its worldwide operations: “An integrated worldwide strategic planning process was put in place, linking products and country planning efforts. A global communications center is being established to provide timely and detailed information for every part of the world. This centralization of planning and intelligence will give 19 . G. Duysters, The dynamics of Technical Innovation: The Evolution and Development of Information Technology, (Cheltenham U.K., Elgar, 1996). Dertouzos, M., “Communications, Computers and Networks”, Scientific American, (September 1991). 20 . See G.Dourakis, “Information Technology and Structural Reconstruction of Enterprises”, in G.Chajiconstandinou (ed.), The Human Labour in Cross Roads, (in Greek), (Thessalonika : Paratiritis, 1996), p. 95. T.Forester, High-Tech Society, (Oxford : B.Blackwell, 1987) pp. 81-130. 21 . J.Henderson and M.Castells, (eds), Global Restructuring and Territorial Development, (Sage, 1987), p.6. 11 Westinghouse a competitive edge in the worldwide deployment of its resources”22 The rapid transmission of information is especially indispensable for financial operations, that is, banking and trade of currencies, shares and bonds - operations which, as we saw above, dominate in the economies of the West. Information technology provides the network that closely interconnects the markets of stocks, bonds, foreign currencies and finance and that allows the rapid transmission of information worldwide on a 24-hour basis. For instance, in the currencies trade millions of dollars may be turned over in only a few minutes in the foreign-currency markets, making the rapid transmission of information of enormous value. Indeed, the Vice-president of the Bank of America has observed : ‘the value of financial information is fast approaching that of money itself’23. To give an example of the velocity and scale of these operations : in August 1993 the well-known speculator G. Soros earned USD 1 bn overnight by speculating on the pound. This example illustrates the significance of information technology for the performance of modern economic operations that are globally integrated through a worldwide network controlled by the advanced capitalist countries. This is precisely the essence of the socalled information society and information economy. But information technology has also been introduced into the production process in the form of what is called flexible manufacture24. Flexible manufacture represents modern technology at the level of production, where it introduces computerised programming of machine tools, so that they can vary their movements, Cited in F. Webster, “The Politics of the New Technology”, in R.Miliband, et al., (eds), The Socialist Register, 1985/86, (London : Merlin Press, 1986), p.396. 23 . Cited by G. Locksley, “Information Technology and Capitalist Development”, Capital and Class, No 27, 1986, p.87. 24 . A.Raouf and M.Ben-Daya, (eds), Flexible Manufacturing Systems: Recent Developments, (New York and Oxford : Elsevier, 1995). 22 12 adapting to varying product designs - that is, without change in the structure of the machine (general-purpose machine tools). In contradistinction, traditional machine tools, known as purpose-specific machine tools, can produce only products with a standard design. The new type of technology is better known as computer-aided manufacture (CAM) and it is also applied to the designing of the product (computeraided design, or CAD). Information technology has also revolutionised the execution of desk work, and more generally the various services, making it possible for them to be executed automatically (the “electronic office”)25. Information technology has been introduced both in large-scale and smallscale manufacture. Of course large-scale manufacture was mechanised long ago and by the early 20th century it was transformed by Fordism, a technical revolution that introduced the moving assembly line into the manufacturing process. Nevertheless, the assembly of the product’s components remained to a great extent labour intensive. Modern information technology, however, has transformed this last domain of craft, that is skilled labour by introducing robots - and more generally, automation - into the process of the final assembly of the product. Robots mimic the flexibility and responsiveness of the human worker. Robots have been introduced especially in the automobile industry, but also in other branches of large-scale production26. For instance, General Electric has introduced long ago a computerised system of information control and coordination that enables robots ‘to communicate with each other’, and that links all machines into an integrated system, whose remote parts can be connected by satellite links27. Automation is today replacing craft labour in 25 . See, T. Forester, High-Tech Society, (Oxford : B.Blackwell, 1987), pp. 195-217. . J. Patchell, “Composing Robot Production Sustems : Japan as a Flexible Manufacturing System”, Environment and Planning A, 25 (7), July, 1993. 27 . F.Murray, “The Decentralisation of Production – the Decline of the Mass-collective Worker”, Capital and Class, No 19, 1983, p.89. 26 13 virtually all branches of industrial production, such as steel, chemical, extractive, refining, household appliance, textile industries, etc28. Small- and medium-scale industry has also applied information technology29. Here it is useful to make several clarifications. Small- and medium-size firms survive competition with large-manufacture in cases in which the product has a limited market, as compared to the mass market of large-scale industry. In these cases it is not profitable for big capital to invest in products for which the demand is limited. Another facet is that small- and medium-size firms are more flexible than large firms, in the sense that they are more responsive both to variations in product demand and product design. In other words, because they do not specialise in the production of a standardised product destined for a mass market, they easily shift from one design to another, and consequently to varying conditions of demand - indeed, they often produce customised products. Due to these characteristics, small- and medium-size industry still retains a high degree of craft labour, since human labour can adapt to varying designs of the product, while the machine, until recently, could not. Information technology has revolutionised even this, by introducting general purpose machine tools - that is, machine tools which can adapt to varying product design via computer programming. In this way craft labour is to a great extent replaced by machinery in the small- and medium-scale industry as well. For instance, in the garment industry, traditionally labour intensive, automatic microprocessor-controlled cutting machines have been introduced, that can minimise wastage and change . See J. Rifkin, The End of Work, (New York : G.P.Putnam’s sons, 1995), pp. 128-40. . M.Levy and Ph.Powell, “SME Flexibility and the role of Information Systems”, Small Business Economics, 11 (2), 1998. R.L.La Rovere, “Small and Medium Sized Enterprises and Information Technology Diffusion Policies in Europe”, Small Business Economics, 11 (1), 1998. B.D.Phillips, “The Increasing Role of Small Firms in the High-Technology Sector : Evidence from the 1980”, Business Economics, 26(1), 1991. 28 29 14 patterns on command, and that can be integrated into automated sewing machines similarly designed and controlled30. As information technology serves the centralised control of the worldwide system of production and finance, as well as production itself, an increasing part of investments in the advanced capitalist countries is expended on nonmaterial inputs, such as software, planning, research and development. This trend has been described as the softening of the economy31. III. The Transformation of the Class Structure in the West. The processes analysed above entail the accelerated increase of services in the advanced capitalist countries, services organised around world economic management and control, services related to the production of knowledge and technology, as well as those related to the distribution of commodities and consumption. The growth of services and the contraction of the industrial sector in the West have given rise to the so-called postindustrial society32. These developments are clearly reflected in the composition of the working population of the advanced capitalist countries. The USA, Canada and Australia are ahead in these tendencies. Employment in manufacturing in these countries is today only 16%, 15,5% and 13,5% respectively, while employment in services reaches the amazing figure of 73% of the total active population. The United Kingdom follows . See G.Lockslay, “Information Technology and Capitalist Development”, Capital and Class, No 27 1986, p. 102. 31 . See T.Morris-Suzuki, “Robots and Capitalism”, New Left Review, No 147, 1984. 32 . See J.B.De Foucauld, “Post-Industrial Society and Economic Security”, International Labour Review, 135 (6) 1996. K.Kumar, From Post-Industrial to Post-Modern Society : New Theories of Contemporary World, (Oxford : Blackwell, 1995). D.Champlin and P. Olson, “Post-Industrial Metaphors : Understanding Corporate Restructuring and the Economic Environment of the 1990s”, Journal of Economic Issues, 28 (2), 1994. F.P.Romo and M.Schwartz, “The Coming of Post-Industrial Society Revisited :Manufacturing and the Prospects for a Service-Based Economy”, in R. Swedberg, (ed), Explorations In Economic Sociology, (New York : Russel Sage Foundation, 1993). 30 15 closely with 19% of the active population employed in manufacturing and with 71% employed in services. Similar percentages are observed in the rest of the centres of capitalism, with Japan and Germany, however, somehow ‘delayed’ as regards these developments. Employment in the manufacturing sector is relatively higher in these latter two counties, 22% and 25,5% respectively, and employment in services is relatively lower, 62% and 60% respectively33. These figures clearly reflect the contraction of industrial production and the augmentation of services in the advanced capitalist countries. We may say, that the proletariat is no longer the spine of the working masses in these societies. The prevalence of services in Western economies combined with the potential that the new technology bears, gave rise to theories that conceive the information technology as the vehicle of revolutionary economic and social change, epitomised in the so-called information society. The most prominent exponent of the information society is D.Bell. A. Toffler, J. Naisbit, Y. Masuda and other writers promoted the idea, picturing it in utopian colours34. The ideas of these writers have been extensively propagated and popularised by the mass media, especially the press and popular journals, giving rise to great expectations about the coming of a new egalitarian society, and the “rise of a new civilization”. The central concepts of these theories are35: 33 . OECD, Labour Force Statistics, 1998. . See, D.Bell, “The Social Framework of the Information Society”, in J.Forester (ed), The Microelectronics Revolution, (Oxford : B.Blackwell, 1980), pp. 500-49. A Toffler, The Third Wave, (New York : Bantam Books, 1981 and A.Toffler, Powershift, (New York : Bantam Books, 1992). J.Naisbitt, Megatrends :The New Directions Transforming Our Lives, (New York : Warner Books, 1984). J.Naisbitt and P.Aburdene, Megatrends 2000, (London : Sidgwick and Jackson, 1990). T. Stonier, The Wealth of Information : A Profile of the Post-Industrial Economy, (London : Thames Matheum, 1983). Y., Masuda, The Information Society as Post-Industrial Society, (Bethesda, M.D : World Futures Society, 1981), and Y.Masuda, “Computopia”, in J.Forester (ed), The Information Technology Revolution, (Oxford : B.Bklackwell, 1985), pp. 620-634. P.Drucker, The Post-Capitalist Society, (London : Butterworth-Heinemann, 1993). 35 . For an extensive presentation and a critique of these theories see K.Kumar, From Post-Industrial to Post-Modern Society. New Theories of the Contemporary World, pp. 6-35. 34 16 (a) Knowledge and information are becoming the strategic resource of growth and wealth, as well as the main transforming agent of modern society. Knowledge and information are thus conceived as the central socioeconomic entities of the information society, predominating over material capital and labour. (b) Under the above circumstances there emerges a “new service class” and the “knowledge worker”, or the “information worker”. Knowledge and information upgrades the content of work in modern society. Skills, professionalism, knowledge are attributes of the new worker, the “knowledge worker”, who will eventually, come to predominate in the information society. (c) Knowledge and information are also the “new coin of power”. As the information technology diffuses knowledge and information throughout society, it restructures the distribution of power. The new society will be more democratic, more egalitarian, more knowledgeable, and more affluent. J. Naisbitt argues that the information technology demolishes the hierarchies of the centralised, industrial era and transforms the vertical form of organisation into a horizontal one, “which has its roots in the natural egalitarian and spontaneous formation of groups among like-minded people”. As he puts it: “the computer will smash the pyramid”36. Y. Masuda with his “computopia” goes so far as to argue that “the future information society…will become a classless society, free of overruling power, the core of society being voluntary communities”37. These theories exercised broader influence within the social science community. Moreover, some of their core concepts have been adopted by official institutions and agencies, and become instrumental in the way the latter collect 36 . J. Naisbitt, Megatrends : The New Directions Transforming Our Lives, pp. 281-2. . Y. Masuda, “Computopia”, p. 629. For a critique of these theories see D.Lyon, “The Roots of the Information Society Idea”, in N.Heap, et. al., (eds), Information Technology and Society, A Reader (London : Sage, 1995), pp. 54-73 and N., Wintheford, “Autonomist Marxism and the Information Society”, Capital and Class, No 52, 1994. For a moderate critique see M.Castells, The Rise of the Network Society, (Oxford : B.Blackwell, 1996) pp. 203-206. 37 17 information38. The influence of the information society theory endures within the context of recent dramatic developments, such as the collapse of the Soviet Block and the retreat of the Marxist theory. The blurring, in turn, of the boundaries between right and left, the evolution of the left parties in the West, where it is now difficult to trace the difference of their policies from those of the right wing parties, as monetarism and neo-liberalism is adopted throughout the West and throughout the globe as well39, and the voting tendencies of the electorate shifting from one party to the other, contributed to skepticism as to whether political and social behaviour is nowadays associated with class determinants. It is often argued that the category of class is today irrelevant for social and political analysis. Some writers explicitly proclaim the “death of classes” in contemporary capitalism, without, however, denying social inequality. “The most advanced societies”, they say, “are no longer class societies”40. The growing critique of the class concept and class analysis by the end of the 1980s was followed by a growing alignment, particularly within the sociological perspective, with the thesis that the stratification mechanism in Western societies has shifted from capital ownership, production systems and market relations, to cultural values, lifestyles, patterns of consumption, occupational status, “credentialism” and professionalism. Different writers give different emphasis to one or more of these stratification-creating categories41. 38 . See, for instance, OECD, Global Information Infrastructure-Global Information Society (GII-GIS) : Policy Requirements, (OECD Working Papers, No 82, 1997), where it is characteristically argued : “the driving force behind economic growth and development in such a networked economy [Information Economy] will not be natural resources of physical goods, but based on information..”, p.6. The American Bureau of Labour Statistics defined the “information sector” as a “fourth economic sector”. See D. Lyon, The Information Society, Issues and Illusions, (Cambridge : Polity Press, 1988), pp. 45,46. 39 . See T. Fotopoulos, Towards an Inclusive Democracy, pp. 36-41. 40 . J.Pakulski and M. Waters, The Death of Class, (London : Sage, 1996), p. 4. 41 . See J.Pakulski and M. Waters, The Death of Class, pp. 24-26, 28-46, 114-131. For a critical exposition see R. Crompton, Class and Stratification. An Introduction to Current Debates, (Cambridge : Polity Press, 1993). 18 But let us turn, first, to information technology. Instead of upgrading the knowledge content of the work in contemporary Western society, information technology leads to a massive deskilling of both manual and service work, as we shall see below. It should be pointed out that deskilling, degrading of the knowledge content of work is nothing more than the manifestation of a tendency inherent in the capitalist mode of production, which characterised it throughout its historical course. Namely, it is the manifestation of the incessant deepening of the division of labour. The separation of knowledge and conception from execution, has been the production principle of capitalism since its very beginning42. Knowledge and science, applied and transformed to technology is incessantly being transferred to and absorbed by the machinery, not by living labour. This is indeed the trade mark of capitalist production. At the beginning of this century Fordism and Taylorism rationalised and further enhanced this tendency inherent to the functioning of capital 43. Modern information technology, the computer, the robots and “artificial intelligence” are nothing but the present day culmination of this process. As shown above, flexible manufacture, alias computer aided manufacture (CAM) has transformed the production process and has, to an unprecedented extent replaced craft labour via computer programming. As CAM tends to be applied in almost every sphere of material production, as well as in both large-scale and smallscale manufacture, that is, as it tends to be generalised, an ever increasing amount of the remaining skills of the manual workers are being absorbed by modern, computer . See K. Marx, Capital, Vol. I, (London : Lawrence and Wishart , 1970), Ch. XVI: “Division of Labour and Manufacture”, Ch. XV : “Machinery and Modern Industry”. 43 See H., Braverman, Labor and Monopoly Capital. The Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century, (New York : Monthly Review Press, 1974). Braverman’s central thesis is that Taylorist modes of organisation of the contemporary capitalist enterprise involves the routinisation and deskilling of all aspects of work, manual and white-collar, managerial work being therewith no exception. The argument, therefore, of the “upgrading” of the occupational structure, concomitant to the growth of services in Western societies, put forward by the earlier propagators of the “post-industrial society” thesis, was misguided. 42 19 directed machinery. At the same time, automation puts millions of manual workers out of work. The more this process develops, as ever more “intelligent” robots are being constructed and introduced into the production process, the “automatic factory”, that is the almost workerless factory, does not belong to the distant future.44 Nowadays, information technology touches upon the higher ranks of the service occupations to the same effect, namely that of deskilling. Most important of all, information technology has intruded upom the very administrative structure of the capitalist enterprise. The latter has hitherto been based on a complex, multiple hierarchy, splitting into various directions, creating hierarchies within hierarchies of lower, middle and higher management and the corresponding intermediate specialised functionaries within the various departments of the corporation (finance and accounting, marketing and advertising, research and development departments). Today, information technology substitutes the work of lower and middle managers, as well as the jobs of intermediate functionaries, with computer networks, that undertake the vertical and horizontal flow and processing of data and information, as well as the coordination and control of the various operations of the larger enterprise. This process has been described as corporate “re-engineering”, whereby companies eliminate several layers of management, flattening their organisational pyramids45, replacing the lower and middle traditional manager with the so-called “silicon 44 . Already by the middle of 1980’s the Japanese machine tools factory by Jamazaki employed 65 computer-controlled machines and 34 robots linked via a fiber-optic cable with the computerised design center in the headquarters of the company, from where it was directly run. The plant employed 215 workers helping to produce what would take 2500 in a conventional factory. See G. Bylinsky and A.H.Moore, “Flexible Manufacturing Systems”, in T.Forester, (ed), The Information Technology Revolution, (Oxford : B.Blackwell, 1985) pp. 288-9. By the middle of 1990’s the famous FANUC plant in Japan employed only six people and had 101 robots to produce ten thousand servo motors a month. See P.Kennedy, “Robotics, Automation and a New Industrial Revolution”, in N.Heap, et al., Information Technology and Society. A Reader, pp. 107-8. 45 . It is worth referring to a couple of characteristic examples : Eastman Kodak has reduced its management levels from thirteen to four. Intel has cut its management levels hierarchy in some of its operations from ten to five levels. Cited by J. Rifkin, The End of Work, p. 105. 20 manager”, that is computer networks, and along with him extinguishing hundreds of job categories. J. Rifkin gives ample evidence of the effects of corporate “reengineering”, which is as yet in its initial phases. It is estimated that “up to 80 percent of those engaged in middle management tasks are susceptible to elimination”. According to the Wall Street Journal, “across the entire U.S. economy, corporate reengineering could eliminate between 1 million and 2,5 million of jobs a year “for the foreseeable future”. By the time the first stage of re-engineering runs its course, some studies predict a loss of up to 25 million jobs in a private sector labour force that currently totals around 90 million workers”. In Japan, it is estimated, that as many as 860.000 management jobs will be eliminated in the next wave of corporate reengineering. In Europe corporate restructuring is beginning to have an equally profound impact.46 Furthermore, information technology has the same effect, namely the deskilling and potentially putting out of work many professionals. For example, the skills and knowledge of the civil engineer are increasingly being absorbed by software programs capable of accomplishing the entire static study of buildings, or other constructions. The ordinary civil engineer tends to become a computer data feeder, a job that can be undertaken by a person with much lower skills and knowledge than the traditional civil engineer. Therefore, his job is susceptible to elimination. Only a relatively small number of civil engineers with top expertise will be required to direct the work of semi-skilled workers in the profession. Architectural, industrial and other forms of design are also increasingly being undertaken by software programs in the wider field of Computer Aided Design. Artificial intelligence gradually absorbs expert knowledge and skills in almost every field of professional work, such as law, . J. Rifkin, The End of Work, pp. 7, 199. See also H. Blair, et.al., “A Pernicious Panacea : A Critical Evaluation of Business Re-engineering”, New Technology, Work and Employment, No 2, 1998. 46 21 medical diagnosis, financial advice, education, etc47. As K. Kumar points out, “most notably of all, the continuing development of computers has taylorised the computer professionals themselves. Computer work has followed the familiar pattern of the separation and splitting of tasks, leading to increasingly routinized work for the mass of workers and highly specialized work for a small group of designers and researchers”48. Information technology has been introduced and it has radically transformed work in all areas of services, notably banking, insurance, communications, wholesale and retail trade etc, tending at the same time to replace massively, as it develops by leaps and bounds, all categories of service workers, substituting them with computer networks49. We may conclude that these developments tend to single out a small elite of top managers, highly specialised professionals, computer designers and researchers, scientists in research and development and educators, workers of the so-called “knowledge sector”, those otherwise described as “symbolic analysts”. These same processes tend to push down the social ladder, or throw out of work altogether all sorts of categories of hitherto high occupational status. J. Rifkin points to the decline of the middle class in the USA and comments: “While the first automation wave had its greatest impact on blue collar workers, the new re-engineering revolution is beginning to affect the middle echelons of the corporate community, threatening the economic stability and . See M.A. Boden, “The Social Impact of Thinking Machines”, in T.Forester, (ed), The Information Technology Revolution, pp.98-9. 48 . K. Kumar, From Post-Industrial to Post-Modern Society, p. 22. 49 . See J.Rifkin, The End of Work, pp. 141-157. C. Lloyd and H.Newell, “Computerising the salesforce; the introduction of technical change in non-union workforce”, New Technology Work and Employment, No 2, 1998, pp. 104-115. See also, A. Tickel, “Restructuring the British financial sector into the twenty-first century”, Capital and Class, No. 62, 1997, pp. 13-9, especially Tb.1, p.15, where it is shown that between 1989 and 1993, employment in the financial sector of G.Britain has fallen by 7,4 %. 47 22 security of the most important political group in American society – the middle class”50. We may now come to the low level employees, the routine non-manual labourers, that execute orders and move the gears of the economic machine, notably handling the computer. They may have the technical capacity to run the computer, but not knowledge. They handle a tool, just as the traditional mass worker handled the factory tool and the machine. He or she needed a technical capacity for this too. Little training is required for handling the computer and feeding it with data. We may name this category of working people the “new mass worker”. Exactly as the traditional mass worker (manual worker) was and still is a “slave” to the machine, the new mass worker is a “slave to the computer”51. Moreover, exactly like the traditional mass worker, the new mass worker has virtually no comprehension, or knowledge of the overall plan and the economic structure his/her work fits into. Of course the new mass worker must read and write competently, as papers, computer screens and satelites deliver information world-wide. Apart from this fact and the better environment of the office, or work place when compared to the old factory, the work of the new mass worker is devoid of meaningful content, as was the work of the traditional mass worker52. Meanwhile, long-term unemployment in all categories of work persisting in the economies of the West, especially in Europe, as well as the 50 . J.Rifkin, The End of Work, p.170. .This phrase, “slave to the computer” is often used for the contemporary clerical workers. For the deskilling and the “proletarianisation” of the clerical workers, see R.Crompton and G.Jones, WhiteCollar Proletariat: Deskilling and Gender in the Clerical Labour Process , (London : Macmillan, 1984). 52 .This situation has been reflected in a number of new “class maps”, that identify a working class which cut across the conventional manual/non-manual boundary, proposed by authors maintaining the category of class as an analytical and theoretical tool. Within this perspective the working class of the late twentieth century is taken to include routine non-manual workers, that is lower-level clerical and service employees. See, R.Crompton, Class and Stratification. An Introduction to Current Debates, pp. 191 ff. 51 23 dismantling of the welfare state since the early 1980’s, have given rise to the marginalisation of considerable sections of the population, the so-called “underclass”, the “new-poor”, the homeless and the destitute. In addition to this, information technology is today in the process of replacing massively employees in the service sector, the main employment-creating sector of the Western economies since the second World War. Furthermore, automation and the shifting of the core of the manufacturing industry from the centers of capitalism to the rest of the world, has already hit manual workers in the West severely. The slackening, finally, of social controls upon the labour market has given rise to a new kind of workers increasing today rapidly in numbers, the disadvantaged labourers in part-time and temporary work, marginalized workers in insecure employment53. The societies of the West are becoming “societies of the two thirds”, as it has succintly put. Let us now, comment briefly upon the other argument of the information society theorists that the information technology will “smash the social pyramid”. Apart from what has already been said about the deskilling effects of this technology upon various categories of middle and upper service occupations, let us be reminded that this technology serves the concentration of management and control of the world economic system in a small number of headquarters, in the advanced capitalist countries, as analysed above. As we have demonstrated, information technology also serves the worldwide transactions in the financial markets, themselves controlled from a few headquarters in the advanced capitalist countries. A colossal concentration of economic power and control over the world means of production and resources, unprecedented in the history of capitalism, has taken place. This means at the same . See T.Fotopoulos, Towards an Inclusive Democracy, pp. 33-41. K.Coates, “Unemployed Europe and the Struggle for Alternatives”, New Left Review, No 227, 1998. J.Rifkin, The End of Work, pp. 3, 9-11, 166-7. For an extensive examination of unemployment, poverty and the “underclass” in western 53 24 time the concentration and intensification of control over the world labour force, both manual and white-collar. F. de Benedetti, managing director of Olivetti, characterised information technology as “a control tool for capital” and commented: “Information technology is basically a technology of co-ordination and control of the labour force, the white-collar workers, which Taylorian organization does not cover”54. There is also a growing tendency towards substituting the human supervisor with the so-called “electronic supervisor”. “According to a 1987 report published by the Office of Technology Assessment, entitled The Electronic Supervisor , between 20 and 35 percent of all clerical workers in the United States are now monitored by sophisticated computer systems. The OTA report warns of an Orwellian future of “electronic sweatshops” with employees doing “boring, repetitive, fast paced work that requires constant alertness and attention to detail, where the supervisor isn’t even human”, but an “unwinking computer taskmaster”55. As for the thesis of the information society theorists, that “knowledge and information predominate over material capital and labour” in this society, it suffices to point out that modern information technology requires huge capital investment to be applied, as IT multinationals, such as IBM in computers, AT&T and IT&T in telecommunications, etc, demonstrate. Capital controls and commands, it “predominates over” information technology and its functionaries, such as computer specialists, scientists etc, not vice versa. It is, therefore, entirely misleading to describe late twentieth century Western societies as classless societies. The control over the means of production and labour societies since the 1970’s, see F.Gaffikin and M.Morrisey, The New Unemployed. Joblessness and Poverty in the Market Economy, (London : Zed Books, 1992). 54 . Cited in K.Kumar, From Post-Industrial to Post-Modern Society, p. 20. 55 . J.Rifkin, The End of Work, p. 188. See also, C. Wright and J.Land, “‘Under the Clock’ : Trade Union Responses to Computerised Control in US and Australian Grocery Warehousing”, New Technology, Work and Employment, No 1, 1998, pp. 3-15. 25 by capital, enhanced nowadays to a level unprecedented in the history of capitalism, defines the distribution of wealth and power, as well as the division of labour within countries, and across the globe, as analysed above. The distribution of wealth and power and the division of labour in capitalist society is the basis of its class division, it constitutes its stratification mechanism. Modern information technology, the current day means of organisation and control of both material and service production by capital, allocates work and determines its content. It tends to push various categories of middle and upper service occupations down to lower levels of the social ladder, or to throw them altogether out of work. At the same time, it transforms the mass worker in contemporary Western society to an appendage to the computer. It is clear that the class structuring mechanism, that is to say the stratification mechanism, stems today from the predominance of capital over society, as it has always been the case through the entire history of capitalism. Therefore, the argument that the stratification mechanism has shifted from capital to other stratification creating factors is unacceptable. We may conclude that classes are present in Western societies 56. No miraculous emergence of a peculiar capitalism without classes is taking place. Conclusion We may summarise the main points of the analysis in this article as follows: While in previous epochs an international market of commodities existed, during the post-war period a global network of closely interconnected production units and financial institutions has been created as well. At the same time financial speculation has acquired disproportional dimensions. But while production, finance and commerce are decentralised worldwide, their management and control is centralised . For the relevance of class and class politics in the West today, and beyond see J.Moran, “The Dynamics of Class Politics and National Economies in Globalisation : The Marginalisation of the Unacceptable”, Capital and Class, No 66, 1998. A.Danford, “The ‘New Industrial Relations’ and Class 56 26 in a few headquarters in the advanced capitalist countries. A colossal concentration of economic power and control over the world means of production, resources and labour force, unprecedented in the history of capitalism, has taken place. Concomitant to these developments is a new International Division of Labour. The international capitalist system is gradually moving towards a division of the world between a few countries preoccupied with the centralised management and control of the world economic system, as well as with production of knowledge and technology, tending in the long run to retain mainly the production of industrial products with a high content of advanced technology, and the rest of the world being charged mainly with agricultural, raw materials and industrial mass production. On the other hand, the universal adoption of neo-liberal and monetary policies, during the last two decades, has completed the liberalization of the markets, removing the remaining “restrictions” upon the free movement of capital and commodities all over the world, slackening at the same time the social controls upon labour markets. The economic philosophy supporting these policies dictates that the free play of the market forces and unrestricted antagonism should be left alone to organise national and international economy and society, the market itself assumed to be the best mechanism to allocate resources. For the brutal economism of this dogma politics are almost irrelevant for both the national and the international economy. The directors of the world orchestra should be the economic technocrats and bankers. But the liberalisation of the market forces leads to an intensification of economic antagonism, that destroys, among other things, the small and medium-scale economic units in all spheres of economic activity, which have been the main source of employment in the private sector of Western societies. More widely, the process of globalization leads to Struggle in the 1990s”, Capital and Class, No 61, 1997. A.H.Yun, “Industrial Restructuring and the Reconstitution of Class Relations in Singapore”, Capital and Class, No 62, 1997. 27 the over enlargement of certain firms (multinationals) and to the redistribution of wealth to the detriment of the weaker social classes and income groups, as well as the weaker countries internationally. It leads, in the end, towards an economic, so to speak, totalitarianism. Finally, the prevalence of services and the information technology has radically transformed work in Western society and changed therewith the features of its class structure. The rapid expansion of information technology applied in all areas of economic activity has replaced all kinds of craft labour. It has, at the same time, given rise to the “new mass worker”, the routine non-manual labourer, who works as an appendage to the computer. Information Technology and Artificial Intelligence has also affected all kinds of professional and managerial work. It is, lately, in the process of pushing considerable numbers of middle and upper service occupations down to the lower levels of the social ladder, or to throw them altogether out of work, along with low-level service employees. It singles out a small elite of the privileged top managers, highly specialised scientists and professionals, computer designers and researchers. Information technology amplifies, therefore, unemployment rather than creating new jobs, frustrating expectations in the opposite direction. At the same time the welfare state is being dismantled and long term unemployment persists. Western societies seem to be driven towards the marginalisation of large sections of their population and the society of the two-thirds appears to be already a reality, not merely an alarming exaggeration. It seems that the information society, inaugurated by contemporary capitalism, will turn out to be an inhuman society, subordinated to the logic of global accumulation of capital, realised by the vertiginous speed of information technology. However, the processes that we analysed above involve major contradictions, such as, 28 for instance, the ones that crop up almost endemically with the recurring turmoil of the international financial markets, endangering the stability of the world system, haunting the international society with the repetition of the great “crash” of 1929. It is, then, more than plausible to say that these processes do not describe a one way path to the future. By the same token, it is reasonable to anticipate that the peoples of the West and world-wide will resist this menacing spectre of a new “Middle Age”. Via what paths? History is unpredictable. Biography Sophia N. Antonopoulou is Assistant Professor of Economics at the National Technical University of Athens. She is the author of the books : The Political and Economic Thought of Rosa Luxemburg. The Critique of Marx’s Capital, (Athens : Papazissis, 1998). The Post-war Transformation of the Greek Economy, 1950-1980, (Athens : Papazissis, 1991). The Marxist Theory of “Development” and its Convergence with the Conventional Theoretical Paradigm, (Athens : Papazissis, 1991). She has also published articles in scientific journals and the economic press. Abstract In this article the contemporary international capitalist system is examined and a rising New International Division of Labour is defined. It is argued that while in previous epochs an international market of commodities existed, during the post-war period a global network of closely interconnected production units and financial institutions has been created as well. But while production, finance and commerce are decentralised worldwide, their management and control is centralised in a few headquarters in the advanced capitalist countries. A colossal concentration of economic power and control over the world means of production, resources and labour force, unprecedented in the history of capitalism, is taking place. Information Technology is shown to be the current day means of centralisation of organisation and control of both material and service production by capital. It, at the same time, 29 allocates work and degrades its knowledge content. Coupled with the prevalence of services in Western society, it changes the features of its class structure.