1 Negishi's Contributions to the Development of Economic Analysis: research programs and outcomes* Warren Young Bar Ilan University * Forthcoming, International Journal of Economic Theory (special issue on Negishi) Copyright , International Journal of Economic Theory (Blackwell), not to be cited without the permission of the publisher and author. The following persons assisted me greatly in understanding the importance of Negishi's path-breaking contributions to economics: Kenneth Arrow, Jean-Pascal Benassy, Jacques Drèze, Victor Ginsburgh, Peter Howitt, Tim Kehoe, Kazuo Nishimura, Roy Radner, Herbert Scarf, Nancy Stokey, Steve Spear, Makoto Yano and last, but not least, Takashi Negishi himself. 2 Introduction In 1992, Negishi described himself "as a mainstream economist who has made some contributions to the areas of general equilibrium, international trade and neoKeynesian economics" (1992, 227). Indeed, few economists have written on such a wide range of topics as Negishi. Among other things, Negishi attempted to extend the multi-market Neo-Walrasian system in a number of directions so as to encompass stability, imperfect competition, money, trade and unemployment – both demarcating some of the boundaries of mainstream economic theory and setting research agenda, as Samuelson in Foundations of Economic Analysis. Interestingly enough, it was Arrow and Hahn (1971), who initially outlined some key elements in the Negishian research program, and described the initial impact of his early work, while Negishi himself (1972) completed the immediate picture, as will be seen below. Over just a short five year period, 1958-62, Negishi made fundamental contributions to General Equilibrium theory which changed the course of modern economics. His 1958 paper article reduced the number of conditions for stability of tatonnement to gross substitution. In his pioneering 1960 paper, Negishi provided a completely new way of proving the existence of equilibrium, via the Second Welfare Theorem. He established equivalence between the equilibrium problem set out by Arrow-Debreu and what has been called "mathematical programming", thereby developing a "method" which has been utilized with much success by later economists working in both theoretical and applied General Equilibrium modeling, as will be shown below. 3 Negishi's 1961 paper "On the formation of prices" (1961a) was, according to Arrow and Hahn (1971, 346) "the first study of a process without recontract" and, according to them provided fertile ground for extensions by Uzawa (1962a) and Hahn (1962). Negishi's 1961 incorporation of imperfect competition into General Equilibrium models(1961b), while problematic to some (see, e.g. Hart, 1985, 107) has been seen by others as his most important contribution, as will be seen below. In this paper, he initiated the study of imperfect competition in general equilibrium analysis. He assumed consumers to be price takers and firms to be monopolistically competitive. In his model, firms exhibited subjective functions, these being consistent with the given information regarding the current state of the market. He assumed convexity of possible production set of firms, and clearly indicated the problems associated with non-convexities in a Walrasian system. Finally, he proved the existence of equilibrium in an imperfect market setting. His joint 1962 paper with Hahn (1962a), introduced the "Hahn-Negishi Process" of non-tatonnement stability, while Negishi's survey article on stability, published in 1962, is still considered to be the most authoritative on the subject published over the past four decades (1962b). Any attempt to analyze all of Negishi's "multifarious contributions", as Drèèze recently put it, would be a Herculean effort. The object of this paper, therefore, is to assess the impact of what can be considered his "most significant" contributions (Drèèze, 2006, personal communication), in terms of the research programs that emanated from his early work (1958, 1960, 1961a, 1961b, 1962a, 1962b) and their outcomes.. 4 Negishi on Gross Substitutes, Welfare, and Existence of Equilibrium Gross Substitutes (1958) Already in his Master's dissertation, entitled "Existence and stability of an economic equilibrium" [in Japanese] (1957, cited in Negishi 1972, 12, note 4), as he recalls, he had proven "the local stability of the gross substitute case" (2000 b, 326). His first publication in English was in one of the leading journals, Econometrica, in July 1958, and remains, along with papers by Arrow and Hurwicz (1958) and Hahn (1958), one of the fundamental papers dealing with issues of existence of stability of the tatonnement process. What is interesting to also recall here is the editor's note regarding Negishi's first published paper (1958, 445): "These papers [Hahn; Arrow and Hurwicz; Negishi] were written independently of one another and were submitted for publication at about the same time". This illustrates not only the importance of Negishi's contribution in the context of the "multiple discovery", but also highlights the importance the editors of Econometrica placed upon it. Now, according to Negishi, in his 1958 paper, he "proved the local stability of the tatonnement process under the assumptions of gross substitutability and the homogeneity of excess demand functions" (2000 b, 326). While Hahn's 1958 paper did not cite Negishi, it did refer to the forthcoming work of Arrow and Hurwicz and their proof of "a similar theorem" (Hahn, 1958,169, note 1). Arrow and Hurwicz, for their part, referred to both Hahn's paper and that of Negishi and wrote (1958, 546, note 44) "the general case [regarding stability of equilibrium under the assumption of gross substitutability] has been demonstrated independently by Hahn... and Negishi". And, almost 50 years later, the legacy of Negishi's 1958 paper is still "well alive" (Hamada and Endo, 2004, 22). 5 Welfare, Existence of Equilibrium and Competitive Economy (1960) and its impact Theoretical extensions and modifications What has been called Negishi's " approach" or " method" (1960) has been widely utilized on both theoretical and applied levels, the former in the context of dynamic models and infinite dimensional general equilibria; the latter in the context of their numerical computation, as will be seen below. Similar results to Negishi's 1960 proof of the existence of equilibria based on what can be termed mathematical programming techniques, were obtained by Takayama and El Hodiri (1968) and Diewert (1970). Mantel (1971) was the first to consider the utilization of Negishi's1960 approach for computing equilibria. This extension, or tatonnement algorithm, encompassed what Mantel called "the welfare adjustment process" so as to enable "the computation of an equilibrium solution, adjusting the weights assigned to each individual in the social welfare function" (1971, 415). Negishi's 1960 approach also showed that a vector of welfare weights existed and that transfers necessary for decentralizing the Pareto efficient outcome were zero. In seminal papers, Bewley (1982 [1980]) and Yano (1984a, b) applied this to dynamic models in what Kehoe later termed characterizing "equilibria as solutions to social planning problems" (1991, 2090). Lucas and Stokey (1984) also utilized Negishi's approach and that of Bewley (1982 [1980]) in their treatment of optimal dynamic growth, and while not directly citing Negishi (1960), they took his 1960 approach to be part of the corpus of economic theory, and utilized it as such (Stokey, 2006, personal communication). 6 Kehoe and Levine (1985) modified the approaches of Negishi and Bewley to deal with the properties of an infinite horizon economy. More specifically, they developed an approach by which to deal with the problem of determinacy in settings with infinite dimensional characteristics based upon Negishi's characterization of equilibrium as zero on the map of excess spending (1960). Further modification formed the basis for Kehoe, Levine and Romer (1990). This involved conversion of the infinite dimensional problem "into a finite dimensional Negishi problem" (1990, 1). Following this, Kehoe, Levine and Romer (1992), utilized the the Negishi approach to deal with equilibria of economies with externalities and taxes. The Kehoe and Levine (1985) approach of utilizing the map of excess spending assuming additively separable preferences was further extended by Belasko (1997) and Chichilnisky and Zhou (1998). Mas-Colell(1986) also followed Negishi's 1960 approach in his reconsideration of the existence problem regarding price equilibrium and exchange economy characterized by unbounded number of commodities with a finite number of consumers, and developed a topological version of Negishi's approach, as manifest in Mas-Colell and Zame (1991). Dana and Le Van (1991) also extended Negishi's approach, albeit into a "dual version", by utilizing a Pareto optimal weighting system. This Negishi-based "weight approach" has, in fact, come to be one of the main tools in equilibrium asset pricing (Duffie, 1996; Becker and Boyd, 1997). Following from the work of Dana and Le Van (1991), Duran and Le Van (2003) applied Negishi's method to prove existence of equilibrium in a one- sector Ramsey economy. The "Negishi-type" social planner also provided the basis for the analysis by Jensen (2004) of unbounded growth with consumers who are heterogeneous. 7 Another extension of Negishi's 1960 approach can be found in Ghiglino and Olszak-Duquenne (2001) and Ghiglino and Sorger (2002). The former, by utilizing Negishi's 1960 approach, showed that the dynamics in a two-sector neoclassical general equilibrium model with exogenously determined labor supply-- with a single consumption good-- is affected by the initial distribution of capital. The latter, using the Kehoe-Levine-Romer (1991) modification of Negishi's 1960 approach, analyzed how initial individual values of wealth, and the wealth distribution, impacted on the dynamics of equilibrium. And, as Ghiglino put it (2002, 5) "the natural framework to analyze the effects of income inequalities in a general equilibrium framework is provided by a generalization of the Negishi [1960] approach". Crockett, Spear and Sunder (2005) have further extended Negishi's 1960 approach to a learning rule that could ensure convergence to competitive equilibrium. Indeed, on the theoretical level, then, it can be said that Negishi's 1960 approach has become a "standard tool" (Ghiglino and Sorger, 2002, 122). Applications and Computational Analysis With regard to the influence of Negishi's 1960 paper upon the development of "applied", that is "computable" general equilibrium models, in a private communication to the present author, Ginsburgh gave a comprehensive albeit "brief history" of the impact this paper made. He wrote (2006, personal communication): Waelbroeck and I were among the first to use in an applied model Negishi's way of proving the existence of a competitive equilibrium in Ginsburgh and… Waelbroeck (1981)….The book came out in 1981, but there were papers published [by me] before that, the oldest being "Computational experience with a large general equilibrium model"(1976) and a 1975 Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper "A general equilibrium model of world trade. Part I: Full format computation of economic equilibria"… Dixon played with the same idea in his 1972 Harvard Ph.D. thesis which was published in 1975 as The theory of joint maximization, but he only refers very loosely to Negishi, though it is exactly the same model as Negishi's. He calls it "joint maximization". Earlier than that, a paper in the spirit of Negishi's proof... is Trzeciakowski, (1971). 8 More recent applications of Negishi's 1960 approach to the computation of equilibria can be found in Ginsburgh and Van der Heyden (1988), who apply it to the case of the government price supports; Kehoe (1991), who dealt with multiplicity of equilibria; Backus, Kehoe and Kydland (1992 a, b, c), who apply the approaches of Negishi (1960) and Mantel (1971) to calculate equilibria in international real business cycles and dynamic general equilibrium models of international trade; Nordhaus and Yang (1996), who apply it to develop a computable general equilibrium model of alternate climate-change strategies; Ginsburgh and Keyzer (1997), who deal with the structure of AGE models in their book; Esterban-Bravo (2004), who surveys the computation of equilibria in GE models via interior-point methods; Kehoe et. al (2005), who present the "frontiers" of CGE models; and Judd (2005), who extends the approach to dynamic stochastic GE models. Monopolistic Competition: 1959, 1961, and 1972 vintages and their impact Negishi first gave this paper at the December 1959 Washington, D.C. meeting of the Econometric Society .According to the report of the Washington meeting, he presented his paper on Monday afternoon, 28 December 1959, at the session "Economic Theory I". The three papers presented at the session included one by Hahn entitled "The existence of competitive equilibrium". Koopmans also presented a paper, entitled "Stationary Ordinal Utility and Timing Preferences". Ando and McKenzie were the discussants for all the papers. Negishi's paper, however, was the only one that had an abstract published in the Washington meeting Report (1960, 67778). A decade later, Arrow and Hahn (1971, 151-167) extended the existence theorem and formal model contained in what they called Negishi's "brilliant paper" (1971, 167) via more general assumptions such as non-convex production possibility sets 9 (1971, 152). Negishi's monopolistic competition paper (1961b) has been cited almost as many times as his 1960 paper, and also originally stimulated a Negishian-based research program in the 1970's as described by Roberts and Sonnenschein in their Econometrica survey (1977). As they wrote (1977, 101) "Since the pioneering work of Negishi [1961b], a number of studies have been directed towards incorporating firms which recognize their ability to influence prices (but behave non-cooperatively towards one another) into the Arrow-Debreu model of general equilibrium". They listed the works of Arrow and Hahn (1971), Fitzroy (1974), Gabszewicz and Vial (1972), Laffont and Laroque (1976), and Marschak and Selten (1974). Drèèze (1975), Grandmont and Laroque (1975) and Benassy (1976) had extended, implicitly, in the former cases, and explicitly, in the latter case, Negishi's "brilliant paper" (1961b) in another direction, into the sphere of disequilibrium, that is to say non-tatonnement situations, where, as Benassy put it, "transactions can actually occur outside equilibrium" (1976, 69). Silvestre (1977a, 1977b) , for his part, extended Negishi (1961b) to encompass increasing returns to scale, including Negishian-style subjective demand functions. He also developed (1978, 397) an alternative existence theorem to overcome what he called the "shortcomings" in the Arrow-Hahn (1971) extension of Negishi (1961b). In his 1980 Econometrica survey, Drazen noted that the "the basic work on monopolistic competition in general equilibrium models is the pioneering contribution of Negishi [1961b]..." (1980,290). Drazen went on to say that besides the work of Benassy [1976] and Drèèze[1975] "a model in which price setting is integral to agent's attempts to "break" the constraints is that of Hahn [1978] , also based on Negishi's work [1961b], which uses the Drèèze [1975] basic framework" (1980,291). There is, however, a problem in Drazen's linkage of Hahn [1978] to Negishi [1961b]. This is 10 due to the fact that Hahn said (1978, 7) that his 1978 approach "is not the model Negishi [1961b] considered. I have not found it in Benassy. The kink which my formulation gives rise to has recently been used by Negishi ... in a different context" referring the reader to an unpublished 1974 " Memo" by Negishi, which Hahn cited as "Unemployment Equilibrium". In a recent communication to this author, Negishi (2006d) cleared up the matter by saying that "Judging from the date, the paper seems to be the one I read in a conference organized by the Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna, in 1974. The exact title of the paper is "Existence of an under-employment equilibrium." This paper was published in G. Schwoediauer, ed., Equilibrium and Disequilibrium in Economic Theory, D. Reidel Publishing, 1978, pp. 497-510" [Negishi 1974,1978]. Hart (1985), in his overview of work on "imperfect competition in general equilibrium" claimed that both Negishi's approach (1961b) and that of Arrow and Hahn (1971) were not "very satisfactory" (1985, 107) and "suffered from…weakness" as "the class of possible equilibria…is very large"; the outcome of being based upon "subjective", rather than "objective" demand (1985, 139). Hart's points may be relevant; however, as Gabszewicz (1985, 152) noted in his comment on Hart, the "overview" did not deal with the issue of imperfect competition and product differentiation, as set out by Negishi in the 1972 revision of his paper (1972, 104), an approach that was implicitly taken up, for example, by Mas-Colell (1975) and Drèèze and Hagen (1978). In contrast to Hart's critical view of Negishi (1961b), then, and the fact that he did not deal with the work it stimulated, Gabszewicz (1985, 151) wrote "The Negishi approach…received a considerable revival of interest". 11 Very significant outcomes of Negishi (1961b) are found in the non-tatonnement approach of Benassy (1976, 1978, 1982, 1991, 1995), and in the attempt to reformulate Negishi's approach (1961b) by Gary-Bobo (1989). It should also be recalled at this point that Negishi's volume Microeconomic Foundations of Keynesian Macroeconomics appeared in 1979, but before this he had presented papers, and published articles which formed the basis for this book (1974, 1978). Perhaps the most influential of Negishi's articles in this field, that appeared prior to his 1979 book, was entitled "Existence of an under-employment equilibrium". As mentioned above, this paper was originally presented at a conference in Vienna in July 1974, and was published in the volume Equilibrium and Disequilibrium in Economic Theory (1978, 497-510). In this volume, Negishi's paper was complemented by that of Benassy, "A Neo-Keynesian model of price and quantity determination in disequilibrium" (1978, 511-544). It is important to point out here that both papers, in addition to Benassy (1976), preceeded the so-called "New Keynesian" works that appeared in the 1980s (e.g. Rotemberg 1982; Mankiw, 1985). Indeed, in his 1976 paper, Benassy wrote (1976, 69) "monopolistic price setting was incorporated for the first time in a brilliant paper by Negishi [1961b]". The impact of Negishi (1961b) on "New Keynesian economics" has been recounted by Peter Howitt (2006, personal communication): "most of modern New Keynesian Economics owes its intellectual origins to his [Negishi's] work in imperfect competition in General Equilibrium, although it is, like Benassy's work which was also very influential, hardly ever cited. I would say these works were influential because so much subsequent work is a straightforward extension of the concepts and techniques in them, and because although they are not much cited, they 12 were available in prominent publication outlets when the work that is cited (Blanchard-Kiyotaki, for example) was done". More recently, Dehez, Drèèze and Suzuki, in their work on imperfect competition and fixed costs have asserted (2003, 220) Negishi's 1961 "perceived demand approach" to be, in their opinion, "more realistic, in many situations, than the alternative, objective demand approach". Moreover, Negishi's approach (1961b) has been even further extended into the area of international trade theory by Neary (2003), in his attempt to analyze globalization and the structure of markets. Econometrica survey article and "Hahn-Negishi process", 1962 Negishi's classic 1962 survey article "The stability of a competitive economy" was originally presented, in part, at the September 1960 Naples meeting of the Econometric Society (Negishi 1962b, 635, note 1). The abstract of this paper was published in the Report of the Naples meeting in Econometrica (1962, 192). Among those who took part in the discussion also published in the Report (1962, 192-194) were Malinvaud and Wold, with a brief reply by Negishi. In his comments, Malinvaud focused on the implications of Negishi's analysis of "tatonnement" and "non-tatonnement" processes. Negishi's reply to the commentators was "I would say that the tatonnement processes is a special case or limiting case of non-tatonnement processes. It must be noted that both of them lead to a point which is optimal in the sense of Pareto" (1962, 194). Writing with the perspective of over four decades, Drèèze has recently commented on what Negishi said as follows (2006, personal communication): "I agree that limit points of both Walrasian tatonnement and Walrasian nontatonnement are Pareto-efficient (under standard assumptions). The point on which there has been occasional misunderstanding is that limit points of Walrasian non- 13 tatonnement are not competitive equilibria relative to initial endowments, so the efficiency proof is a bit different." His 1962 survey article contained important "suggestions for future studies" (1962b, 665-666), some of which Negishi himself took up in his 1964 papers (1964a, b) and in Chapter 13 of his 1972 book. For example, in the 1962 survey paper, he proposed studying the "price formation process... over Hicksian weeks", with reference to "the cobweb process" and "the process with interactions between expectations and inventory fluctuations" (1962b, 666). In his 1964 paper (1964b, 649), Negishi linked Arrow-Debreu (1954), and Enthoven and Arrow (1956), with Muth (1961); which he repeated in Chapter 13 of his 1972 book (1972, 201). The importance of Negishi's survey article was recognized early on. For example, Patinkin, in Money, Interest and Prices wrote (1965, 540): "The extensive literature which has grown up in recent years on the stability question has been usefully and critically surveyed by Takashi Negishi". In 1962, Negishi also published his joint paper with Hahn. The first note in this paper (1962a, 463, note 1) said that "this is the outcome of two papers by the authors, each written independently. Hahn's paper [Hahn, 1960] formulated the process of adjustment and proved some theorems which were then generalized by Negishi..."; "Negishi's contribution" was "a sequel" to his 1961 International Economic Review paper "On the formation of prices", written while he was at Stanford (1961a, 26). As Negishi recalled (2006, personal communication) "Frank and I got acquainted …before the Washington meeting, in [the] Stanford-Berkeley regular joint seminars in 1959-60. Frank was at Berkeley in 1959-60 and I was at Stanford, though, because of [the] 1958 gross-substitute paper, we knew each other's names in 1958". 14 In his paper "The stability of exchange and adaptive expectations" (1964a)-which also emanated from the research program he outlined in his 1962 survey article--Negishi attempted to model the relationship between prices and expectations in the non-tatonnement process he had originally developed independently of Hahn (Negishi, 1961a), based upon the approach developed in Hahn and Negishi (1962a) and Arrow and Nerlove (1958). Perhaps one of the most important outcomes of the "suggestions for further studies" in his 1962 survey article, is Negishi's utilization of rational expectations in his 1964 "Note" in Econometrica entitled "Stability and rationality of extrapolative expectations"(1964b). Negishi did not attend the sessions of Muth and Mills at the 1959 Washington meeting of the Econometric Society where he gave his own paper ("Monopolistic Competition"), but as he recalled in a letter to this author (9 Dec. 1991): I recognized, however, the significance of their contributions soon after they were published, at least in my own way of interpretations. I published a small note “Stability and Rationality of Extrapolative Expectations” in Econometrica (1964), in which I referred to Muth’s 1961 Econometrica paper. Also, in the Chapter on Rational Expectations of my 1965 book Kakaku to Haibun no Riron (Theory of Price and Allocation), I referred to Mills’ 1962 book as well as Muth’s 1961 paper. In fact, Negishi’s 1964 “small note” is, in my view, quite significant, for in it he used Muth’s approach to “give some rational basis to extrapolative expectations” (1964b, 649). In other words, Negishi proposed rational expectations as the basis for the endogenous expectational assumption underlying “the dynamic stability of multiple markets” in the system originally proposed by Arrow and Debreu (1954) as manifest in Enthoven and Arrow (1956). In fact, Negishi actually extended Muth’s approach in this regard. As he put it (1964b, 649): The rational expectation hypothesis advanced by Muth...is that expectations are essentially the same as the predictions of the relevant economic theory; that the economy generally does not waste information; and that expectations depend 15 specifically on the structure of the entire system. However, since there is cost of information and computation, expectations may also be called rational when they are formed as the prediction based on a simplified and approximated version of the economic theory, using only limited amounts of information on a part of the system. Extrapolative expectations will be derived below as the prediction of the equilibrium by the use of estimated excess demand functions, and it will be shown that the coefficients of expectations thus derived are such that the system of multiple markets is stable when gross substitutability and tatonnement are assumed. By making rational expectations the expectational basis of the Arrow-Debreu general equilibrium model, Negishi provided fertile ground for Radner to further develop the Arrow-Debreu approach. For, as Roy Radner also wrote in a letter to this author (1992, personal communication): My own interest in the subject arose from my attempt to extend the ArrowDebreu model to the case of incomplete markets. The first results of this attempt were published in 1967...This paper dealt simultaneously with two aspects of “rational expectations”: consistency in the expectations of future prices, and making inferences about other agents’ information from equilibrium prices. I like to think it had little impact because it was published in French!" [on these and related issues, see Young and Darity, 2001 and Young, Leeson and Darity, 2004]. Negishian Research Programs: variations on the themes of his contributions Negishi 1960 and 1961 In order to gauge the impact of Negishi's contributions in the eyes of his peers, this author contacted those leading economists who worked with, or were directly influenced by Negishi, and asked them to assess the impact of his work on the General Equilibrium and Non-Walrasian research programs. In his reply, Kenneth Arrow wrote (2006, personal communication): Negishi's work...pioneered in the study of "non-tatonnement" stability, in a paper of his own and a subsequent one jointly with Frank Hahn... He also developed a model of general imperfectly competitive equilibrium, based on subject[ive] demand curves, which impressed me at the time, though it doesn't seem to have had a permanent effect on the literature. Finally, and perhaps most importantly, he had a proof of the existence of equilibrium based on the idea that a competitive equilibrium maximizes a suitably weighted sum of individual utilities. The existence proof depends on a fixed point in the space of weights. This proposition has been used in solving applied general equilibrium models and was also extensively used by Lucas 16 and Stokey in the analysis of intertemporal equilibrium as applied to the study of economic fluctuations. In his reply, Drèèze took the opposite position to that of Arrow regarding the importance of Negishi's "extension of general equilibrium to monopolistic competition". As Drèèze wrote (2006, personal communication) Regarding Negishi, I have all along admired his work, mostly for the reason which he himself lists as his main motivation in his entry for "Who's who in Economics" (3rd ed. p. 819): "I have always tried, not so much to generalise theory mathematically, as to enrich it with economic significance, so that it can be applied to the problems of the real-world economy". Of course, this remark should be applied primarily to General Equilibrium Theory, not to any brand of theory. The remarkable feature is the combination of respect for abstract theory as evidenced by privileged attention to GE, and primary interest in real-world problems [Drèèze's emphases]. Two obvious applications of the principle are: (i) the extension of GE to monopolistic competition; and (ii) the attention to non-Walrasian equilibria. To my own eyes, (i) stands as the most significant among Negishi's multifarious contributions. There is really no palatable alternative to his approach (given the existence problems and lack of realism of the so-called "objective demand" alternative). I am confident that it will be retained again and again by future researchers in the area. Also, his exposition in the 1961 article and 1972 book is very good: rigorous, concise and understandable - what more could one ask? In his reply, Benassy (2006, personal communication), strongly supported Drèèze's postition when he wrote "To me the major contribution by Negishi has been his short but incredibly influential 1961 article "Monopolistic competition and general equilibrium". All authors writing on the subject have been directly influenced by this highly elegant article, so I would place it at the center of any piece on Negishi's contributions". Scarf, for his part, noted in his reply (2006, personal communication) to this author: Takashi Negishi has made many significant contributions to economic theory, primarily, though not exclusively, in the area of general equilibrium theory. One of his most striking innovations is his proof of the existence of equilibrium prices based on maximizing a weighted sum of individual utilities. Each such maximization will produce a vector of prices and an allocation of society’s resources in which the value of consumption will be different from income for the typical consumer. A fixed point argument is then applied in the space of social welfare weights to find the appropriate set of weights for which the value of consumption is equal to income for all 17 consumers. Fixed point algorithms, or their equivalents, are used to find equilibrium prices in applied general equilibrium analysis. Computational demands depend on the dimension of the space in which the fixed point argument is applied - typically the number of commodities in the model. The number of consumers is usually much smaller than the number of commodities. Applied general equilibrium practitioners have found Negishi’s approach extremely useful in reducing computational time and allowing much larger problems to be solved. Stokey, for her part, when asked by this author about the connection made by Arrow in his reply to the present author as cited above, that is, between her joint work with Lucas (1984), and Negishi's 1960 "method", replied (2006, personal communication): "Ken has a good memory. Bob Lucas and I used Negishi's method in our 1984 JET paper on optimal growth with Koopmans-Diamond-Williamson preferences, which are recursive but not additively separable over time. In our setting, the key idea was to define a mapping on the Pareto weights, which with those preferences evolve over time"; and this, despite the fact that Negishi's 1960 paper is not cited in Stokey and Lucas (1984). Indeed, as Spear has recently observed in a communication to this author (2006): …my exposure to this body of work has been most focused on the work on existence, the work on tatonnement stability conditions, and the non-tatonnement, Hahn-Negishi processes….I was probably first exposed to the existence paper in graduate school, and came to particularly appreciate it as a way of showing existence of equilibrium in the neo-classical capital model with finitely-many agents… I think some results can become so well-known and so well discussed in surveys that people stop citing them. This would certainly explain the absence of a citation by Lucas and Stokey. This observation has been confirmed by Stokey, who, with Lucas (1984) "took Negishi's method to be part of the corpus of modern economic theory" (2006, personal communication). Analytical Extension of Negishi (1960) and the "Negishi-Mantel algorithm" But more is involved here than simple theoretical and computational application of Negishi (1960), and its absorption into the "corpus" of modern theory. In his seminal paper, Yano (1998) extended the analytics of Negishi's 1960 approach to 18 gauge the efficacy of "temporary fiscal policy". By extending Negishi's approach he found that, among other things "the inefficacy of temporary fiscal policy… may be thought of as one of the most fundamental properties of dynamic general equilibrium" (1998, 440). The crucial implication of this result has yet to be digested by those who deal with macroeconomic policy and analysis. On another level, there has been increasing utilization of what has been called the "Negishi-Mantel algorithm" (Backus et al. 1992b, 9). For example, Cunat and Maffezzoli (2004), apply the "Negishi-Mantel algorithm" to Heckscher-Ohlin business cycles, while Mendoza and Oviedo (2005), apply it to the analysis of fiscal policy and macroeconomic uncertainty in emerging markets. Tim Kehoe has recently provided this author with his important account of the development of what Scarf originally termed the "Negishi-Mantel algorithm". According to Kehoe (2006, personal communication): I started in the Ph.D. program at Yale in the fall of 1975. I took Herb Scarf’s general equilibrium course (mathematical economics as it was called then) that fall. In the spring, Herb was a visitor at Harvard …Rolf Mantel, who was a visitor at Yale, taught the second semester of Herb’s course. That is when I first heard about what Rolf called the “Negishi approach” to proving the existence of equilibrium via the second welfare theorem and a fixed point problem in welfare weights. Rolf stressed that Negishi’s approach relied on an underlying fixed point problem. He explained that, in his Ph.D. thesis, he (that is, Rolf) had tried to circumvent using fixed point methods in developing a computational algorithm for general equilibrium models. Of course, by the time the principal paper taken from Rolf’s thesis, Mantel (1971), was published, he had realized that the stability properties of a tâtonnement process on welfare weights depended on the properties of the underlying utility functions and endowments of the economy. In fact, an argument due to Uzawa (1962)[1962b] said that any proof of existence of equilibrium in an economy whose excess demand function was arbitrary except for the assumptions of continuity, homogeneity of degree zero, and Walras’s law could be trivially manipulated into a proof of Brouwer’s fixed point theorem. Rolf was intrigued by the question of whether excess demand functions were arbitrary except for these basic assumptions or whether they satisfied some stronger properties that would make computation of equilibria easier. He came up with the answer in Mantel (1974): Aggregate excess demand functions are, in fact, arbitrary except for these assumptions unless we place strong restrictions on utility functions, endowments, or numbers of consumers… The next year, Herb Scarf was back at Yale, and he asked me to be the grader for his course….Many of my friends and classmates, now in their second year, including 19 Dave Backus, took this course. In the second semester, Herb spent a couple of classes going over the results of Negishi, Uzawa, and Mantel. If anyone was first to refer to a Negishi-Mantel approach or algorithm, it was Herb. (Or it was Dave and me talking about what we had learned in his course.) Herb stressed that any general algorithm for computing equilibria that would be guaranteed to converge had to be a fixed point algorithm. The dimensionality of the problem, however, was determined by the minimum of the numbers of goods and consumers. For models with lots of consumers and few goods, we should solve a problem in price space. For models with lots of goods and few consumers, we should use the Negishi-Mantel approach and solve a problem in the space of welfare weights. Herb gave the class a homework problem with two infinitely lived consumers and asked the students to solve it using the Negishi-Mantel approach. Versions of this problem still survive in the problems that I give first year graduate students at Minnesota in my macro course …and in exam questions. It is also the basis of the approach that David Levine and I took in our papers on determinacy of equilibria… To sum up, a number of major research programs can be identified, therefore, as emanating from Negishi's now classic papers, that of 1960 and 1961 (1961b) respectively. Negishi's 1960 paper forms the basis for both "theoretical" an "applied" research programs in general equilibrium analysis, and his 1961 paper (1961b) has been almost as influential in demarcating ongoing research up to the present in the field of imperfect competition and non-tatonnement processes. These papers, as has been shown above, attest to Negishi's considerable influence on the development of modern economic theory and analysis. 20 References The references are divided into two sections: (i) Negishi's works cited in this paper and other relevant works of Negishi and (ii) other works cited in this paper, including those emanating from the Negishian research program based upon Negishi's landmark papers (1960) and (1961b). (i) Negishi's Works (1957) "Existence and stability of an economic equilibrium" (in Japanese), presented to the University of Tokyo as a partial requirement for MA [ see reference in Negishi, 1972, 12 note 4]. (1958), "A note on the stability of an economy where all goods are gross substitutes," Econometrica 26, 445-7. (1960), "Welfare economics and existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy," Metroeconomica 12, 92-7. (1961a), "On the formation of prices," International Economic Review 2, 122-6. (1961b), "Monopolistic competition and general equilibrium," Review of Economic Studies 28, 196-201. (1962a), "A theorem on non-tatonnement stability,"(with Hahn), Econometrica 30, 463-9. (1962b), "Stability of a competitive economy: A survey article," Econometrica 30, 635-69. (1963), "On social welfare function," Quarterly Journal of Economics 77, 156-8. (1964a), "The stability of exchange and adaptive expectations,", International Economic Review 5, 104-111. (1964b), "Stability and rationality of extrapolative expectations," Econometrica 32, 649-51. 21 (1965a), "Ippankikoron no shomondai" ['General Equilibrium Theory'], unpublished Ph.D dissertation, University of Tokyo. (1965b), Kakaku to Haibun no Riron [' Theory of Price and Allocation'] Tokyo: Toyokeizai. (1972), General Equilibrium Theory and International Trade, Amsterdam: NorthHolland. (1974), "Existence of an under-employment equilibrium", a paper presented at the Conference of the Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna, July 1974. (1978), "Existence of an under-employment equilibrium," G. Schwodiauer, ed., Equilibrium and Disequilibrium in Economic Theory, 497-510,Dordrecht: Reidel. (1979), Microeconomic Foundations of Keynesian Macroeconomics, Amsterdam: North Holland. (1985), Economic Theories in a Non-Walrasian Tradition, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (1987), Disequilibrium Trade Theories (with Itoh), New York: Harwood. (1992), "Breaking away-history of economics as history of science- comment," History of Political Economy 24, 227-9. (1994a), Collected Essays , Vol. I: General Equilibrium Theory, Aldershot: Elgar. (1994b), Collected Essays , Vol. II: The History of Economics, Aldershot: Elgar. (2000a), Collected Essays , Vol. III: Economic Thought from Smith to Keynes, Aldershot: Elgar. (2000b), "Takashi Negishi," R. Backhouse and R. Middleon, eds. Exemplary Economists Volume II, 325-331, Aldershot: Elgar. 22 Other works cited Abstract, "Monopolistic competition and general equilibrium," by T. Negishi, in Report of the Washington Meeting, December 28-30, 1959, Econometrica 28, 677-78 (July 1960). Abstract, "On the stability of a competitive economy," by T. Negishi , and discussion in Compte Rendu du Congres de Naples, 12-14 Septembre 1960, Econometrica 30, 192-194 (January 1962). Arrow , K. and G. Debreu (1954), "Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy," Econometrica 22, 265-90. ________. and L. Hurwicz (1958), "On the stability of the competitive equilibrium, I,", Econometrica 26, 522-52. ________. and M. Nerlove (1958), "A note on expectations and stability," Econometrica 26, 297-305. Backus, D., P. Kehoe, and F. Kydland (1992 a), "International real business cycles," Journal of Political Economy 100, 745-775. _______________________________ (1992b),"Relative price movements in dynamic general equilibrium models of international trade," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper No. 9213, November. _______________________________ (1992c),"Relative price movements in dynamic general equilibrium models of international trade," NBER Working Paper No. 4243, December. 23 Balasko, Y. (1997), "Equilibrium analysis of the infinite horizon model with smooth discounted utility functions," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 21, 783829. Becker, R. and J. Boyd (1997), Capital Theory, Equilibrium Analysis and Recursive Utility, Malden, MA.: Blackwell Benassy, J.P. (1976), "The disequilibrium approach to monopolistic price setting and general monopolistic equilibrium," Review of Economic Studies 43, 69-81. __________. (1978), "A neo-Keynesian model of price and quantity determination in disequilibrium," G. Schwodiauer, ed., Equilibrium and Disequilibrium in Economic Theory, 511-544, Dordrecht: Reidel. ___________. (1982), The Economics of Market Disequilibrium, New York: Academic Press. ___________. (1991),"Monopolistic competition", W. Hildenbrand and H. Sonnenschein, Handbook of Mathematical Economics vol. 4, 1997-2045, Amsterdam: Elsevier. ___________ ed. (1995), Macroeconomics and Imperfect Competition, Aldershot; Elgar. Bewley, T. (1980), "An integration of equilibrium theory and turnpike theory," Working Paper, Northwestern University [cited in Lucas and Stokey (1984)]. ________. (1982), "An integration of equilibrium theory and turnpike theory," Journal of Mathematical Economics 10, 233-267. 24 Chichilinsky, G. and Y. Zhou (1998), "Smooth infinite economies," Journal of Mathematical Economics 29, 27-42. Crockett, S., S. Spear and S. Sunder (2005), "Learning Competitive Equilibrium," working paper , Cal Tech, Carnegie-Mellon and Yale Universities, September. Cunat, A. and M. Maffezzoli (2004), "Heckscher-Ohlin business cycles," Review of Economic Dynamics 7, 555-585. Dana, R. and C. Le Van (1991), "Equilibria of a stationary economy with recursive preferences," Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 71, 289-313. Dehez, P., J. Drèze and T. Suzuki (2003), "Imperfect Competition a la Negishi , also with Fixed Costs," Journal of Mathematical Economics 39, 219-237. Diewert, W. (1970), "On a theorem of Negishi," Metroeconomica 25, 119-135. Dixon, P. (1975), The Theory of Joint Maximization, Amsterdam: North Holland. Drazen, A. (1980),"Recent Developments in Macroeconomic Disequilibrium Theory," Econometrica 48, 283-306. Drèze, J. (1975), "Existence of an Equilibrium Under Price Rigidity and Quantity Rationing," International Economic Review 16, 301-20. _______. and K. Hagen (1978), "Choice of product quality: equilibrium and efficiency," Econometrica 46, 493-515. Duffie, D. (1996), Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory, 2nd ed., Princeton: Princeton University Press. 25 Duran, J. and C. Le Van (2003), "Simple proof of existence of equilibrium in a onesector growth model with bounded or unbounded returns from below," Macroeconomic Dynamics 7, 317-332. Enthoven, A. and K. Arrow (1956), "A Theorem on Expectations and the Stability of Equilibrium," Econometrica 24, 288-93. Esterban-Bravo, M. (2004), "Computing equilibria in general equilibrium models via interior-point methods," Computational Economics 23, 147-171. Fitzroy, F. (1974), "Monopolistic competition, non-convexity and inverse demand," Journal of Economic Theory 7, 1-16. Gabszewicz, J. (1985), "Comment on Hart," K. Arrow and S. Honkapohja, eds., Frontiers of Economics, 150-169, Oxford:Blackwell. __________ and J.Vial (1972), "Oligopoly 'a la Cournot' in general equilibrium analysis," Journal of Economic Theory 4, 381-400. Gary-Bobo, R. (1989), "Cournot-Walras and locally consistent equilibria," Journal of Economic Theory 49, 10-32. Ghiglino, C. (2002), "Introduction to a general equilibrium approach to economic growth," Journal of Economic Theory 105, 1-17. _________ and M. Olszak-Duquenne (2001), "Inequalities and fluctuations in a dynamic general equilibrium model," Economic Theory 17, 1-24. _________ and G. Sorger (2002), "Poverty traps, indeterminacy, and the wealth distribution," Journal of Economic Theory 105, 120-139. 26 Ginsburgh, V. and M. Keyzer (1997), The Structure of Applied General Equilibrium Models, Cambridge MA: MIT Press ____________ and L. Van der Heyden (1988), "On extending the Negishi approach to computing equilibria: the case of government price support policies," Journal of Economic Theory 44, 168-178. _____________ J. Waelbroeck , "Computational experience with a large general equilibrium model of the world economy," J.Los and M. Los, eds., Computing equilibria: How and Why, 257-269, Amsterdam: North Holland. __________________________, (1981), Activity Analysis and General Equilibrium Modeling, Amsterdam: North Holland. Grandmont, J. and G. Laroque (1975), "On temporary Keynesian equilibria," Review of Economic Studies 43, 53-67 Hahn, F. (1958), "Gross substitutes and the dynamic stability of general equilibrium," Econometrica 26, 169-70. ______. (1960), "On the stability of competitive equilibrium," Working Paper No. 6, Bureau of Business and Economic Research, University of California at Berkeley, April. ______. (1962), "On the stability of pure exchange equilibrium," International Economic Review 3, 206-213. ______. (1978), "On non-walrasian equilibria," Review of Economic Studies 45, 1-17. 27 ______ and T. Negishi (1962), "A theorem on non-tatonnement stability," Econometrica 30, 463-469. Hamada, K. and M. Endo (2004), "Preferential trade agreements, the Metzler paradox, and trade diversion,", preliminary draft working paper, Yale and Keio Universities, March. Hart, O. (1985), "Imperfect competition in general equilibrium: an overview," K. Arrow and S. Honkapohja, eds., Frontiers of Economics, 100-149, Oxford:Blackwell. Jensen, M. (2004), "On unbounded growth with heterogenous consumers," revised draft working paper, Brown University, February. Judd, K. (2005), "Solving dynamic stochastic competitive general equilibrium models," T. Kehoe, T.N. Srinivasan and J. Whalley, eds. , Frontiers in Applied General Equilibrium Modeling, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kehoe, T. (1991), "Computation and multiplicity of equilibria," W. Hildenbrand and H. Sonnenschein, Handbook of Mathematical Economics vol. 4, 2049-2143, Amsterdam: Elsevier. Kehoe, T. and D. Levine (1985), "Comparative statics and perfect foresight in infinite horizon economies," Econometrica 53, 433-454. ____________________ and P. Romer (1990), "Determinacy of equilibria in dynamic models with finitely many consumers," Journal of Economic Theory 50, 1-21. 28 _____________________ and P. Romer (1992), "On characterizing equilibria of economies with externalities and taxes as solutions to optimization problems," Economic Theory 2, 43-68 Kehoe,T., T.N. Srinivasan and J. Whalley, eds. ,(2005) Frontiers in Applied General Equilibrium Modeling, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Laffont, J. and G. Laroque (1976),"Existence d'un equilibre general de concurrence imparfaite: une introduction," Econometrica 44, 283-294. Lucas, R. and N. Stokey (1984), "Optimal Growth with Many Consumers," Journal of Economic Theory 32, 139-171 Mankiw, G. (1985), "Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: a Macroeconomic Model of Monopoly," Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, 529-38. Mantel, R. (1971), "The welfare adjustment process: its stability properties," International Economic Review 12, 415-30. Mantel, R. (1974), "On the characterization of aggregate excess demand," Journal of Economic Theory 12, 197-201. Marschak, T. and R. Selten (1974), General Equilibrium with Price-Setting Firms, Berlin and New York: Springer-Verlag Mas-Colell, A. (1975), "A model of equilibrium with differentiated commodities," Journal of Mathematical Economics 2, 263-296. ____________. (1986), "The price equilibrium existence problem in topological vector lattices," Econometrica 54, 1039-1054. 29 Mas-Colell, A. and W. Zame (1991), "Equilibrium theory in infinite dimensional space," W. Hildenbrand and H. Sonnenschein, Handbook of Mathematical Economics vol. 4, 1835-1898, Amsterdam: Elsevier Mendoza, E. and P. Ovideo (2005), "Fiscal policy and macroeconomic uncertainty in emerging markets," Working paper draft, University of Maryland and Iowa State University, December. Mills, E. (1962), Price, Output and Inventory Policy , New York: Wiley. Muth, J. (1961), "Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements," Econometrica 29, 315-35. Neary, J. (2003), "Globalization and market structure," Journal of the European Economic Association 1, 245-271. Nordhaus, W. and Z. Yang (1996), "A regional dynamic general equilibrium model of alternative climate change strategies," American Economic Review 86, 741-765. Patinkin, D. (1965), Money, Interest, and Prices: An Integration of Monetary and Value Theory. 2nd edition. ,New York: Harper and Row. Roberts, J. and H. Sonnenschein (1977), "On the foundations of the theory of monopolistic competition," Econometrica 45, 101-113. Rotemberg, J.(1982), "Monopolistic Price Adjustment and Aggregate Output," Review of Economic Studies 49, 517-31 Silvestre, J. (1977a), "General monopolistic equilibrium under non-convexities," International Economic Review 18, 425-434. 30 _________. (1977b), "A model of general equilibrium with monopolistic behavior," Journal of Economic Theory 16, 425-442. _________. (1978b), "Increasing returns in general non-competitive analysis," Econometrica 46, 397-402. Takayama, A. and M. El Hodiri (1968), "Programming, Pareto optimum and the existence of competitive equilibria," Metroeconomica 20, 1-10. Uzawa, H. (1962), "On the stability of Edgeworth's barter process," International Economic Review 3, 218-232. _______. (1962b), "Walras' existence theorem and Brouwer's fixed point theorem," Economic Studies Quarterly 13, 59-62. Yano, M. (1984a)," Competitive equilibria on turnpikes in a McKenzie economy, I: a neighborhood turnpike theorem," International Economic Review 25, 695-717. _______. (1984b), "The turnpike of dynamic general equilibrium paths and its insensitivity to initial conditions," Journal of Mathematical Economics 13, 235-254. _______. (1998), "On the dual stability of a von Neumann facet and the inefficacy of temporary fiscal policy," Econometrica 66, 427-451. Young, W. and W. Darity (2001) "The Early History of Rational and Implicit Expectations," History of Political Economy 33, 773-813 ____________________ and R. Leeson (2004) Economics, Economists and Expectations: Microfoundations to Macroapplications , London: Routledge 31