Racing to the Bottom in the Post-Communist World: Domestic Politics, International Trade, and Environmental Governance Liliana Botcheva-Andonova Department of Government Colby College Waterville, ME 04901 landonov@colby.edu Edward D. Mansfield Department of Political Science University of Pennsylvania Philadelphia, PA 19104 emansfie@sas.upenn.edu Helen V. Milner Department of Politics Princeton University Princeton NJ 08540 hmilner@princeton.edu Abstract In this paper, we analyze whether trade liberalization and increasing commercial openness has affected environmental governance in the post-Communist countries of Central and Eastern Europe and the Commonwealth of Independent States. During the Cold War, these countries had closed economies and autarkic trade policies combined with little environmental regulation and poor environmental quality. The fall of the Berlin Wall and the breakup of the Soviet Union began a process of marked change in the region. Many post-Communist countries have engaged in extensive trade liberalization. Others, however, have been slower to open their markets; and some have maintained highly protectionist trade policies. Have countries that opened up to global markets improved their environmental policies or has increasing exposure to the international trading system led to a “race to the bottom”? Controlling for a wide variety of economic and political factors, our results indicate that heightened trade openness has weakened environmental governance in the post-Communist world, suggesting that an environmental race to the bottom has been occurring among the transition economies. 1 Introduction In recent years, social scientists, policy makers, and other observers have expressed considerable interest in the relationship between globalization and the environment. Nowhere is the need for a fuller understanding of this relationship more pressing than in research on the post-Communist economies of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) and the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS).1 Until the late 1980s, all of these countries had closed economies coupled with weak environmental regulations and extensive pollution. Since the end of the Cold War, some postCommunist countries have engaged in rapid and extensive trade liberalization and have made various related efforts to increase their integration into the world market, contributing to rising globalization (EBRD 1999, 204; Murrell 1996; Rodrik 1992). For other states, however, progress in reforming their trade regimes has been slow or has not occurred at all. In this paper, we analyze whether the trade regimes of post-Communist states have influenced their environmental policies. One of the chief fears expressed in the burgeoning literature on globalization is that this process will precipitate a “the race to the bottom” in environmental governance. The worry is that heightened competition in a globalized economy may lead firms to locate investments in countries that minimize regulations and other costs of doing business. Equally, domestic firms that cannot relocate may press their governments to reduce such costs in order to avoid being placed at a competitive disadvantage in global markets. These pressures could prompt governments to weaken or abolish environmental regulations. A number of studies have found evidence of this phenomenon, although the 1 The CEE countries are Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Slovakia, and Slovenia. The CIS includes the Russian Federation, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Ukraine, and Uzbekistan. 2 matter remains highly controversial (Copeland and Taylor 2004; Hettige, Lucas, and Wheeler 1992; Lofdahl 2002; Low 1992). Alternatively, globalization may place pressure on firms and countries to improve environmental standards if, for example, they are required to make such improvements before gaining access to valuable foreign markets (Garcia-Johnson 2000; Jha, Markandya, and Vossenaar 1999; Mol 2001; Vogel 1995). Many observers have suspected that this would be the case for certain transition economies, since the European Union (EU) made accession by the CEE countries contingent on the adoption of relatively stringent environmental regulations (Andonova 2003a, 2003b; Holzinger and Knoepfel 2000; OECD 1999b). However, little systematic research has been conducted on the links between trade and environmental policy in the post-Communist world. This paper aims to fill that important gap. We argue that an environmental race to bottom has occurred in the region. We begin by discussing the history of environmental policy in these countries since 1991. We then present our argument about why open trade might produce a race to the bottom in environmental policy. We discuss evidence from several cases to support the logic behind our argument. Then we perform a systematic quantitative analysis of the relationship between trade and environmental policy for the CEE and CIS countries in the 1990s. Our statistical results and anecdotal evidence from the historical record support our argument. During the 1990s, trade liberalization produced a weakening of environmental policy by reducing governments’ ability to collect environmental taxes and support environmental investments. Consequently, globalization seems to be undermining the environmental regimes of the post-Communist world. 3 Environmental Politics in the Transition Economies Post-Communist governments inherited critical environmental problems. Severe air pollution, soil degradation, and contamination of rivers and regional seas were common dilemmas in the region (Asian Development Bank 1997; Carter and Turnock 1993; Weinthal 2002; World Bank 1994). The health effects of environmental degradation and the active role played by environmental movements in the breakup of the communist system placed environmental reforms at the top of the political agenda in the early 1990s. However, the environmental enthusiasm of the early transition period waned quickly. Economic and social concerns took precedence as some of the worst environmental problems were alleviated by sharp declines in industrial production. Almost fifteen years after the collapse of the Berlin Wall, the record of environmental policy reform varies considerably across the post-Communist world. Countries such as Poland, the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Slovenia, and Hungary have led the way in strengthening environmental legislation and institutions. They were able to reduce pollution even after their economies began to grow. Others countries – such as Romania and Bulgaria – have improved their environmental legislation, but are hampered by a weak institutional capacity for implementing these reforms. Still other transition economies – including Russia, Ukraine, and Kazakhstan – have implemented only the most basic environmental policies (Andonova 2003a; Carter and Turnock 2002; Ichikawa, Tsutsumi, and Watanabe 2002; Klarer and Moldan 1997; Kotov and Nikitina 2002; OECD 1999b; OECD 2000; Vovk 2003). Similarly, the extent to which environmental laws are actually implemented also varies considerably across countries in the region. Virtually all transition countries have 4 developed economic instruments to facilitate such implementation; for example, many introduced charges, taxes, and penalties intended to stimulate investments in pollution abatement. Post-Communist states also established special extra-budgetary environmental funds – financed by environmental charges, taxes, and penalties – to provide public support for environmental investments. As we explain later, these are critical instruments and we focus on them throughout this paper. But the ability of environmental authorities to enforce these instruments is often weak. Environmental ministries and inspectorates are typically in a tenuous position. It is politically infeasible to penalize enterprises for environmental damage while they struggle to adjust to domestic economic reforms and increasing international competition (Bluffstone and Larson 1997; Ichikawa, Tsutsumi, and Watanabe 2002; OECD 1999a; REC 1999, 2001b). Recent studies reveal that apart from a few countries – such as Poland and the Czech Republic – the overall environmental tax burden on industry has been kept low and does not provide strong incentives to undertake environmental improvements (Bluffstone and Larson 1997; REC 1999, 2001b). An even more significant enforcement problem is the low rate at which charges and penalties are collected. This problem is especially severe in CIS countries – such as Russia, Ukraine, and the Central Asian republics – which have emphasized export-led growth based on the development of natural resources while facing little domestic pressure to penalize polluters. Pollution offset schemes under which polluters are temporarily relieved from emissions charge payments in exchange for a largely unenforceable commitment to use those resources for environmental investments are widespread in these countries (Ichikawa, Tsutsumi, and 5 Watanabe 2002; Kotov and Nikitina 2002; OECD 1999a, 2000). However, this problem is not limited to the CIS states: the capacity and willingness of CEE states to enforce environmental legislation is also a matter of considerable concern (Commission of the European Communities 2001). In sum, the opening and restructuring of transition economies has been accompanied by divergent trends in environmental protection. Virtually all countries, but particularly the EU accession states, have updated their environmental legislation and reduced the overall level of pollution. The enforcement of environmental regulations, however, has remained lax and even deteriorated in many cases. The purpose of our analysis is to address whether differences in the exposure of post-Communist countries to the global economy helped to shape variations in their environmental governance. To examine the impact of trade on environmental policy, we analyze the per capita size of national environmental funds. These funds, capitalized primarily by environmental taxes and fees, are among the most important environmental instruments in transition countries. They were intended to compensate for the underdeveloped financial systems of these countries during the transition period (Anderson and Zylicz 1999; Ichikawa, Tsutsumi, and Watanabe 2002; OECD 1999a; REC 2001).2 The relative size of the environmental funds collected is a good indicator of regulatory enforcement since it reflects both the level of environmental fees and fines imposed on polluters as well as the ability of governments to collect them. It is also a good measure of the 2 Although the environmental funds were conceived as transitional instruments that would eventually give way to private financing, their statutes did not include sunset provisions and most funds have persisted as the single most important source of public financing for the environment (REC 2001b). After 2000, a few countries – including Slovenia, Estonia, and Russia – ended their environmental funds, while Bulgaria and Hungary consolidated the environmental fund resources into national budgets for greater fiscal control. In CEE states, these funds are expected to play an important role in helping to address the environmental investment needs associated with EU accession (REC 2001b). 6 government’s capacity to support environmental improvements that have been written into law. We thus examine the effect of trade on the commitment to environmental policy as reflected in these national funds rather than simply the adoption of environmental regulations. The Argument As a group, post-Communist states have made considerable headway in trade liberalization since the fall of the Berlin Wall (EBRD 1999; Frye and Mansfield 2003; Murrell 1996; Rodrik 1992). On average, foreign trade was about 70% of gross domestic product (GDP) for these states in 1990. This figure rose to about 100% in 1992 and has remained close to that level since. Nonetheless, not all countries have displayed the same interest in opening their markets to foreign trade. Some states (for example, Uzbekistan) have chosen to retain closed trading regimes, and others (for example, Ukraine) have been slow to increase their exposure to foreign competition. Have differences in the commercial openness of transition economies influenced the quality of environmental governance? Economic research suggests that the linkage between trade and the environment in the post-Communist world is ambiguous.3 Existing studies have distinguished three dimensions along which the environmental effects of trade are likely to vary: scale, composition, and technology. The scale effect reflects the overall environmental impact of economic growth, stemming from trade as well as other sources. Growth is likely to increase the consumption of a country’s natural resources and generate pollution. At the 3 For reviews of the literature on the relationship between international trade and the environment, see Copeland and Taylor 2004; Dean 2001; Fredriksson 1999; and Low 1992. 7 same time, however, rising income is expected to increase the demand for environmental protection. The latter is reflected in the Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC), which stipulates that the initial increase in pollution associated with growth will give way to declining levels of pollution as societies reach a certain level of prosperity and demand higher environmental quality (Grossman and Krueger 1993). The composition effect reflects changes in the relative size of polluting sectors, and thus could have positive or negative environmental implications depending on countries’ factor endowments and comparative advantage. Finally, the technology effect reflects the expectation that trade will contribute to the diffusion of cleaner technologies and to efficiency gains. Trade openness together with restructuring is likely to be associated with environmentally beneficial efficiency and technology gains as well as a cleaner sectoral mix. However, as critics of globalization fear, international competition coupled with the economic hardship of transition may also induce laxer enforcement of environmental regulations and unchecked exploitation of natural resources. Economic theory therefore does not provide clear expectations about the effects of heightened openness on environmental governance. By contrast, the policy effects of trade in transition economies, which is the main focus of our analysis, suggest that a race to the bottom is likely to occur. Two sets of policy-related factors, however, could contribute to a positive relationship between trade and the quality of environmental governance in these countries. First, heightened trade may contribute indirectly – as suggested by the EKC via increasing income – to greater demand for environmental regulations and quality. Second, firms in transition economies that aim to export products to valuable markets with stringent environmental regulations, 8 such as the EU or the United States, may have incentives to press for increased regulatory standards at home (Andonova 2003a; Mol 2001; Vogel 1995). However, we expect these factors to be outweighed by others that contribute to an inverse relationship between trade openness and environmental governance. The political logic of post-Communist states suggests that increased exposure to global markets is likely to stimulate a deterioration of environmental governance. This effect stems from both the demand side and supply side of politics: that is, from firms’ and governments’ incentives in the face of increasing openness. Heightened exposure to foreign competition is likely to put pressure on firms to reduce costs, increasing their resistance to environmental regulations. Governments that levy taxes and fines on firms to finance environment funds increase the costs of production, thereby degrading firms’ competitiveness. Import-competing firms may lose market share to cheaper goods produced overseas. Exporters may find that their products are now more expensive and consequently that they face dampened demand abroad. As trade becomes more important to the economy, more firms are hurt by environmental regulations, thus widening the coalition pressing for their reduction or abolition. This demand-side pressure means that significant opposition to environmental taxes (which support the funds) might exist and grow with rising trade dependence. On the supply side, when governments are trying to build coalitions for market reforms in general, and trade liberalization in particular, they cannot afford to alienate key industrial interests. Hence, such governments may be reluctant to increase taxes or regulations that important economic interests oppose, potentially undermining support for the broader reform package. Furthermore, when trade expands, public officials might 9 lower the taxes and penalties that generate the revenue for environmental funds or reduce their collection efforts out of fear of damaging the competitiveness of crucial domestic industries and thus precipitating a macroeconomic downturn. Such economic problems can jeopardize the government’s hold on power. In sum, then, reductions in environmental budgets or laxity in collecting funds may result from both supply-driven and demand-driven political pressures arising from heightened trade openness. Russia is probably the best-documented case in the region of rapid economic liberalization accompanied by deteriorating environmental governance. This country markedly increased its exposure to world markets in the early 1990s and its foreign trade subsequently soared from around 30% of GDP in 1991 to about 70% by 2000. During the same period, the Federal Ministry of the Environment and Natural Resources, established in 1991, was downgraded to a State Committee on the Environment in 1996 and disbanded altogether in 2000. The enforcement of environmental regulations, charges, taxes, and penalties throughout the decade has been characterized as “abysmal,” and the system of environmental funds was abolished in 2001 (Danilov-Daniliyan 2002; Darst 2001; Kotov and Nikitina 2002; National Intelligence Council 1999; Tavernise 2003; Vovk 2002). Even Russian President Vladimir Putin admitted that “Right now, industries are not held responsible for harming the environment” (quoted in Tavernise 2003). Crucial to the links between trade openness and environmental policy in Russia in the late 1990s are the incentives of both industries and politicians for lax environmental standards. Victor Danilov-Daniliyan (2002), the former Chairman of the State Committee on Environmental Protection, emphasizes that industrial lobbies, fearful that 10 environmental regulations would undercut their international competitiveness and profits, have been instrumental in undermining environmental policy in Russia. Firms, increasingly squeezed by international markets and structural reforms, have demanded exemptions and even the reversals of environmental taxes and penalties, thereby substantially reducing the resource base of national and regional environmental funds (Danilov-Daniliyan 2002; OECD 1999). In fact, Kotov and Nikitina (2002, 12) point out that “in 1996 according to official data about 2412 firms in Russia were exempt from payments for pollution, and for 1251 firms the level of payments was reduced.” Norlisk Nikel, Russia’s largest exporter of nickel and other non-ferrous metals, is a well-document example of a major polluter that was able to secure lax environmental regulations while expanding its share in international markets (Darst 2001; Honneland 2003; Kotov and Nikitina 1996). The company increased its exports significantly during the 1990s, from 87,000 tons in 1993 to 120,000 tons in 1995. It controlled about 26% of the world market for nickel and important shares of the world markets for copper, cobalt, platinum, and palladium (Kotov and Nikitina 1996). As Norilsk Nikel expanded its presence in international markets during the 1990s, it remained Russia’s largest source of air pollution and one of the largest transboundary emitters of sulfur in Europe (Barrett 2000). Citing cost and competitiveness concerns, the enterprise defied international efforts during the 1990s to support pollution abatement and was exempted on a number of occasions from paying domestic pollution taxes and penalties (Honneland 2003; Kotov and Nikitina 1996). In 2001, the Russian Supreme Court even reversed some of the environmental payments of the company, referring to a contradiction between the federal tax law and environmental regulations (Danilov-Daniliyan 2002). 11 The primacy of export-led growth based on Russia’s natural resources has not only increased demand for lax environmental regulation on the part of enterprises, but also reduced the willingness of the Russian government to impose strict environmental regulations. Tavernise (2003), for example, reports that the Russian government has given a free hand to companies in the export-oriented gas, oil, and timber sectors to expand unencumbered by strict environmental regulations. Environmental protection is left largely to the “consciousness” of large domestic and multinational companies operating in these sectors (Tevernise 2003). The increasing share of export earnings in government budgets, combined with other factors such as corrupt institutions and the lack of company transparency, stifles incentives to enforce environmental taxes and penalties that may undermine industries’ competitiveness. In the case of Norilsk Nikel, whose 1995 tax contribution to the budget was in the order of 3 trillion rubles (Kotov and Nikitina 1996), the federal government had a clear interest in supporting the company’s international competitiveness with all possible measures, including lax environmental regulation. Incentives to undersupply environmental enforcement vis-à-vis enterprises engaged in international trade are even stronger at the local level, where such enterprises provided not only tax revenue, but also employment and essential infrastructure (Honneland 2003; Tevernise 2003). The Russian case thus illustrates precisely the mechanisms that environmentalists feared would lead trade openness to stimulate political pressures to relax environmental policies. Compounded by problems such as weak institutions and corruption, globalization has increased both firms’ demands for and the government’s willingness to supply lax enforcement of environmental regulations, which in turn undermined the 12 viability of Russia’s environmental funds. The limited evidence available from other CIS countries similarly suggests that the primacy attributed to export-led growth, coupled with weak institutions and widespread corruption, has resulted in weak implementation of environmental regulations vis-à-vis industrial enterprises and has reduced the funds available for environmental governance (Asian Development Bank 1997; Ichikawa, Tsutsumi, and Watanabe 2002; OECD 2000; Vovk 2003). In the CEE countries, the process of EU integration required significant environmental reforms and partially offset the negative environmental incentives associated with globalization. Even for CEE countries, however, anecdotal accounts have linked competitiveness concerns, weak domestic institutions, and cases of lax environmental control of major industrial polluters (Bluffstone and Larson 1997; Jacoby 1999). Anecdotal evidence is insufficient, however, to determine the prevailing effect of trade and economic liberalization on environmental policy. Case studies reveal that the experiences of countries and, in some cases, even sectors and firms in a single state may vary (Andonova 2003a; Bluffstone and Larson 1997). A more systematic, quantitative analysis is therefore in order to test the prevailing impact of openness on environmental governance. We now turn to such an analysis. A Statistical Model of Environmental Governance Little evidence has been accumulated on whether there is a race to the bottom in environmental standards stemming from commercial globalization. No research that we are aware of focuses on the post-Communist world. However, there is a burgeoning empirical literature on other aspects of the political economy of the environment. Failing 13 to account for the factors emphasized in this literature could yield misleading results if they are systematically related to environmental policy and to globalization. As such, the following model of environmental governance includes many of these factors as well as a variable designed to assess the extent of any race to the bottom among the postCommunist countries. Environmental Governanceit = 0 + 1Opennessit + 2Developmentit + 3Growthit + 4Landit + 5Environmental Governancei(t-1) + eit The dependent variable in this model is the national environmental funds spent by each country, i, in each year, t, divided by i’s national population in t. Data on these expenditures are taken from the OECD (1999a) and the REC (2001a). Data on national population are taken from the World Bank Development Indicators. Most empirical studies of trade and the environment conducted in the last decade analyze the level or intensity of pollution, emphasizing the environmental effects of economic growth, efficiency gains, technology diffusion, and changes in the structure of the economy (e.g., Scruggs 2003). In most of these analyses, therefore, trade influences environmental policy only indirectly by increasing incomes; in fact, per capita income is often used as a proxy for policy (e.g., Copeland and Taylor 2003). While gaining a fuller understanding of such economic processes and their effect on environmental outcomes is obviously important, these studies do not confront directly the race to regulatory bottom hypothesis, which posits that globalization will create political pressure to weaken environmental policies in emerging markets. It has been suggested that lack of adequate data and analyses on regulations and regulatory enforcement may have masked the extent of a regulatory race to the bottom or a regulatory chill stemming from the pressures of 14 globalization (Smarzynska and Wei 2001; Zarsky 1999). We focus precisely on this gap in the literature, examining the relation between trade and the strength of regulatory policies in the post-Communist world. One reason why there is only a limited and inconclusive body of literature addressing the impact of globalization on environmental policy is the difficulty of operationalizing the dependent variable. For advanced industrial countries, the environmental abatement costs of highly polluting industrial sectors have been used as a proxy for the stringency of environmental regulations (Ederington and Minier 2003; Jaffe et al. 1995). Such data, however, are often impossible to obtain for developing countries, especially those with weak and non-transparent institutions, precisely where the race to the bottom effect is likely to be most pronounced and best hidden. Studies that examine the effect of trade on the environmental policies of a broader sample of countries typically resort to using indirect proxies of regulations, such as membership in or ratification of international environmental treaties (Smarzynska and Wei 2001); the strength of environmental nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) (Damania, Fredriksson, and List 2003; Smarzynska and Wei 2001); lead content in petrol (Damania, Fredriksson, and List 2003); and the Dasgupta index of environmental policies (Damania, Fredriksson, and List 2003; Eliste and Fredriksson 2002). While external treaty commitments and the strength of local advocates are likely to influence domestic regulations, these factors offer an incomplete picture of domestic environmental policies and tell us relatively little about the implementation and enforcement of these policies. Only the Dasgupta index is a direct, albeit subjective, measure of environmental regulations. The index measures the level of environmental governance in 1990, based 15 on data from a survey of environmental officials attending the 1992 Earth Summit in Rio de Janeiro (Dasgupta et al. 1995). The Environmental Sustainability Index (ESI) is a more recently constructed policy index of environmental sustainability with a nearly global coverage, but still provides data for only a few isolated years (Levy 2002). Such indicators are generally difficult to construct and controversial, since they involve a subjective decision about what components to include. To overcome the problem of measuring the effect of openness on governmental policy, we use the size of national environmental funds as a proxy for environmental governance in transition countries. As we explained earlier, the environmental funds in post-Communist countries use revenues generated primarily through environmental taxes, fees, and penalties to support environmental investments. By relying on a measure that reflects the stringency and the enforcement of environmental taxes and penalties, our study will be one of the first to address the hypothesis that globalization undermines the political will of states to enforce environmental regulations. Our dependent variable also measures the capacity of governments to implement environmental policy. In developing and transition countries – where enterprises and municipalities are often strapped for capital – government capacity and assistance to offset the costs of pollution abatements is frequently a precondition for implementing environmental rules and reflects the government’s commitment to effective environmental reforms (Andonova 2003a; Haas, Keohane, and Levy 1993; Koehane and Levy 1995). An OECD (1999) survey of environmental funds in post-Communist countries reveals that the largest share of funds financing in the region supported air and water pollution abatement, followed by waste management and nature protection. In the period 16 from 1993 to 1997, for example, Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Estonia, and Poland allocated over 30% (in the Czech Republic, as much as 57%) of their environmental funds for financing for water projects. The financing primarily supported municipal waste water treatment and infrastructure, targeted at improved water quality. Reducing air emissions from industrial enterprises was another priority. Slovenia, Hungary, the Czech Republic, Poland, Bulgaria, and Russia allocated large shares (84%, 22%, 37%, 33%, 9%, and 5% respectively) of their national funds financing to support air pollution abatement projects. Fund resources also went to waste management and in the case of many countries that were formerly part of the Soviet Union (FSU) (such as Russia, Kazakhstan, Ukraine, Moldova, and Uzbekistan) to nature protection. Countries such as Kyrgystan, Moldova, and Uzbekistan that generated relatively limited resources for their funds, were less capable of supporting investments in pollution abatement infrastructure and directed a greater share of fund resources to environmental education, monitoring, research, and strengthening of environmental authorities and NGOs. To be sure, environmental regulation does not necessarily depend on the availability of public financing. The “polluter pays” principle is fundamental to environmental law and is embedded in a range of regulatory instruments such as emission limits, tradable pollution permits, and technology standards. The environmental funds, which reflect environmental taxation and public subsidies, are only one instrument of the environmental policy mix in post-Communist countries. However, in the absence of more comprehensive measures of regulatory stringency, the size of these environmental funds is one of the better proxies for environmental policy outside of OECD countries. Moreover, as Table 1 shows, this measure is positively correlated with other less direct 17 proxies of environmental governance available for selected years, including all of the extant empirical measures used, such as the ratification of international environmental treaties, the 2001 Environmental Sustainability Index, the 1997 index compiled by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) on air pollution regulations, and a measure of the strength of environmental NGOs.4 The relative magnitude of environmental funds across post-Communist countries also corresponds with these countries’ overall environmental policy performance, as documented by qualitative studies. Figure 1 ranks the countries according to the mean value of their annual environmental funds per capita, Environmental Governanceit, which is our dependent variable. At the top of the scale are the Czech Republic, Poland, Hungary, and Slovenia, states that are widely considered to have made the most successful environmental reforms in the post-Communist world (Andonova 2003a; Ichikawa, Tsutsumi, and Watanabe 2002; OECD 1999a; REC 2001a). Government officials in Poland and the Czech Republic have suggested that the ability of these states to institute a strong system of regulation and enforcement early in the transition period and to use the resources generated from enforcement to offset some of the cost of environmental investment has been critical for staying the course of environmental reforms after public support for the environment declined in the 1990s (Andonova 2003a). A survey of economic instruments for environmental policies in CEE indicate that both the Czech Republic and Poland have a system of relatively high air and water pollution charges, Poland’s air pollution charges being among the highest in Europe. Data on environmental treaty participation is taken from the CIESIN’s “Environmental Agreement Dataset,” Columbia University, April 19, 2002. Data on the 2001 Environmental Sustainability Index is found at http://ciesin.columbia.edu/indicators/ESI/ESI_01_tot.pdf. For the EBRD index, see EBRD 1997. The measure of NGO strength is the number of IUCN member organizations by year for each country. These data were obtained from the IUCN. 4 18 Slovenia has been one of the first European countries to introduce a tax on carbon dioxide emissions, intended to raise revenue as well as to provide incentives for less carbon intensive development. These countries also have collection efficiency rates of approximately 97%, which compare favorably to other CEE countries, such as Bulgaria and Lithuania, where collection efficiency rates for penalties and taxes are only 50%80% and 50%-60% (REC 1999). While similar data on environmental taxes and collection rates are not available for FSU countries, numerous anecdotal accounts point to the weak enforcement capacity and corruption, and the resulting low or nonexistent collection of environmental fees and fines as a major impediment to effective environmental governances (Ichikawa, Tsutsumi, and Watanabe 2002; Kotov and Nikitina 1996; OECD 1999a; OECD 2000). Not surprisingly, countries with the weakest capacity for environmental governance – such as Moldova, Azerbaijan, Uzbekistan, and Turkmenistan – rank lowest on the scale of environmental funds (see Figure 1). Turning to the independent variables, Opennessit is the sum of state i’s imports and exports divided by its GDP in year t. Globalization is a multifaceted concept. As noted earlier, we focus on the globalization of foreign trade because many studies analyzing whether there is a race to the bottom of environmental regulation center on trade (Andonova 2003a; Copeland and Taylor 2004; Frankel and Rose 2002) and because trade is obviously a crucial aspect of globalization (Garrett 1998; Rodrik 1997). Later, however, we examine whether the impact of globalization on environmental governance stems from other aspects of economic openness in the post-Communist world. The remaining independent variables are included to account for political and economic factors that previous research has linked to environmental policy. Over the 19 past decade, studies of the environment have displayed a growing interest in the effects of per capita income (Grossman and Krueger 1993). As we mentioned earlier, much of this research focuses on the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Underlying the EKC is the argument that as poor countries experience rising per capita income, pollution first increases and then – after reaching some threshold – declines. The fall-off in pollution, according to this argument, stems from the tendency for economic development to promote environmental concerns in society and a heightened demand for stricter environmental policies, technological advances that are environmentally friendly, and an increasing share of services (relative to manufacturing) in the economy.5 The EKC is thus premised on the view that a positive relationship exists between per capita income and environmental policy after a certain level of development is reached. For the transition countries – with both an average per capita income of about $4500 and widespread concerns about high pollution levels inherited from communism – we anticipate that a positive relationship will exist between per capita income and the resources a country is willing and able to collect and earmark for environmental spending (Smarzynska and Shang-Jin Wei 2001). To test this hypothesis, we analyze Developmentit, which is the natural logarithm of per capita GDP of state i in year t. In the same vein, some recent research has found that economic growth increases the demand for environmental quality (Bhagwati 1993; Copeland and Taylor 2004; Lofdahl 2002). We therefore analyze Growthit, which is the percentage change in country i’s GDP from year t-1 to year t. 5 Various studies have estimated the local maximum or tipping point of this inverted U-shaped relationship to be somewhere between $2,000 and $5,000 per capita, depending on the polluting substance and estimation method used, although some estimates run as high as $10,000-$15,000 per capita (Stern, Common, and Barbier 1996). 20 Next, Landit is the natural logarithm of the land area of state i.6 We include this variable because various studies have suggested that land area affects pollution levels (Frankel and Rose 2002; Lofdahl 2002; Mitchell 2003). Furthermore, all else being equal, it is harder to effectively regulate the environment as the size of what is to be regulated increases. This, in turn, implies that a larger land mass may be associated with less environmental governance. To account for any temporal dependence in the data, we include a lagged dependent variable, Environmental Governancei(t-1). Finally, eit is a stochastic error term. Our sample is made up of all post-Communist states for which data on environmental governance are available (OECD 1999a; REC 2001a) over the period from 1994 to 1999 (years t).7 After pooling these data across states and over time, we estimate the model using least squares regression. Tests of statistical significance are based on Huber (robust) standard errors that account for any heteroskedasticity in the data and for the fact that the data are grouped by country. The Statistical Results The results of this analysis are shown in the first column of Table 2. They indicate that our model provides a good fit to the data, explaining 85% of the variation in Environmental Governanceit. Moreover, the results provide strong evidence that heightened commercial openness undermines environmental governance in the postCommunist world. Consistent with our argument that greater exposure to the 6 Data on openness, per capita GDP, growth, and land are taken from the World Bank Development Indicators (cd-rom). Note that data on per capita GDP are expressed in constant US dollars adjusted for purchasing power parity. 7 The only post-communist countries excluded from our sample due to the absence of data are Armenia, Bosnia, Georgia, Lithuania, Macedonia, Mongolia, Romania, and Yugoslavia. 21 international economy has led to a race the bottom in the region, the estimate of Opennessit is negative and statistically significant. The effect of this variable is also substantively large. Increasing the mean value of Opennessit by one standard deviation yields more than a one-third decline in the predicted value of Environmental Governanceit. Not surprisingly, a post-Communist country’s trade regime is only one of various factors affecting its environmental policy. Contemporary environmental policy is also heavily influenced by this policy in the recent past, as indicated by the positive and statistically significant estimate of the lagged endogenous variable. Of greater substantive interest is the tendency for environmental standards to rise with the extent of economic development and the rate of economic growth, since the estimates of Developmentit and Growthit are positive and statistically significant. Equally, states with a smaller land mass tend to have more extensive environmental regulation than their larger counterparts, since the estimate of Landit is negative and significant. Having generated some initial estimates of our model, it is important to assess the robustness of these results. First, we address some issues regarding the estimation of our model. In order to model the dynamics in our data, we have relied on a lagged endogenous variable. An alternative approach is to estimate our model using feasible generalized least squares (FGLS), a technique that involves estimating the parameter coefficients using ordinary least squares and then purging the errors of serial correlation. Recent research indicates that there are substantial advantages to modeling dynamics via a lagged dependent variable rather than FGLS, especially when the number of temporal observations is relatively small (Beck and Katz 1996, 14). In light of the fact that our 22 analysis covers the period from 1994 to 1999, the approach we have taken is therefore entirely appropriate. Nonetheless, we also omit the lagged endogenous variable and estimate the model using FGLS and assuming that the errors for each state follow a firstorder autoregressive process common to all post-Communist countries. Like our earlier results, the estimate of Opennessit is negative and statistically significant. Furthermore, the remaining estimates are much the same as before, except that the coefficient of Growthit is no longer significant. Another issue concerning the estimation of our model is whether there are factors that are specific to countries in the region (for example, their history or culture) affecting environmental policy. We have assumed that there are no such factors. To address this assumption in more detail, however, we also experimented with including countryspecific fixed effects. The results do not allow us to reject the null hypothesis that the fixed effects should be omitted (F = .72; p = .78). Equally, a Breusch and Pagan (1980) Lagrange multiplier test provides no indication that the model should be estimated using a random effects specification. As such, there is no reason to be concerned that our results are threatened by unmeasured heterogeneity in the data. Second, it is useful to determine whether the results are being driven by any particular post-Communist state. We therefore re-estimate the model after removing each of the seventeen states in our sample, one at a time. The results are remarkably consistent. There is no case in which an estimate in the first column of Table 2 changes sign. There are only three instances where a statistically significant estimate becomes insignificant, all of which involve Growthit. Most important for our purposes, however, 23 is that the estimate of Opennessit is negative, statistically significant, and relatively large in each of these seventeen regressions. As such, no single country is driving our results. Third, we have treated the effects of Opennessit as exogenous. It is also important, however, to ensure that our results are not undermined by any simultaneity bias that could emerge if a country’s environmental policy affects its trade openness (Frankel and Rose 2002). Lately, various observers have advanced a “pollution haven” hypothesis (Copeland and Taylor 2004). Countries with environmental policies that impose substantial costs on firms may see their trade competitiveness erode and firms migrate to countries with laxer regulatory regimes. Costly environmental policies might then stimulate a rise in imports, thereby threatening domestic industries and increasing unemployment. Hence, trade patterns could be shaped by the extent and nature of countries’ environmental policies. To address this issue, we re-estimate our model using instrumental variables regression. Recent research indicates that the trade policies of post-Communist countries are influenced by their GDP and regime type, the number of “veto players” in government, and whether they were part of the Soviet Union (Frye and Mansfield 2003). To create an instrument for Opennessit, we use these variables, the four independent variables other than Opennessit in our model, and a dummy variable indicating whether each country was a member of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) or the World Trade Organization (WTO).8 The results of this analysis are reported in the second column of Table 2 and continue to furnish strong evidence of a race to bottom in the region. The estimate of Opennessit is negative and statistically significant. 8 Data used to construct this instrument are taken from Frye and Mansfield (2003) and from the WTO (http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/tif_e/org6_e.htm). 24 Furthermore, it is virtually the same size regardless of whether we treat Opennessit as endogenous or exogenous. Fourth, we have defined trade openness as the sum of each country’s exports and imports in each year, divided by its GDP in that year. Although this measure is very widely used, it is useful to consider whether the effects of openness are primarily determined by either imports or exports. To this end, we replace Opennessit with country i’s imports divided by its GDP in year t. We then replace it with i’s exports divided by its GDP. The results – shown in the third and fourth columns of Table 2 – indicate that the estimates of these variables are the same size and that both of them are negative and statistically significant. Consequently, the observed effects of trade openness on environmental policy are not being driven by either imports or exports alone. The Effects of International Institutions Another issue that merits attention is whether variables that are not included in our model account for the observed effect of openness on environmental governance. A wide variety of tests, however, provide no evidence of this sort. To ensure that openness does not reflect other aspects of trade policy, we include a variable indicating whether state i had formally applied for membership in the European Union (EU) as of year t, another variable indicating whether i had signed an association agreement with the EU as of t, and a third variable measuring whether i was a party to the GATT or the WTO in t.9 As reported in the first three columns of Table 3, these variables do not have a strong 9 Data on EU membership and association agreements are taken from Europa (http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/pas/europe_agr.htm). Data on GATT/WTO membership are taken from WTO (http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/tif_e/org6_e.htm). 25 influence on environmental governance. Moreover, including them in our model has little effect on the size of Opennessit and no effect on its sign or significance level. These findings do not imply that the EU had had no effect on environmental regulation in the post-Communist world. In fact, recent research provides considerable evidence that it played a key role in stimulating the reform of environmental regulations in the Central and East European countries that were candidates for EU membership (Andonova 2003a; Baker and Jehlicka 1998; Holzinger and Knoepfel 2000).10 Our data suggests that there is high correlation between the level of countries’ Development and their EU Applicant or EU Association status (correlation coefficient .88 and .50 respectively), which partially accounts for the lack of statistical significance of the EU variables in our model. Our results also indicate that while the EU may have had a strong impact on the adoption of environmental laws in Central and Eastern Europe, its impact on environmental policy implementation in the broader sample of post-Communist countries is much weaker, particularly after we control for level of development. Nonetheless, various studies have found that other international institutions have a pronounced influence on environmental quality. One set of studies concludes that states participating in international environmental institutions and protocols realize a reduction in pollution levels (Helm and Sprinz 2000; Mitchell 2003). As such, we analyze Treaty Participationit, which is the number of environmental treaties and protocols to which state i is a party, as of year t.11 Another set of studies emphasizes that institutions designed to promote economic development became an important part of the 10 The ten transition countries that are in the process of EU membership negotiations are: Bulgaria, Hungary, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, the Czech Republic, Poland, Romania, Slovakia, and Slovenia. 11 Data for this variable are taken from the CIESIN’s “Environmental Agreement Dataset,” Columbia University, April 19, 2002. 26 transnational policy network established to support environmental reforms in transition countries. The first decade of post-Communist transitions coincided with increased pressure for the greening of multilateral development institutions (Gutner 2002; Nielson and Tierney 2003). The World Bank, for example, saw an opportunity in the region to increase the share of its environmental lending and to stimulate policies encouraging both greater economic efficiency and environmental improvements (Connolly, Gutner, and Bedarf 1996; Gutner 2002). More generally, international financial institutions (IFIs) might insist that states improve the quality of environmental governance as precondition for granting assistance; or the receipt of assistance could promote growth, thereby increasing the demand for environmental quality, as we discussed earlier. On the other hand, states receiving economic assistance from an IFI may be unable or unwilling to devote scarce resources to improving environmental governance. To address these issues, we analyze three dummy variables indicating whether state i receives aid (loans or grants) from the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF), or the EBRD, respectively, in year t.12 Of these three variables and Treaty Participationit, only the EBRD has a statistically significant effect on environmental regulation. As shown in Table 3, post-Communist states that receive aid from this organization have relatively poor environmental governance, which probably reflects the tendency for the EBRD to assist countries with especially serious economic and environmental problems. Nonetheless, including these variables has no bearing on the 12 Data on IMF assistance are taken from Vreeland (2003); data on EBRD loans are taken from EBRD (various years); and data on World Bank assistance are taken from World Bank (http://lnweb18.worldbank.org/ECA/eca.nsf/General/E6B6CA3E53D868DB85256C37005CC332?OpenDo cument). 27 estimate of Opennessit, providing additional evidence of a race to the bottom in the postCommunist world.13 The Effects of Domestic Politics Besides international institutions, domestic political conditions might affect both commercial openness and environmental regulation. One obvious possibility is that a country’s regime type influences both factors. Various studies have found that democracy fosters trade liberalization (Frye and Mansfield 2003, 2004; Milner with Kubota forthcoming). There has also been some speculation that democracy may promote environmental governance (Frankel 2003). To measure each state’s regime type, we rely on two variables. The first is Polityit, a 21-point index that was developed by Jaggers and Gurr (1995).14 This variable measures five institutional features in state i as of year t and ranges from -10 for a highly autocratic state to 10 for a highly democratic one. The second, ACLPit, was developed by Przeworski, Alvarez, Cheibub, and Limongi (2000). It equals one if elections in country i are contested as of year t, 0 otherwise. As shown in the first two columns of Table 4, neither measure of regime type has a statistically significant effect on environmental governance. Nor does including these variables influence the coefficient of Opennessit. In addition, a number of recent studies have concluded that the fragmentation of political power has spurred reform in post-Communist countries (Frye and Mansfield 13 In addition to analyzing whether the receipt of aid or loans influences environmental governance, we also addressed the effects of loans that are earmarked for environmental purposes. More specifically, we include the total value (in dollars) of all “brown” and “green” loans that country i received in year t from the EBRD or from the World Bank, respectively, using data compiled by Parks, Tierney, Roberts and Hicks (2004). Neither variable, however, is statistically significant and including them (separately or together) has no effect on the remaining variables in the model. 14 Data for this variable are taken from http://weber.ucsd.edu/~kgledits/Polity.html and ftp://isere.colorado.edu/pub/datasets/p4/p4vksg.asc. 28 2003; Hellman 1997, 1998). To analyze whether fragmentation has promoted environmental reform, we include two variables. First, Presidential Powerit is a measure of the extent to which power is concentrated in a country’s chief executive. It was developed by Shugart and Carey (1992) and modified by Frye (2002) to the fit the postCommunist world. As the value of this variable declines, fragmentation rises. Second, Fragmentationit is a five-point index of the concentration of political power within country i’s national government in year t. Created by Frye, Hellman, and Tucker (2000), this variable adapts to the post-Communist countries Roubini and Sachs’ (1989) measure of the number of partisan actors that can block policy change. We also include a measure of political partisanship that indicates whether country i’s chief executive is leftist, rightist, or centrist (Frye 2002). There is reason to expect that right-of-center leaders will be especially pro-business and therefore reluctant to impose regulations (environmental or otherwise) on industry. Such leaders might also be inclined to liberalize trade. Partisanship could therefore account for the inverse relationship between the openness of overseas commerce and environmental governance. Finally, we include variables indicating whether country i is a former Soviet republic or whether it was at war (either external or civil) in year t. A number of studies have found that less reform has taken place in countries that were part of the Soviet Union than in other post-Communist states (Andonova 2003a; Asland, Boone, and Johnson 1996); and war may create additional pollution and reduce the willingness of public officials to impose environmental regulations on industry.15 15 Data for these variables are taken from Frye (2002), Frye, Hellman, and Tucker (2000), and (in the case of war) the Correlates of War Project (http://cow2.la.psu.edu). 29 As shown in Table 4, however, none of these variables has a strong influence on environmental governance. Furthermore, including them has very little bearing on the estimated effects of trade openness. These results therefore provide no evidence that domestic political conditions underlie the race to the bottom in the post-Communist world. The Effects of Economic, Demographic, Geographic, and Environmental Conditions In addition to political factors, it is important to ensure that economic and demographic factors, as well as the environmental conditions that governments inherited after the collapse of the Berlin Wall, do not account for the inverse relationship between openness and environmental regulation. First, it is well known that economically large states tend to be less open than their smaller counterparts. Large states may also be better able to raise sizeable national environmental funds. Second, aggregate government spending might be driving this relationship. Governments might spend large sums of money on the environment because they are generally interventionist. If so, they also might be inclined to regulate overseas commerce, thereby reducing openness, and to spend freely on various social, economic, and political activities. Third, in countries where the domestic oil industry plays an important economic role, the oil and gas sector is likely to be politically potent and to fight efforts to regulate pollution. Since this sector is likely to depend on foreign markets and therefore to have a preference for commercial openness, whether a country derives substantial revenues from oil could account for the inverse relationship between openness and environmental 30 regulation.16 Fourth, it is important to consider the effects of foreign direct investment (FDI). The race to the bottom argument suggests that greater exposure to international markets stimulates increasing pressure to reduce environmental standards, since countries with higher standards will suffer economically if foreign firms choose to locate in and do business elsewhere. One implication of this argument is that the flows of FDI into state i in year t should not be positively associated with the extent of environmental regulation. Fifth, a recent study has found that economic and political reform in the postCommunist world has followed a pattern of spatial diffusion (Kopstein and Reilly 2000). Countries with capitals that are geographically close to the West have engaged in more extensive reforms than countries that are farther away. It is useful to see whether such diffusion might be driving the inverse relationship between openness and environmental regulation. Sixth, some research has indicated that pollution tends to rise with population density (Frankel and Rose 2002). If increased pollution stimulates greater environmental regulation and if greater population density spurs demands to restrict openness (perhaps by increasing unemployment, which often creates protectionist demands), then population density might be driving our earlier results. Seventh, it is important to consider the effects of the environmental conditions at the time of the Soviet bloc’s demise. Countries with especially serious initial environmental problems might be expected to spend more to resolve these problems during the 1990s. As shown in Table 5, however, none of these factors has a strong influence on environmental governance in the post-Communist world. We included the GDP of 16 The same might also be the case for states with a large manufacturing sector. Further, a large sector of this sort might contribute to high levels of pollution, sizable taxes on this pollution, and hence large environmental funds. However, we find no evidence that a country’s manufacturing value added as a percentage of its GDP in year t is strongly related to environmental governance, and the estimate of Opennessit remains negative and statistically significant when this variable is included in the model. 31 country i in year t, i’s government spending as a percentage of GDP in t, a dummy variable indicating whether it was heavily dependent on oil revenue, its net inflows of FDI in t, its population density in t, the distance (in miles) between its capital city and Vienna, its SO2 emissions (in metric tons) per populated kilometer in 1990, and its NOx emissions (in metric tons) per populated kilometer in 1990.17 None of these variables has a statistically significant effect on Environmental Governanceit. Moreover, including them has no bearing on the sign, size, or significance of Opennessit. Finally, we considered the effects of the existing environmental conditions for each country in every year analyzed here. Doing so is useful because the inverse relationship between openness and environmental regulation could stem from a tendency for heightened trade to drive highly polluting firms out of business, thereby reducing the taxes collected on such firms and consequently the size of the environmental funds. Indeed, this possibility is suggested by the composition effect that we mentioned earlier and that has been emphasized in some economic research on the environment (e.g., Copeland and Taylor 2004). To address this possibility, we examine the effects of aggregate SO2 emissions and aggregate NOx emissions for country i in year t, SO2 emissions per capita and NOx emissions for i in t, and the change in both types of emissions for i between years t-1 and t, respectively.18 We find no evidence, however, that any of these variables has a statistically significant effect on environmental governance. Moreover, regardless of which of these variables is analyzed, the estimate of 17 Data for these variables are taken from the World Bank Development Indicators, Frye (2002), and the Environmental Sustainability Index (http://ciesin.columbia.edu/indicators/ESI/ESI_01_tot.pdf). 18 Data on aggregate SO2 and NOx emissions is taken from the Cooperative Program for Monitoring and Evaluation of the Long-Range Transmission of Environmental Pollutants in Europe (EMEP) accessed via http://www.emep.int/index_data.html, in December 2004; and from Eco-Portal Central Asia accessed via http://www.eco-portal.kz/modules.php?name=News&file=article&sid=35#21, in December 2004. 32 Opennessit is negative, large, and statistically significant. Indeed, these results continue to provide strong evidence of a race to the bottom in the post-Communist world. Conclusion The countries of East-Central Europe and the former Soviet Union have undergone massive transformations over the past fifteen years. Particularly important have been the efforts made by many of these states to increase their integration into the global economy. Heightened commercial openness has yielded many benefits, but it has also reduced the ability of governments to exercise environmental governance. Rising exposure to international economic competition has seemingly reduced both the demand for and the supply of environmental reform and regulation in post-Communist countries. Demands by firms for lower environmental taxes and laxer regulation have multiplied, hampering governmental efforts to collect such taxes and enforce regulations. Moreover, faced with making fundamental economic and political transitions as well as the pressures stemming from globalization, governments have placed less emphasis on environmental governance as their exposure to global markets has increased. Both anecdotal and statistical evidence strongly supports our argument that heightened openness has led to an environmental race to the bottom in the post-Communist world. Scholars studying other regions have suggested that the pressures exerted by globalization can be constrained and reshaped by domestic political institutions (Adsera and Boix 2002; Garrett 1998; Swank 2002). In post-Communist countries, however, heightened openness is associated with weak environmental governance even after controlling for a range of institutional factors. Furthermore, these factors have little 33 effect on environmental regulation, a finding that may stem from the relative weakness of political institutions in transition economies. This suggests that where domestic institutions are weak, policymakers may have difficulty restraining and reshaping the pressures stemming from globalization. Only when political institutions have strengthened and matured can countries pursue both an open economy and a cleaner environment. A second reason why domestic political factors appear to have little direct impact on environmental governance is related to the salience of environmental concerns in transition states. Unlike economic reforms and restructuring, which have been hotly contested issues, environmental governance in these countries fell to the bottom of the political agenda over the course of the 1990s. Neither leftist nor rightist governments had well-defined environmental strategies. Apparently, globalization and concern with economic redistribution have overridden any tendency for leftist parties, which are elsewhere more sympathetic to environmental concerns, to play that role in transition countries. If anything, leftist post-Communist parties that were closely associated with the business interests of the “red directors” have had even fewer incentives to pursue increase environmental standards. Similarly, political polarization, which enables the groups that gain from partial economic reforms to block policy change, has had little effect on the stringency of environmental regulation. In most transition countries, interest groups with sufficient political leverage have evoked concerns over competitiveness to demand lenient application of environmental rules. The process of global integration and economic liberalization may have indeed overwhelmed the political agenda of transition 34 states at the expense of other important issues, a proposition that merits further exploration in the post-Communist literature. Such an interpretation of the limited effect of domestic politics is consistent with the evidence provided by the case study literature on environmental policy in the transition economies, which emphasizes the low political priority attributed to the environment (Carter and Turnock 2002; Kotov and Nikitina 1996, 2002; Pavlinek and Pickles 2001). Only states that were able to lock in environmental reforms early in the 1990s have had a lasting record of improved environmental governance (Andonova 2003a). That the lagged dependent variable in our model is positive and highly significant is consistent with this view: the effects of those environmental policies that are implemented tend to persist from one year to the next. The role of international institutions is also interesting. In general, these institutions seem to have had little effect on environmental governance in the postCommunist world. Neither the GATT/WTO, nor the EU, nor the IMF, nor the World Bank appears to exert much direct influence on these environmental funds. Only participation in the EBRD loan programs seems to have an impact, and a negative one at that. These findings diverge from case study analyses concluding that the EU has influenced environmental policy in CEE states (Andonova 2003a; Holzinger and Knoepfel 2000) and that international donor institutions have been active proponents of reform in post-Communist states (Gutner 2002; Weinthal 2002). This discrepancy suggests that international institutions may be more important at some stages of environmental policymaking than others. The extant literature implies that international institutions can facilitate agreements and the formal adoption of 35 international environmental norms, but that they often have only weak and at best indirect effects on the stringency of domestic implementation (Haas, Keohane, and Levy 1993; Victor, Raustalia, and Skolnikoff 1998; Wise and Jacobson 1998). Our measure of environmental policy reflects both the government’s ability to legislate and its desire to enforce environmental regulations. It appears that international institutions in this region have not played a significant role in offsetting pressures for lax implementation associated with globalization. Perhaps this is an area where they might focus more attention, given the difficulties that national governments may have in doing it alone. Our research indicates that for countries undergoing massive social, economic, and political transformation, increasing trade openness creates pressures to reduce environmental governance. But this finding does not imply that heightened protectionism is the best way to improve the environment in transition countries. As political institutions mature, these countries may become better able to shape globalization to their benefit. Furthermore, the positive scale, composition, and technology effects associated with trade might arise only over longer periods of time. In the medium run, trade may promote economic growth and in the long run it may enhance aggregate wealth, both of which are likely to foster better environmental policy and outcomes. Over time, trade may also promote a more environmentally friendly mix of industries. It is too early in these countries’ transition to open, market-based systems to counsel protectionism and closure, all of which would slow down their economic modernization and the countervailing pressures it brings for environmental reform. 36 Table 1. Correlations between Environmental Governance and Alternative Measures of Environmental Policy. --------------------- Measure ----------------------Treaty Ratification EBRD ESI NGOs 0.26* 0.86* 0.55* 0.53* * indicates that the bivariate correlation is statistically significant at the .05 level. Note: Treaty Ratification measures participation in international environmental treaties; EBRD is a 1997 index compiled by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development on air pollution regulations; ESI is the 2001 Environmental Sustainability Index; and NGO is a measure of the strength of environmental NGOs. See also fn. 4. 37 Table 2. The Effects of Trade Openness, Economic Development, Growth, and Geographical Size on Environmental Governance. - - - - - - - - - - - - Model - - - - - - - - - (1.1) (1.2)a (1.3) (1.4) Intercept -6.83*** (1.80) -6.13** (2.29) -5.70*** (1.85) -7.58*** (1.91) Openness -0.015** (0.006) -0.016** (0.007) ____ ____ Development 1.68*** (0.34) 1.59*** (0.38) 1.53*** (0.31) 1.69*** (0.36) Growth 0.035* (0.018) 0.038* (0.020) 0.037* (0.018) 0.035* (0.018) Land -0.399*** (0.188) -0.385*** (0.129) -0.401*** (0.116) -0.366*** (0.111) Lagged Environmental Governance 0.682*** (0.045) 0.688*** (0.056) 0.689*** (0.055) 0.688*** (0.055) Variable Imports ____ ____ -0.026** (0.010) Exports ____ ____ ____ N R2 94 82 0.85 0.85 94 0.85 ____ -0.026** (0.012) 94 0.85 Note: Entries are feasible generalized least squares estimates with robust (Huber) standard errors in parentheses. For presentational purposes, each estimate except that of Lagged Environmental Governance is multiplied by 1,000,000. a Estimates are generated using instrumental variables regression. *** p < .01; ** p < .05; * p < .10. Two-tailed tests of statistical significance are conducted for all estimates. 38 Table 3. The Effects of Trade Openness on Environmental Governance, Controlling for International Institutions. Variable - - - - - - - - - - - - Model - - - - - - - - - (2.1) (2.2) (2.3) (2.4) Intercept -10.90*** (3.37) -9.56*** (2.14) -6.81*** (2.10) -8.66*** (2.77) Openness -0.020** (0.009) -0.018** (0.008) -0.015** (0.006) -0.017** (0.007) Development 2.57*** (0.77) 2.29*** (0.56) 1.67*** (0.44) 1.90*** (0.47) Growth 0.044* (0.024) 0.041* (0.020) 0.035* (0.018) 0.037* (0.020) Land -0.594** (0.213) -0.540*** (0.184) -0.397*** (0.137) -0.371*** (0.102) Lagged Environmental Governance 0.665*** (0.055) 0.678*** (0.051) 0.682*** (0.053) 0.672*** (0.055) EU Applicant -1.49 (1.14) ____ ____ ____ EU Association ____ -0.99 (0.72) ____ ____ GATT/WTO ____ ____ 0.014 (0.382) ____ Treaty Participation ____ ____ ____ -0.005 (0.006) N R2 94 94 0.86 0.86 39 94 0.85 94 0.85 Variable - - - - - - - - - - - Model - - - - - - - - - (2.5) (2.6) (2.7) Intercept -7.15*** (2.09) -6.34*** (2.14) -9.54*** (2.03) Openness -0.014** (0.006) -0.022*** (0.006) -0.016** (0.006) Development 1.68*** (0.34) 1.72*** (0.47) 2.04*** (0.31) Growth 0.036* (0.019) 0.033* (0.017) 0.044** (0.020) Land -0.393*** (0.118) -0.455*** (0.142) -0.360*** (0.114) Lagged Environmental Governance 0.689*** (0.057) 0.713*** (0.075) 0.666*** (0.059) World Bank 0.177 (0.411) ____ ____ IMF ____ 0.709 (0.411) ____ EBRD ____ ____ N R2 94 94 0.85 0.86 -0.825** (0.351) 94 0.86 Note: Entries are feasible generalized least squares estimates with robust (Huber) standard errors in parentheses. For presentational purposes, each estimate except that of Lagged Environmental Governance is multiplied by 1,000,000. *** p < .01; ** p < .05; * p < .10. Two-tailed tests of statistical significance are conducted for all estimates. 40 Table 4. The Effects of Trade Openness on Environmental Governance, Controlling for Political Conditions. - - - - - - - - - - - - Model - - - - - - - - - (3.1) (3.2) (3.3) (3.4) Intercept -7.54*** (2.56) -5.80** (2.45) -6.52*** (2.00) -8.09*** (2.40) Openness -0.015** (0.006) -0.021*** (0.007) -0.017** (0.007) -0.015** (0.006) Development 1.80*** (0.45) 1.75*** (0.42) 1.76*** (0.42) 1.91*** (0.41) Growth 0.031 (0.021) 0.034* (0.019) 0.038* (0.019) 0.029 (0.020) Land -0.419*** (0.131) -0.467*** (0.123) -0.448*** (0.130) -0.492*** (0.154) Lagged Environmental Governance 0.681*** (0.056) 0.680*** (0.058) 0.681*** (0.058) 0.678*** (0.055) Regime Type (Polity) -0.016 (0.031) ____ ____ ____ Regime Type (ACLP) ____ -0.223 (0.310) ____ ____ Veto Points ____ ____ -0.095 (0.184) ____ Presidential Power ____ ____ ____ 0.041 (0.032) Variable N R2 94 94 0.85 0.85 41 74 0.85 94 0.85 Variable - - - - - - - - - - - - Model - - - - - - - - - (3.5) (3.6) (3.7) Intercept -5.03* (2.48) -8.34*** (2.66) -6.89*** (2.03) Openness -0.016** (0.007) -0.019** (0.009) -0.015** (0.006) Development 1.54*** (0.41) 1.99*** (0.58) 1.68*** (0.34) Growth 0.038** (0.017) 0.034* (0.018) 0.035* (0.019) Land -0.469*** (0.157) -0.488*** (0.182) -0.396*** (0.129) Lagged Environmental Governance 0.712*** (0.097) 0.691*** (0.052) 0.682*** (0.058) Partisanship 0.139 (0.222) ____ ____ Former Soviet Republic ____ 0.569 (0.616) ____ War ____ ____ -0.036 (0.317) N R2 76 94 0.87 0.85 94 0.85 Note: Entries are feasible generalized least squares estimates with robust (Huber) standard errors in parentheses. For presentational purposes, each estimate except that of Lagged Environmental Governance is multiplied by 1,000,000. *** p < .01; ** p < .05; * p < .10. Two-tailed tests of statistical significance are conducted for all estimates. 42 Table 5. The Effects of Trade Openness on Environmental Governance, Controlling for Economic, Demographic, Geographic, and Pre-existing Environmental Conditions. - - - - - - - - - - - - Model - - - - - - - - - (4.1) (4.2) (4.3) (4.4) Intercept -6.55*** (2.26) -9.84** (3.57) -7.28*** (1.92) -6.63*** (1.71) Openness -0.015** (0.006) -0.017** (0.007) -0.014** (0.006) -0.015** (0.006) Development 1.66*** (0.37) 1.86*** (0.42) 1.66*** (0.35) 1.91*** (0.33) Growth 0.035* (0.018) 0.053* (0.029) 0.038* (0.019) 0.037* (0.019) Land -0.412*** (0.131) -0.353*** (0.117) -0.352** (0.144) -0.404*** (0.120) Lagged Environmental Governance 0.682*** (0.057) 0.699*** (0.058) 0.678*** (0.059) 0.681*** (0.057) GDP 4.01 10-13 (1.47 10-12) Variable ____ ____ ____ ____ ____ Government Spending ____ 0.037 (0.026) Oil ____ ____ -0.283 (0.297) ____ FDI ____ ____ ____ -0.012 (0.026) N R2 94 67 0.85 0.88 43 94 0.85 94 0.85 - - - - - - - - - - - - Model - - - - - - - - - (4.6) (4.7) Variable (4.5) Intercept -7.02*** (1.65) -6.95*** (2.34) -6.96*** (1.89) -6.79*** (1.79) Openness -0.015** (0.006) -0.015** (0.006) -0.015** (0.006) -0.015** (0.006) Development 1.68*** (0.34) 1.69*** (0.40) 1.70*** (0.35) 1.70*** (0.36) Growth 0.035* (0.019) 0.035* (0.018) 0.037 (0.023) 0.037 (0.022) Land -0.389** (0.150) -0.403*** (0.124) -0.406*** (0.123) -0.415*** (0.131) Lagged Environmental Governance 0.680*** (0.054) 0.682*** (0.057) 0.686*** (0.062) 0.681*** (0.056) Population Density 0.001 (0.003) Miles from Vienna ____ SO2 per km (1990) ____ NOx per km (1990) ____ N R2 ____ ____ ____ ____ ____ ____ 0.032 (0.133) ____ ____ ____ 0.045 (0.231) 1.83 10-5 (1.32 10-4) 94 94 0.85 (4.8) 0.85 91 0.85 91 0.85 Note: Entries are feasible generalized least squares estimates with robust (Huber) standard errors in parentheses. For presentational purposes, each estimate except that of Lagged Environmental Governance is multiplied by 1,000,000. *** p < .01; ** p < .05; * p < .10. Two-tailed tests of statistical significance are conducted for all estimates. 44 Figure 1. Mean Annual Environmental Fund Expenditures. CzechR. Poland Slovenia Hungary SlovakR. Estonia Belarus Bulgaria Latvia Kazakhstan Ukraine Lithuania Russia KyrgyzR. Moldova Azerbaijan Uzbekistan Turkmenistan $0.00 $2.00 $4.00 $6.00 US$ per capita 45 $8.00 $10.00 References Adsera, Alicia, and Carles Boix. 2002. “Trade, Democracy, and the Size of the Public Sector: The Political Underpinnings of Openness.” International Organization 56 (Spring): 229-62. Andersson, Magnus. 1999. Change and Continuity in Poland's Environmental Policy. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Andonova, Liliana. 2002. “The Challenges and Opportunities for Reforming Bulgaria’s Energy Sector.” Environment 44 (December): 8-19. Andonova, Liliana. 2003a. Transnational Politics of the Environment. The EU and Environmental Policy in Central and Eastern Europe. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Andonova, Liliana. 2003b. “Openness and the Environment in Central and Eastern Europe: Can Trade and Foreign Investment Stimulate Better Environmental Management in Enterprises?” Journal of Environment and Development 12 (2): 177-204. Asian Development Bank (ADB). 1997. Central Asian Environments in Transition. Manila: ADB. Aslund, Anders, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson. 1996. “How to Stabilize: Lessons from Post-Communist Countries.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 217-311. Baker, Susan, and Petr Jehlicka, eds. 1998. Dilemmas of Transition: The Environment, Democracy and Economic Reform in East Central Europe. Special Issue of Environmental Politics 7 (1). Barrett, Mark. 2000. “The Worst and the Best: Atmospheric Emissions from Large Point Sources in Europe.” Report of the Swedish NGO Secretariat on Acid Rain. Beck, Nathaniel, and Jonathan N. Katz.1996. “Nuisance vs. Substance: Specifying and Estimating Time-Series-Cross-Section Models.” Political Analysis 6: 1-36. Bhagwati, Jagdish N. 1993. “The Case for Free Trade.” Scientific American (November): 42-49. Bluffstone, Randall, and Bruce A. Larson, eds. 1997. Controlling Pollution in Transition Economies: Theories and Methods. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Breusch, T., and A. Pagan. 1980. “The Lagrange Multiplier Test and its Applications to Model Specification in Econometrics.” Review of Economic Studies 47: 239-53. Carter, Francis W., and David Turnock. 1993. Environmental Problems in Eastern Europe. New York: Routledge. 46 Carter, Francis W., and David Turnock. 2002. Environmental Problems in Eastern Europe. Second edition. New York: Routledge. Commission of the European Communities. 2001. “Administrative Capacity for Implementation and Enforcement of EU Environmental Policy in the 13 Candidate Countries.” Report of DG Environment. Commission of the European Communities. 2002. “Regular Report from the Commission on Progress towards Accession. Romania.” Report of DG Environment. Copeland, Brian R., and M. Scott Taylor. 2004. “Trade, Growth, and the Environment.” Journal of Economic Literature 42 (March): 7-71. Damania, Richard, Per G. Fredriksson, and John A. List. 2003. “Trade Liberalization, Corruption, and Environmental Policy Formation: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 46: 490–512. Danilov-Daniliyan, Victor. 2002. “Two Years of Ecological Disorder under “Delicate Direction” of the Ministry of Natural Resources.” Published by OPEC.RU at: http://www.opec.ru/library/article.asp?d_no=455&c_no=66. Darst, Robert G. 2001. Smokestack Diplomacy: Cooperation and Conflict in East-West Environmental Politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Dasgupta, S., A. Mody, S. Roy, and D. Wheeler. 1995. ‘‘Environmental Regulation and Development: A Cross-Country Empirical Analysis.’’ Policy Research Working Paper No. 1448, Policy Research. Available at http://www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/1448/. Dean, Judith M. 2001. International Trade and the Environment. Brookfield, VT: Ashgate. Ederington, Josh, and Jenny Minier. 2003. “Is Environmental Policy a Secondary Trade Barrier? An Empirical Analysis.” Canadian Journal of Economics 36 (1) 137-54. Eliste, P., and P.G. Fredriksson. 2002. “Environmental Regulations, Transfers and Trade: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Environmental Economic Management 43: 234–50. European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). 1997. Transition Report. London: EBRD. Frankel, Jeffrey A. 2003. “The Environment and Globalization.” Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 10090. 47 Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Andrew K. Rose. 2002. “Is Trade Good or Bad for the Environment? Sorting Out the Causality.” Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 9201. Fredriksson, Per G., ed. 1999. Trade, Global Policy and the Environment. Washington, DC: World Bank. Frye, Timothy. 2002. “The Perils of Polarization: Economic Performance in the Postcommunist World.” World Politics 54 (April): 308-37. Frye, Timothy, and Edward D. Mansfield. 2003. “Fragmenting Protection: The Political Economy of Trade Policy in the Post-Communist World.” British Journal of Political Science 33 (October): 635-57. Frye, Timothy, and Edward D. Mansfield. 2004. “Timing is Everything: Elections and Trade Liberalization in the Post-Communist World.” Comparative Political Studies 37 (May): 371-98. Frye, Timothy, Joel Hellman, and Joshua Tucker. 2000. “Data Base on Political Institutions in the Post-Communist World.” Unpublished Data Set, Ohio State University. Garcia-Johnson, Ronie. 2000. Exporting Environmentalism: U.S. Multinational Chemical Corporations in Brazil and Mexico. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Garrett, Geoffrey. 1998. Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Grossman, Gene M., and Alan B. Krueger. 1993. “Environmental Impacts of a North American Free Trade Agreement.” In The Mexico-US Free Trade Agreement, edited by Peter M. Garber. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Gutner, Tamar L. 2002. Banking on the Environment. Multilateral Development Banks and Their Performance in Central Eastern Europe. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Haas, Peter M., Robert O. Keohane, and Marc A. Levy, eds. 1993. Institutions for the Earth: Sources of Effective International Environmental Protection. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Hellman, Joel. 1997. “Constitutions and Economic Reform in the Post-Communist Transitions.” In The Rule of Law and Economic Reform in Russia, edited by Jeffrey D. Sachs and Katharina Pistor. Boulder, CO: Westview. Hellman, Joel. 1998. “Winners Take All: The Pitfalls of Partial Reform.” World Politics 50 (January): 203-34. 48 Helm, Carsten, and Detlef F. Sprinz. 2000. “Measuring the Effectiveness of International Environmental Regimes.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 45 (October): 630-52. Hettige, Hemamala, Robert E. B. Lucas, and David Wheeler. 1992. “The Toxic Intensity of Industrial Production: Global Patterns, Trends, and Trade Policy.” American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings) 82 (May): 478-81. Holzinger, Katharina, and Peter Knoepfel, eds. 2000. Environmental Policy in a European Union of Variable Geometry? The Challenge of the Next Enlargement. Basel: Helbing & Lichtenhahn. Honneland, Geir. 2003. Russia and the West. Environmental Cooperation and Conflict. London: Routledge. Ichikawa, Nabuko, Rie Tsutsumi, and Kohei Watanabe. 2002. “Environmental Indicators of Transition.” European Environment 12 (March/April): 64-76. Jacoby, Wade. 1999. “Priest and Penitent: The European Union as a Force in the Domestic Politics of Eastern Europe.” East European Constitutional Review 8 (1-2), accessed in October 2002 via http://www.law.nyu.edu/eecr/vol8num12/special/priestpen.html. Jaffe, Adam B., Stephen R. Peterson, Paul R. Portney, and Robert N. Stavens. 1995. “Environmental Regulation and the Comeptitiveness of US Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?” Journal of Economic Literature 33 (March): 132-63. Jaggers, Keith, and Ted Robert Gurr. 1995. “Tracking Democracy’s Third Wave with Polity III Data.” Journal of Peace Research 32 (4): 469-82. Jha, Veena, Anil Markandya, and Rene Vossenaar. 1999. Reconciling Trade and the Environment: Lessons from Case Studies in Developing Countries. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Keohane, Robert O., and Marc A. Levy. 1996. Institutions for Environmental Aid: Pitfall and Promise. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Klarer, Jurg, and Bedrich Moldan, eds. 1997. The Environmental Challenges for Central European Economies in Transition. London: John Wiley. Kopstein, Jeffrey S., and David A. Reilly. 2000. “Geographic Diffusion and the Transformation of the Postcommunist World.” World Politics 53 (October): 1-37. Kotov, Vladimir, and Elena Nikitina. 1996. “Russia Wrestles with an Old Polluter.” Environment 38: 6-37. 49 Kotov, Vladimir, and Elena Nikitina. 2002. “Reorganisation of Environmental Policy in Russia: The Decade of Success and Failures in Implementation and Perspective Quests.” Working paper of Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, accessed via http://www.feem.it/web/activ/_activ.html. Lebor, Adam. 2000. “Cyanide Leak Heads Towards Danube Killing Every Living Thing In Its Path.” Independent of UK, February 14. Levy, Marc A. 2002. “Measuring Nation’s Environmental Sustainability.” In Environmental Performance Measurement: The Global Report, edited by Daniel Esty and Peter K. Cornelius. New York: Oxford University Press. Lofdahl, Corey L. 2002. Environmental Impacts of Globalization and Trade: A Systems Study. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Low, Patrick, ed. 1992. International Trade and the Environment. Washington, DC: World Bank. Milner, Helen V., with Keiko Kubota. forthcoming. “Why the Move to Free Trade? Democracy and Trade Policy in the Developing Countries.” International Organization. Mitchell, Ronald B. 2003. “The Relative Effects of Environmental Regimes: A Quantitative Comparison of Four Acid Rain Protocols.” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, Portland, OR. Mol, Arthur P. J. 2001. Globalization and Environmental Reform: The Ecological Modernization of the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Murrell, Peter. 1996. “How Far Has the Transition Progressed?” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 (1): 25-44. Nation Intelligence Council. 1999. “The Environmental Outlook in Russia.” Intelligence Community Assessments. Nielson, Daniel L., and Michael J. Tierney. 2003. “Delegation to International Organizations: Agency Theory and World Bank Environmental Reform.” International Organization 57 (Spring): 241-76. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 1999a. Sourcebook on Environmental Funds in Economies in Transition. Paris: OECD. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 1999b. Environment in the Transition to a Market Economy. Paris: OECD. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 2000. Environmental Compliance and Enforcement in the NIS: A Survey of Current Practices 50 of Environmental Inspectorates and Options for Improvement. OECD Report, prepared for the twelfth meeting of the EAP Task Force, 18-19 October 2000, Almaty. Parks, Brad, Michael Tierney, Timmons Roberts, and Robert Hicks. 2004. Greening Aid: Understanding Environmental Assistance to Developing Countries. Unpublished Manuscript, College of William and Mary. Pavlinek, Petr, and John Pickles. 2000. Environmental Transitions: Transformation and Ecological Defense in Central and Eastern Europe. London: Routledge. Przeworski, Adam, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi. 2000. Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990. New York: Cambridge University Press. Regional Environmental Center (REC). 1999. Sourcebook on Economic Instruments for Environmental Policy: Central and Eastern Europe. Szentendre: REC. Regional Environmental Center (REC). 2001a. Environmental Funds in the Candidate Countries. Szentenedre: REC. Regional Environmental Center (REC). 2001b. Environmental Taxes in an Enlarged Europe. Szentendre: REC. Rodrik, Dani. 1992. “Foreign Trade in Eastern Europe’s Transition: Early Results.” In The Transition in Eastern Europe, vol. 2, edited by Oliver Blanchard, Kenneth Froot, and Jeffrey Sachs. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Roubini, Noriel, and Jeffrey Sachs. 1989. “Government Spending and Budget Deficits in the Industrial Countries.” Economic Policy: A European Forum 8: 101-27. Scruggs, Lyle. 2003. Sustaining Abundance: Environmental Policy in Industrial Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Shugart, Matthew Soberg, and John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. New York: Cambridge University Press. Smarzynska, Beata K., and Shang-Jin Wei. 2001. “Pollution Havens and Foreign Direct Investment: Dirty Secret or Popular Myth?” World Bank Working Paper, Development Economics Research Group. Stern, David I., Michael S. Common, and Edward B. Barbier. 1996. “Economic Growth and Environmental Degradation: The Environmental Kuznets Curve and Sustainable Development.” World Development 42 (7): 1151-160. 51 Swank, Duane. 2002. Global Capital, Political Institutions and Policy Change in Developed Welfare States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Tavernise, Sabrina. 2003. “Oil Rush in Siberia Puts Other Treasures at Risk.” New York Times, October 5, p. A3. Vogel, David. 1995. Trading Up: Consumer and Environmental Regulation in a Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Vovk, Viktor. 2003. “Sustainable Development for the Second World. Ukraine and the Nations in Transitions.” World Watch Paper no. 167. Victor, David G., Kal Raustiala, and Eugene B. Skolnikoff. 1998. The Implementation and Effectiveness of International Environmental Commitments: Theory and Practice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Vreeland, James. 2003. The IMF and Economic Development. New York: Cambridge University Press. Vukina, Tomislav, John C. Beghin, and Ebru G. Solakoglu. 1999. “Transition to Markets and the Environment: Effects of the Change in the Composition of Manufacturing Output.” Environment and Development Economics 4 (October): 582-98. Weinthal, Erika. 2002. State Making and Environmental Cooperation: Linking Domestic and International Politics in Central Asia. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. World Bank. 1994. “Environmental Action Program for Central and Eastern Europe.” Report no. 10603-ECA. Washington, DC: World Bank. Zarsky, Lyuba. 1999. “Havens, Halos, and Spaghetti: Untangling the Evidence about Foreign Direct Investment and the Environment.” Foreign Direct Investment and the Environment. OECD, 47-74. Zinnes, Clifford F. 1997. “The Road to Creating an Integrated Pollution Charge and Permitting System in Romania.” In Controlling Pollution in Transition Economies: Theories and Methods, edited by Randall Bluffstone and Bruce A. Larson. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Weiss, Edith Brown, and Harold K. Jacobson. 1998. Engaging Countries: Strengthening Compliance with International Environmental Accords. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. 52