Network Linkages and Financial Leverage-The Group Governance View1 Dan Lin Assistant Professor Department of Banking and Finance Takming University of Science and Technology 56, Sec. 1, Huanshan Rd., Neihu, Taipei 11451, Taiwan Tel: 886-2-26585801; Fax: 886-2-26588448 E-mail: mcylin@takming.edu.tw Hsien-Chang Kuo Professor Department of Banking and Finance Takming University of Science and Technology 56, Sec. 1, Huanshan Rd., Neihu, Taipei 11451, Taiwan Tel: 886-2-26585801; Fax: 886-2-26588448 E-mail: hckuo@takming.edu.tw Lie-Huey Wang Associate Professor Finance Department Ming Chuan University 250, Zhong Shan N. Rd., Sec. 5, Taipei 111, Taiwan Tel: 886-2-28824564 ext.2191 E-mail: lhwang@mail.mcu.edu.tw 1 This work was fully supported by the National Science Council in Taiwan, under contract no.: NSC 96-2416-H-147-009-MY2. 1 Network Linkages and Financial Leverage-The Group Governance View Abstract This study examines capital structures from the perspective of network linkages. Based on a panel of business groups listed on the Taiwan Stock Exchange (TSE) and in the over-the-counter (OTC) market from 2006 to 2008, we test the relationship between capital structures and network linkages. Specifically, we use the linkages between related party purchases and sales transactions as the proxy for network linkages and employ a panel data linear regression model to examine the relationship between financial leverage and network linkages after considering the family governance in Taiwan’s business groups. Overall, the results show that the shareholdings of family members and the divergence between seat control rights and voting rights are negatively correlated with the related party purchases and sales network linkages. For information technology (IT) family firms, we have observed the following relationships: (1) higher sales to related parties are associated with higher debt ratios; (2) higher purchases from related parties are associated with higher long-term debt ratios; and (3) the greater the number of related purchasers, the higher the short-tem debt ratios. Opposite results are found for non-information technology (NIT) family firms. Finally, both IT and NIT family firms use more short-term debt when seat control rights diverge from voting rights. Keywords: capital structure, related party purchases and sales network linkages, business groups, family governance, panel data linear regression model 2 1. Introduction Since the concept of network linkages has been used by Johanson and Mattsson (1987) to explain the basis for corporate cooperation, network linkages have been widely discussed and applied to important issues such as strategic organizations and overseas investments. Firms construct effective value chain linkages through network structures to generate comparative profits (Porter, 1980) and develop value-adding partnerships (Johnston and Lawrence, 1988). Therefore, a firm can increase its firm value through cooperative network relationships (Prahalad and Hamel, 1990; Blankenburg et al., 1999). In addition, from the viewpoint of the company’s resources, the cooperative relationship between firms can be considered to be a resource of the firm. Therefore, network linkages and firm value are expected to be positively correlated, while firm value may exhibit a positive or negative relationship with capital structure. In other words, network linkages and capital structure may be negatively correlated (Vicente-Lorente, 2001; Kuo, 2006) or positively correlated (Kuo et al., 2003). Kuo (2006) examines the changes in capital structure from the perspective of network linkages, and studies the evolution of capital structure from a new angle, namely, that of corporate cooperation. Kuo (2006) arrives at an interesting finding which indicates that network linkages and financial leverage are negatively correlated. The evidence suggests that network linkages can help increase firm value and subsequently reduce the use of debt financing. The supply chain effects formed by the economic links between the firm, its suppliers and its clients will affect the firm’s capital structure decisions and competitive behavior in the market. Here, the supply chain effects refer to the credit financing and the long-term trade agreement with the suppliers, the quality guarantee demanded by customers and the ongoing trade relationship with the clients. In recent years, with the rise of the Chinese economy and its structural impact on international economic development, global and inter-industry competition has made the cooperative relationship between firms more crucial and important. Without a doubt, the multiple supply chain network linkage has become an important direction for development. In deciding on the capital structure, firms can incorporate the idea of a network structure, which can provide further understanding not only of the firms’ financial leverage but also its optimal leverage level. More importantly, this opens a 3 new research field in studies on capital structure. The influence of network linkages on the capital structure during the development process of a firm has hardly been discussed by scholars. Thus, with the increasing importance of the issue of supply chain management, the effect of network linkages on a firm’s capital structure constitutes a valuable new direction for further research. With the trend towards globalization, firms are facing more intense competition in global markets and transitions in the global economic environment. To cope with these changes, corporations are seeking cooperative opportunities through, for example, mergers, joint ventures, reinvestments, and cross-shareholdings, or else forming strategic alliances or business groups in order to achieve resource sharing, economies of scale, business growth and competitive edges. Since the subsidiaries of business groups are linked through shares, business groups can be considered to be a network collectivity. In Taiwan, large business groups are mostly founded and operated by families or relationship networks (Wong, 1985; Claessens et al., 2000; Yeh et al., 2001) and possess the characteristic of overlapping ownership and control (Yeh et al., 2001; Yeh, 2005). The benefits of family business groups include the consolidation of power, the centralized execution of commands and increased company performance and value (Gerlach, 1992; Keister, 1998; James, 1999; Schneider, 2000; Khanna and Palepu, 2000; Khanna and Rivkin, 2001; Carney and Gedajlovic, 2002; Chang, 2003; Joh, 2003; Anderson et al., 2003; Anderson and Reeb, 2003; Burkart et al., 2003; Luo and Chung, 2005). However, family business groups can increase conflicts of interest (Granovetter, 2005; Berkman et al., 2009) and are more likely to allow the expropriation of minority shareholders by management to take place (Mahaffy, 1998; La Porta et al., 1999; Gilles, 1999; Johnson et al., 2000; Hutchinson, 2002). The empirical findings show that monitoring by large shareholders can decrease the agency problem caused by choosing sub-optimal capital structures (Fosberg, 2004) and can restrain the controlling shareholders from increasing debt to reduce the dilution of control. Furthermore, monitoring by large shareholders can mitigate the threat of being taken over (Harris and Raviv, 1988; Stulz, 1988; Du and Dai, 2005) and the reduce-debt-for-tunneling effects (Du and Dai, 2005). The reasons for the formation and the characteristics of business groups in Taiwan are drastically different from those of such groups in other countries. This is because, in Taiwan, the business groups are typically family businesses, while other 4 business groups are established by forming the parent company first and the subsidiaries later. Therefore, the scale of network linkages in family groups must be substantially different from the scale of network linkages formed by individual businesses. Since the subsidiaries are linked with each other through a “shareholding relationship network” and the characteristic of being family-related in Taiwanese business groups highlights the importance of network relationships, this study contributes to the literature by examining business groups from the network linkage perspective and analyzing the effect of business group supply chain network linkages on company capital structures. Although network relationships exist in all economic activities, they are not easily observable. In a departure from the previous literature, this study analyzes network linkage from the business transactions perspective. Since the purchases and sales relationships between a firm and its trading partners form a network, we can use trading data to examine the interactive relationships between firms. The number of cooperating companies and the trade volume in dollar amounts then represent the strength of a network linkage. This study adopts a sample of business groups listed on the Taiwan Stock Exchange (TSE) and in the over-the-counter (OTC) market over the period 2006-2008 and is based on the idea of a purchases and sales network linkage between related parties in the cooperative industrial system. In addition to analyzing the relationship between the corporate governance of Taiwanese business groups and the network linkage strategies, we incorporate the effect of family governance in the panel data linear regression model when examining the relationship between the capital structure and the related party purchases and sales network linkage. Our results show that family shareholdings and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio are negatively correlated with the purchases and sales involving related parties. The effect of the related party purchases and sales network linkage on the capital structure is also different for family and nonfamily companies in different industry sectors. In the information technology (IT) industry, family companies tend to provide financial support through debt financing to related parties with a sales network linkage. However, for non-family IT companies, the related party purchase network linkage will increase the maturity risk in a capital structure. Finally, this study finds that the seats-shareholding divergence ratios of IT and non-information technology (NIT) family companies are positively and negatively correlated with debt (both short-term and long-term debt), respectively, indicating that the seats-shareholding divergence 5 ratios will influence the risk-taking tendency in companies’ capital structure decisions. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a literature review on capital structures, network linkages, and corporate governance in family firms and business groups, which form the foundation of the study. Section 3 presents the methodology and explains the data sources, research variables and empirical models. Section 4 analyzes and discusses the empirical results. The final section is the conclusion. 2. Literature Review 2.1 Network linkage and capital structure decisions Since Modigliani and Miller (1958), Jensen and Meckling (1976), Myers (1977), Ross (1977) and Myers and Majluf (1984) proposed different models for capital structures, subsequent studies have analyzed corporate capital structures from other perspectives, including agency theory (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Haugen and Senbet, 1979), bankruptcy costs (Myers, 1977; Haugen and Senbet, 1979; Titman, 1984), debt tax shields (DeAngelo and Masulis, 1980; Dammon and Senbet, 1988), pecking order theory (Myers and Majluf, 1984), profitability (Myers and Majluf, 1984), signaling theory (Ross, 1985), growth opportunities (Myers, 1977; Titman and Wessels, 1988) and product uniqueness (Titman and Wessels, 1988). Johanson and Mattson (1987) propose the concept of a network linkage to explain the basis for corporate cooperation. This idea has been widely discussed and applied to important issues such as strategic organizations and overseas investment. A “network” refers to the horizontal or vertical cooperation between supply chains, through which companies combine their financial, production, marketing, personnel, and R&D resources to form a cooperative support network, share resources, and increase their competitive advantages (Thorelli, 1986; Jarillo, 1988). The network structure can also help construct an effective value chain, create comparative advantages (Porter, 1980) and develop a value-adding partnership (Johnston and Lawrence, 1988). Therefore, industrial network linkages can increase the efficiency in resource usage, construct a complete supply chain, and increase the company’s 6 resource flexibility and adaptability. Moreover, companies can benefit from economies of scale, economies of scope and, most importantly, increases in firm value (Prahalad and Hamel, 1990; Blankenburg et al., 1999; Elfring and Hulsink, 2003). There have been many studies on strategic networks, such as supply chain linkages (Jarillo, 1988; Dyer and Singh, 1998) and network resources (Gulati, 1999). From the strategic alliance perspective, there have been discussions on the resource-based view, such as the close cooperative relationship between construction material suppliers (Wernerfelt, 1984; Dierickx and Cool, 1989; Barney, 1991), the discussions on the cooperation based on R&D (Powell et al., 1996), and on the trade information linkages between managerial teams (Gulati and Westphal, 1999). In addition, from the resource-based perspective, the cooperative relationship between companies can be a form of company resources, which can increase firm value (Thorelli, 1986; Jarillo, 1988; Johnston and Lawrence, 1988; Prahalad and Hamel, 1990; Blankenburg et al., 1999). In particular, the network linkages based on financial resources can increase the capacity of spontaneous financing, raise the overall company’s financial flexibility and thus reduce the company’s debt level (Vicente-Lorente, 2001; Kuo, 2006). Kuo et al. (2003) examine the corporate capital structure decisions from the perspective of international network linkages and find that the level of working capital in the US IT industry has a positive relationship with the capital structures in the Taiwanese IT industry. Therefore, during the development of a company, the network relationship does indeed affect the capital structure. This is a completely new issue and deserves further study. 2.2 Corporate governance and capital structure decisions Even though debt financing can reduce agency conflicts and increase firm value (Grossman and Hart, 1980; Jensen, 1986), the opportunistic behavior of management in making financing decisions will be influenced by the structure of equity ownership (Demsetz, 1983; Shleifer and Vishny, 1986; Agrawal and Mandelker, 1990). The difference between the goals of the managers and of the shareholders is an important factor influencing a firm’s capital structure decisions (Morellec, 2004). Fosberg (2004) finds that a firm’s debt ratio is positively correlated with the director shareholding ratio. Fosberg (2004) argues that the monitoring by large shareholders can effectively reduce the agency problem of choosing the sub-optimal 7 capital structure by the company. The empirical finding of Arslan and Karan (2006) shows that the degree of ownership concentration is correlated with the debt maturity. Harris and Raviv (1988), Stulz (1988) and Du and Dai (2005) all suggest that controlling shareholders, based on entrenchment motives, prefer debt financing. This is because increasing debts can avoid the dilution of control and reduce the takeover risk. Du and Dai (2005) propose another view and suggest that a higher debt level will result in higher pressure to pay off the debt. Therefore, more of the company’s earnings will be used for paying debts. Consequently, controlling shareholders are restrained from misappropriating firm’s assets through self-dealing. However, controlling shareholders may choose to reduce the firm’s financial leverage to cover up their misappropriating behavior and this is the “reduced-debt-for-tunneling effect” hypothesis. Mahaffy (1998) and Gilles (1999) find that concentrated ownership is detrimental to firm performance, especially when controlling shareholders are individuals or family members. However, James (1999) and Schneider (2002) both suggest that as family shareholders are more concerned about the companies’ future growth and longevity, family firms tend to have longer horizons for the companies’ operations. Anderson et al. (2003) find that family control can provide more resource aids to a company and increase firm value. Anderson and Reeb (2003) also find that family ownership can provide more stringent monitoring and long-term attention to the firm’s operations. Moreover, family involvement in a firm’s operations can increase the firm’s competitive advantages, thereby increasing its long-term and short-term performance. Carney and Gedajlovic (2002), Chang (2003), and Joh (2003) all find that firms with controlling family ownership have higher operational performance. Anderson and Reeb (2004) suggest that family shareholders will adopt the maximization of firm performance as their goals. However, Hutchinson (2002) finds that when a board of directors is dominated by company insiders, it is more likely that there will be opportunistic behavior. Filatotchev et al. (2005), however, do not find a significant relationship between family ownership and firm performance. The studies by Yeh et al. (2001) and Yeh (2005) find that large family shareholders in Taiwanese corporations tend to utilize pyramidal structures, cross-shareholdings, indirect shareholdings, the intervention of management, board of director seats and important managerial positions to meet the government requirement of separation of ownership and control. 8 Since family shareholders often use cross-shareholdings within the business groups to secure the management ownership or use board of director seats or voting rights to strengthen the rights of management and decision-making, it is likely that there will be a divergence between control rights and cash flow rights. Grossman and Hart (1988) and Harris and Raviv (1988) suggest that when voting rights diverge from cash flow rights, there will be a negative entrenchment effect on firm values. Du and Dai (2005) further propose that the divergence of shareholder control rights and cash flow rights may result in the non-dilution entrenchment effect, debt signaling effect, and reduce-debt-for-tunneling effect. Du and Dai (2005) find that the divergence of shareholder control rights from cash flow rights is positively correlated with the firm’s financial leverage. That is, in order to avoid the dilution of control, large controlling shareholders tend to increase a firm’s financial leverage, thereby increasing the risk-taking tendency in the firm’s capital structure decisions. Overall, based on the study by Banerjee et al. (2008) who argue from the related party perspective that capital structure decisions are affected by the buyer-supplier relationship, this study examines a sample of Taiwanese business groups. In Taiwan, companies affiliated to a business group often engage in related party purchases and sales as a form of supply chain cooperation. Therefore, this study uses related party purchases and sales linkages to proxy for the network linkage, and at the same time takes into consideration the family governance in Taiwanese business groups. Accordingly, this study will incorporate the influence of family governance in business groups on network linkage strategies and use a panel data linear regression model to test the relationship between network linkages and capital structure decisions. 3. Methodology 3.1 Data So far, there has still not arisen a consistent and definitive definition for “business groups” in the literature (Leff, 1978; Granovetter, 1995; Collin, 1998; Guillen, 2000; Chung, 2001; Khanna and Rivkin, 2001). Therefore, this study adopts the definition of business groups used in the Taiwan Economic Journal (TEJ) database; 9 that is, companies with the same ultimate controller that meet the following requirements: (1) the primary shareholders are members of the same family (the primary shareholders refer to the top-ten large shareholders or shareholders with more than 5% shareholdings); (2) at least one third of the directors on the board of directors are the same; (3) primary management is the same; the chairperson or CEO is the same; (4) there is a controlling or dependency relationship with real controls; and (5) there is a mutual investment relationship. This study is based on Taiwanese listed and OTC companies, and covers the period from 2006 to 2008. The empirical data are obtained from the corporate financial statement database and corporate governance database of the TEJ, the Market Observation Post System of the Taiwan Stock Exchange (MOPS), and companies’ annual reports. This study follows the methodology used in Benerjee et al. (2008) who construct the list of buying and selling firms for each company based on the buyer-supplier list released by firms. In this study, our sample is based on the core companies of the business groups in the TEJ database. In order to obtain the information on related party purchases and sales (i.e., the amount of related party transactions exceeding NT$100 million or firms with paid-in capital of over 20%) for the core companies, we go through each related party transaction one by one as disclosed in the Market Observation Post System of the Taiwan Stock Exchange and companies’ annual reports. This is the first-level purchases and sales linkage. To construct the second-level purchases and sales linkage, we obtain information on firms that have a purchasing or sales relationship with the first-level firms. We treat all related buyers and sellers as the same group and continue doing so until no further purchase and sales linkages can be constructed. While compiling this information, we have observed duplicated information. Thus, during the process of constructing purchasing and sales information, if a firm’s data linked to a specific company have appeared once already, we do not repeat the process. In addition, if a firm linked to a particular company is also the core company of another business group, we do not continue with the process. Thus, after excluding companies with incomplete sales and purchases data, banks and holdings companies, we obtain the related party purchases and sales data for 323 companies (or 969 observations). Moreover, we exclude 8 companies with incomplete financial statement data, and the final sample includes 315 companies or a total of 945 observations. 10 3.2 Variables This study uses long-term debt ratios and short-term debt ratios as the proxy variables for capital structure. In terms of how to measure the degree of network linkages between companies, the previous literature has not provided a consistent and definitive definition. Since this study focuses on Taiwanese business groups, we need to take into consideration their unique characteristics, such as the family network, organizational network and human relations network. In Taiwan, companies affiliated to business groups are often involved in related party purchasing and sales transactions. In other words, the network linkages in Taiwanese business groups are achieved through supply chain cooperation and the division of labor. Therefore, in contrast to the definition of network linkages used in the previous literature,2 this study defines network linkages from the commercial transactions perspective. Using the financial data of business groups, we adopt two measures for the strength of the network linkages in business groups: (1) the number of related party purchases and sales (i.e., the number of related firms purchased from and sold to); and (2) the ratio of related party purchases and sales in dollar amounts.3 In the first measure, the amounts of related party purchases and sales are defined so as to include only the purchasing or selling firms with related party transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20%. The second measure (i.e., the ratio of related party purchases and sales in dollar amounts) is defined as the ratio of purchases from (or sales to) related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% to the total amount of purchases and sales. 2 Previous studies have discussed many different aspects of the network relationship, for example, the human relations network which is based on the interactions between people, the knowledge network formed by exchanges of knowledge and experience, the alliance network created by partner relationships, the social network, and the business network created by interdependent corporations (Johanson and Mattsson, 1987; Coleman, 1990; Uzzi, 1997). 3 This is based on the Statements of Financial Accounting Standards No. 6 “Related Party Disclosures”, which defines a related party as follows: “a party is related to an entity if one party can exercise control or significantly influence the financing policies of the other party. Entities under common ownership or control are also deemed as related parties.” “An entity that satisfies one of the following conditions is referred to as a related party of an enterprise (except when it can prove that there is no control or significant influence): (a) an investee accounted for by the equity method; (b) an investor who uses the equity method to account for the investment in the enterprise; (c) the director or the president is the same person as the chairman or the president of another company, or is the spouse or second immediate family of other companies; (d) a non-profit organization of which the funds donated from the enterprise exceeds one third of the non-profit organization’s total funds; (e) a director, supervisor, president, vice-president, assistant vice-president and the head of department; (f) the spouse of a director, supervisor or president of the enterprise; and (g) the immediate and second immediate families of the enterprise’s chairman and president.” 11 Controlling shareholders of pyramidal business groups tend to use related party transactions, for example, through buying assets at high prices and selling them at low prices, to obtain personal benefits (Almeida and Wolfenzon, 2005; Riyanto and Toolsema, 2008; Cheung et al., 2009). In addition, as family shareholders hold large cash flow rights, opportunistic behavior is likely to occur. Family shareholders may sacrifice firm performance for the benefit of family members (Yammeesri and Lodh, 2004). Furthermore, with the divergence of voting rights from cash flow rights, large shareholders or family shareholders may use pyramidal and cross-shareholdings to misappropriate company assets (Bertrand et al., 2002; Faccio and Lang, 2002; Lins, 2003; Morck et al., 2005; Bozec and Laurin, 2008). Therefore, to take into account the family governance of business groups, we include two proxy variables for corporate governance, namely, the shareholding ratio by controlling family members and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio. Capital structures are also influenced by other factors, such as firm size (Remmers et al., 1974; Scott and Martin, 1975; Warner, 1977; Ferri and Jones, 1979; Aggarwal, 1981; Titman and Wessels, 1988; Friend and Lang, 1988; Moh’d et al., 1998; Smith and Watts, 1992; Kuo et al., 2000), profitability (Myers and Majluf, 1984; Kester, 1986; Friend and Lang, 1988; Baskin, 1989; Titman and Wessels,1988; Moh’d et al., 1998; Kuo et al., 2000), and long-term investments. Therefore, this study uses the number of affiliated companies in a business group and total assets as proxy variables for group size. Moreover, the return on assets and the long-term investment to equity ratio are used as proxy variables for profitability and long-term investments, respectively. Table 1 presents the operational definitions of research variables. 12 Table 1 Operational definitions of research variables Variables Capital structure Network Linkage Corporate Governance Firm Characteristics Abbreviation Definitions Long-term debt ratio LD Long-term debt ratio = (Long-term debts / Total assets)*100% Short-term debt ratio SD Short-term debt ratio = (Short-term debts / Total assets)*100% Number of related firms sold to Sale_No The number of related firms sold to which have trade amounts exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital of over 20%. Number of related firms purchased from Supply_No The number of related firms purchased from which have trades amounts exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital of over 20%. Related party sales ratio Sale_ratio Related party sales ratio = (Dollar amount of sales to related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / Total dollar amount of sales) *100% Related party purchase ratio Supply_ratio Related party purchase ratio = (Dollar amount of purchases from related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / Total dollar amount of purchases) *100% Family member shareholding ratio FMown Family member shareholding ratio = (Shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / Total shares of the firm)*100% Seats-shareholding divergence ratio Diverge Group size GpSize Number of affiliated companies in a business group. Total assets LnTA Log of total assets. Return on assets ROA Return on assets = (Net income after tax / Average total assets)*100% Long-term investment ratio LIratio Long-term investment ratio = (Long-term investments / Shareholder equity)*100% Seats-shareholding divergence ratio = Family member seats ratio / Family member shareholding ratio; where the family member seats ratio = (Seats held by ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / Total seats of the firm)*100%; family member shareholding ratio = (Shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / Total shares of the firm)*100% 13 3.3 Empirical models As this study uses cross-sectional and time-series panel data, we adopt the panel data linear regression model for the empirical analysis. The advantage of using cross-sectional and time-series data is that the problem of estimation errors caused by insufficient observations can be solved or reduced, thereby increasing the degrees of freedom for test statistics, reducing the multicollinearity between explanatory variables, and most importantly, increasing the efficiency of model estimation (Hsiao, 1985). In addition, the panel data allow for multiple observations of subjects (firms) or time periods. Therefore, the potential relationship between unobserved variables and explanatory variables can be more fully incorporated in the behavioral models. The mutual learning behavior between subjects (or firms) can also be analyzed. Hence, we are able to perform a more in-depth analysis of important economic issues that have been neglected by conventional tests of cross-sectional or time-series data. In general, based on the characteristics of the intercept items, the models can be classified into fixed effects models and random effects models (Hsiao, 2003). The fixed effects model can be further categorized into two forms: the ordinary least squares model (OLS) that has fixed constant intercepts, and the fixed effects model (or the least squares dummy variable model) where the intercept item can reflect the heterogeneity between individual subjects (or firms). The second model is the random effects model, also known as a variance components model, which has random intercepts. Therefore, in order to avoid the bias of OLS which ignores the cross-sectional self-discrepancy effect of individual firms, this study uses the F-test, the Lagrange multiplier test and Hausman’s (1978) test to determine the choice of panel data linear regression model and follow-up empirical analyses.4 First, use the F test, F [(RRSS URSS ) / N 1] [URSS /( NT ( N K 1))] ~ F(N-1, NT-N-K+1), to test 4 the null hypothesis 0 : 1 2 n (i.e., accepting the least squares model) and the alternative hypothesis H1: i not all equal (i=1,…,N) (i.e., accepting the fixed effects model), where RRSS is the residual sum of squares of the least squares model; URSS is the residual sum of squares of the fixed effects model; N indicates the number of observations; T indicates the time periods; and K is the number of independent variables. Then, use the Lagrange multiplier test (LM test) to test the null hypothesis 0 : constant intercept, 2 0 (i.e., accepting the least squares model), and the alternative hypothesis 1 : intercept as a random variable, 2 0 (i.e., accepting the fixed effects 14 First, we test the effect of family governance of a business group on its related party purchases and sales network linkages. Then, we analyze the relationship between the related party purchases and sales network linkages and the capital structure. 3.3.1 The model on the relationship between the family governance of business groups and network linkages This study uses the related party purchases and sales network linkage (NL) as the dependent variable of the model, which is measured by the number of related firms sold to (Sale No.), the number of related firms purchased from (Supply No.), the ratio of related party sales (Sale ratio), and the ratio of related party purchases (Supply ratio). The independent variables include the family member shareholding ratio (FMown) and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio (Diverge), with group size (GpSize) as the control variable. The empirical model is as follows: NLit i 1 FMownit 2 Divergeit 3GpSizeit it (1) 3.3.2 The model on the relationship between related party purchases and sales network linkages and capital structures This study uses the capital structure (Debt), measured by the short-term debt ratio (SD) and the long-term debt ratio (LD), as the dependent variable. The related party purchases and sales network linkage (NL), measured by the number of related firms sold to (Sale No.), the number of related firms purchased from (Supply No.), the ratio of related party sales (Sale ratio), and the ratio of related party purchases (Supply ratio), and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio (Diverge) are included as model) for the test. That is, N T N T LM ( NT / 2(T 1)) [ ( uˆ it ) 2 / uˆ it2 ] 1 ~ 2 (1) n 1t 1 n 1 t 1 where ûit is the residual estimated using least squares; 2 (1) is a Chi-square test with 1 degree of freedom. Finally, use Hausman’s (1978) test, i.e., ˆ * ˆ ' Var ( ˆ * ) Var ( ˆ ' ) ˆ 1 * ˆ ' ~ 2 k to test the null hypothesis 0 : E i 1it ,..., kit (i.e., accepting the random effects model), and the alternative hypothesis 1 : E i 1it ,..., kit (i.e., accepting the fixed effects model) for the test, in which ˆ * is the regression coefficient matrix estimated using the least squares model; ̂ ' is the regression coefficient matrix estimated using the fixed effects model; and 2 (k ) is a Chi-square test with k degrees of freedom. 15 independent variables. Total assets (LnTA), the return on assets (ROA) and the long-term investment ratio are the control variables. The empirical model is as follows: p p k 1 k 1 Debt it i k NLkit Divergeit k Contolkit it (2) 4. Empirical Results 4.1 Sample data analysis The descriptive statistics of each variable are presented in Table 2. We find that based on a sample of 315 firms, the short-term debt ratio, the ratios of the related party sales and purchases, the family member shareholding ratio and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio all exhibit greater differences in maximum values, minimum values and standard deviations. Therefore, this study further categorizes the sample into groups based on the type of corporations, the degree of seats-shareholding divergence and the industry sectors. Then, we use a two-sample t-test to see if there are any significant differences between groups. Schneider (2000) suggests that family shareholders are more concerned about the firm’s growth and longevity. James (1999) also argues that family firms hold longer horizons for the operation of the firms. Anderson et al. (2003) further suggest that family firms place stronger emphasis on sustained operations and reputations. On the whole, there are more incentives for family shareholders to monitor the firms, thereby increasing firm performance and reducing the operational risks. Hence, this study classifies the sample firms according to whether they are run by families. If a company meets one of the following requirements, then it is classified as a “family firm”: (1) the positions of chairman of the board of directors and CEO are held by members of the same family; (2) the family controls more than 50% of the board seats (excluding friendly seats) while the friendly director seats ratio and the external director seats ratio are both lower than 33%; (3) the family controls more than 33% of the board seats while at least 3 directors or managers are from the ultimate controlling family; and (4) the family controlled shareholding ratio is higher than the necessary 16 controlling shareholding ratio (i.e., with the controlling shareholding ratio higher than 20%). Under this principle of classifications, there are 177 family firms and 138 non-family firms. Table 2 Descriptive statistics of research variables Variables Min Max Average Std. Dev. Capital Long-term debt ratio 0.00 51.71 7.96 9.32 structure Short-term debt ratio 2.20 86.79 26.95 14.34 Sale No. 0 29 2.68 3.54 Network Supply No. 0 17 1.74 2.08 Linkage Sale Ratio 0 100 21.98 23.43 Supply Ratio 0 100 29.81 31.92 .00 100.00 18.65 21.86 .00 16.37 1.61 2.20 186 648663 31300 78428 -47.38 53.10 5.22 9.61 .00 197.23 48.37 32.69 Corporate Family member shareholding Governance ratio Seats-shareholding divergence ratio Firm Total assets (Million NT$) Characteristics ROA Long-term investment ratio Note: Long-term debt ratio is (long-term debts/total assets)* 100%. Short-term debt ratio is (short-term debts/ total assets)*100%. Sale No. is the number of related firms sold to which have trade amount exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital of over 20%. Supply No. is the number of related firms purchased from which have a trade amount exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital of over 20%. Sale ratio is (dollar amount of sales to related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / total dollar amount of sales) *100%. Supply ratio is (dollar amount of purchases from related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital over 20% / total dollar amount of purchases) *100%. Family member shareholding ratio is (shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total shares of the firm)*100%. Seats-shareholding divergence ratio is (family member seats ratio / family member shareholding ratio), in which the family member seat ratio = (seats held by the ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total seats of the firm)*100%; the family member shareholding ratio = (shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total shares of the firm)*100%. Total assets is the total amount of assets. ROA is (net income after tax / average total assets) *100%. Long-term investment ratio is (long-term investment / shareholder equity)*100%. The studies by Grossman and Hart (1988) and Harris and Ravivi (1988) both find that the divergence between voting rights and cash flow rights can cause a negative entrenchment effect. Du and Dai (2005) also find that the divergence between shareholders’ voting rights and cash flow rights can increase the risk-taking tendency in a firm’s capital structure decisions. Therefore, this study uses a seats-shareholding divergence ratio of 1 as the point of division. That is, if a firm’s seats-shareholding divergence ratio is larger than 1, it is classified as “high divergence”, totaling 160 firms. If the seats-shareholding divergence ratio is smaller than or equal to 1, then it is classified as “low divergence”, totaling 155 firms. Many studies support the view that the industrial group is an important factor to capital structures (Scott and Martin, 1975; Errunza, 1979; Ferri and Jones, 1979; 17 Bowen et al., 1982; Aggarwal and Baliga, 1987; Sekely and Collins, 1988), while only a small number of studies hold a different view (Belkaoui, 1974; Remmers et al., 1974; Stonehill et al., 1974; Naidu, 1983). In Taiwan, the information technology industry has far exceeded the traditional industry since the 1990s, and has become the main player in the development of the Taiwan economy. It also provides the direction for Taiwan’s future development. In fact, the information technology with a comparatively high degree of internationalization has led the steady growth in Taiwan’s GNP. Therefore, this study uses SIC codes for categorizing the industry sectors. Specifically, firms are classified into the information technology (IT) industry and non-information technology (NIT) industry. The IT industry, which has a total of 186 firms, includes semiconductors, computer peripherals, optoelectronics, communications networks, components, electronic access, information services, and other electronics. The NIT industry, which has a total of 129 firms, includes cement, food, plastics, textiles, electrical goods, chemicals, biotechnology, steel, rubber, automobiles, building materials, construction, shipping, trade, department stores, and others. The t-test results presented in Panel A and Panel B of Table 3 show that family or high divergence firms have significantly higher long-term debt ratios, family member shareholding ratios, seats-shareholding divergence ratios, and long-term investment ratios than non-family or low divergence firms. Non-family or low divergence firms exhibit significantly higher short-term debt ratios and related party purchases and sales in both the number of related firms and the ratio, as well as the return on assets than family or high divergence firms. Furthermore, the t-test results in Panel C show that the IT industry has a significantly higher short-term debt ratio and related party sales and supply ratio than the NIT industry, while the NIT industry has a significantly higher long-term debt ratio, family member shareholding ratio, seats-shareholding divergence ratio, and long-term investment ratio than the IT industry. Overall, the t-test results show that the shareholding control and seat control of family firms have a higher degree of divergence. Family firms also prefer long-term debt financing and exhibit a certain relationship with long-term investments. Non-family firms tend to use short-term debt financing and may be influenced by related party purchases and sales. In addition, the short-term debt financing of the IT 18 industry may be influenced by the amount of sales and purchases by related parties, while the long-term debt financing of the NIT industry may be influenced by family governance and long-term investments. Table 3 Test on differences between cluster samples Panel A: Firm type Family Variables Long-term debt ratio Short-term debt ratio Sale No. Nonfamily t-test Panel B: Seats-shareholding divergence High divergence Low divergence t-test Panel C: Industry sector IT NIT t-test 8.69 7.01 2.767*** 8.88 7.00 3.125*** 6.66 9.82 -5.131*** 25.42 28.91 -3.714*** 24.93 29.04 -4.441*** 28.45 24.79 3.936*** 2.39 3.05 -2.763*** 2.44 2.92 -2.092** 2.60 2.79 -0.744 Supply No. 1.55 1.98 -2.934*** 1.59 1.89 -2.205** 1.73 1.75 -.144 Sale ratio 19.59 25.06 -3.534*** 20.12 23.91 -2.488** 24.25 18.71 3.688*** Supply ratio 27.45 32.84 -2.545*** 26.39 33.35 -3.361*** 34.36 23.25 5.529*** Family member shareholding ratio Seats-shareholding divergence ratio Return on assets 33.20 0 39.896*** 29.98 6.96 19.020*** 11.22 29.36 -13.005*** 2.88 0 29.552*** 3.10 0.08 29.251*** 1.30 2.06 -5.496*** 4.82 5.73 -1.398 4.65 5.81 -1.846* 5.17 5.30 -0.228 Long-term investment ratio Number of firms (observations) 53.76 41.45 5.842*** 56.21 40.28 7.714*** 44.68 53.68 -4.204*** 177 138 160 155 186 129 (531) (414) (480) (465) (558) (387) Note: Long-term debt ratio is (Long-term debts/total assets)* 100%. Short-term debt ratio is (short-term debts/ total assets)*100%. Sale No. is the number of related firms sold to which have trade amounts exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital of over 20%. Supply No. is the number of related firms purchased from which have trade amounts exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital over 20%. Sale ratio is (dollar amount of sales to related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / total dollar amount of sales) *100%. Supply ratio is (dollar amount of purchases from related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / total dollar amount of purchases) *100%. Family member shareholding ratio is (shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total shares of the firm)*100%. Seats-shareholding divergence ratio is (family member seats ratio / family member shareholding ratio), in which the family member seat ratio = (seats held by the ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total seats of the firm)*100%; the family member shareholding ratio = (shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total shares of the firm)*100%. ROA is (net income after tax / average total assets) *100%. Long-term investment ratio is (long-term investment / shareholder equity)*100%. This study classifies observations based on whether they are corporations run by families; if a company fulfills any of the following requirements, it is then classified as a family firm: (1) the positions of chairman of the board of directors and of the CEO are held by members of the same family; (2) the family controls more than 50% of the board seats (excluding friendly seats) while the friendly director seats ratio and the external director seats ratio are both lower than 33%; (3) the family controls more than 33% of the board seats, while at least 3 directors or managers are from the ultimate controlling family; (4) the family-controlled shareholding ratio is higher than the necessary controlling shareholding ratio (i.e., with the controlling shareholding ratio higher than 20%) . If a firm’s seats-shareholding divergence ratio is larger than 1, it is classified as high divergence; if the seats-shareholding divergence ratio is smaller than or equal to 1, it is then classified as low divergence. Semiconductors, computer peripherals, optoelectronics, communications networks, components, electronic access, information services, and other electronics are classified as IT firms. Cement, food, plastics, textiles, electrical, chemicals, biotechnology, steel, rubber, automobiles, building materials, construction, shipping, trade, department stores, and other firms are classified as NIT firms. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. 4.2 Analysis of the relationship between the family governance of business groups and the related party purchases and sales network linkage The t-test results of Table 3 show that there may be a certain degree of relationship between the related party purchases and sales network linkage, firm type and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio. Therefore, this study further analyzes 19 how the family governance of business groups affects the related party purchases and sales network linkage. The results presented in Table 4 show that the ratio of related party sales and the number of related firms sold to are mainly influenced by the family member shareholding ratio. Specifically, the higher the family member shareholding ratio is, the lower the related party sales ratio and related party sales number will be. In addition, the related party supply ratio is negatively related to the seats-shareholding divergence ratio. Therefore, the greater the divergence is, the lower the related party supply ratio will be. On the whole, the family member shareholding ratio and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio are negatively correlated with the related party sales and supply ratios. Therefore, there is no evidence that family shareholders will exhibit opportunistic behavior when the controlling seats diverge from the controlling shareholdings. Table 4 Results on related party purchases and sales and corporate governance Variable Related party sales Related party sales Related party ratio sales number Related party purchases Related party Related party supply ratio supply number Family member shareholding ratio -0.091* -0.015*** -0.050 -0.006 (-1.863) (-3.234) (-0.785) (-0.865) Seats-shareholding divergence ratio -0.452 -0.003 -1.175** -0.046 (-1.112) (-0.072) (-2.370) (-0.976) Group size 0.358** 0.180*** 0.463** -1.700*** (2.318) (13.645) (2.163) (-10.537) 21.974*** 1.747*** 29.474*** (11.099) (9.942) (10.912) F-test 18.18*** 38.19*** 29.74*** 27.90*** LM-test 680.21*** 1.46 771.92*** 702.74*** 0.78 0.01 0.40 123.29*** 0.8522 0.164 0.9061 0.900 Intercept Hausman-test Adj R2 Note: Related party purchases and sales number are the number of related firms purchased from and sold to with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20%. Sale ratio is (dollar amount of sales to related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / total dollar amount of sales) *100%. Supply ratio is (dollar amount of purchases from related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / total dollar amount of purchases) *100%. Family member shareholding ratio is (shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total shares of the firm)*100%. Seats-shareholding divergence ratio is (family member seats ratio / family member shareholding ratio), in which the family member seats ratio = (seats held by the ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total seats of the firm)*100%; the family member shareholding ratio = (shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total shares of the firm)*100%. Group size is the number of affiliated companies in a business group. ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. 20 4.3 Analysis of the relationship between related party purchases and sales network linkages and capital structure The t-test results for firm types and industry sectors in Table 3 indicate that the differences between family and non-family firms and between IT and NIT industries in relation to related party purchases and sales network linkages may have heterogeneous influences on capital structure decisions. In addition, the results from Table 4 show that the family member shareholding ratio and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio are significantly negatively correlated with the related party purchases and sales. Therefore, by taking the family governance of business groups into consideration, this study further analyzes the relationship between related party purchases and sales network linkages and corporate capital structures. In particular, we classify 315 sample firms into four subsample groups based on firm types (family/non-family) and industry sectors (IT/NIT industry) for further panel data linear regression analysis. The number of firms in each subsample group is as follows: 75 IT family firms, 111 IT non-family firms, 102 NIT family firms and 27 NIT non-family firms. The empirical results are presented in Table 5 and Table 6. 21 Table 5 IT industry panel data linear regression analysis results Variables Related party sales no. Related party supply no. Network Linkage Related party sales ratio Related party supply ratio Corporate governance Seats-shareholding divergence ratio Total assets (LnTA) Firm characteristics Return on assets (ROA) IT family firms Short-term Long-term debt ratio debt ratio 0.058 -0.719* (0.094) (-1.712) (2.809) (0.194) 0.680 0.359 0.777 -0.0663** (1.019) (0.629) (1.547) (-2.319) 0.109* 0.065* -0.113*** -0.010 (1.782) (1.803) (-3.219) (-0.501) -0.079 0.015 0.001 -0.001 (-1.614) (0.607) (0.026) (-0.041) 0.591 -0.578** (0.993) (-1.978) 8.802*** 4.197*** -1.091 1.976*** (3.869) (5.725) (-1.244) (4.069) -0.071 -0.169*** -0.008 -0.098*** (-1.353) (-3.509) (-0.148) (-2.909) Long-term investment ratio Intercept Panel data Model tests IT non-family firms Short-term Long-term debt ratio debt ratio 1.045*** 0.041 0.029 0.022 (1.184) (1.349) -59.245*** 45.497*** -24.184*** (-5.271) (3.380) (-3.258) F-test LM-test 23.82*** 7.68*** 9.40*** 7.86*** 136.94*** 76.43*** 161.37*** 141.73*** Hausman-test 41.35*** 6.03 9.38 5.78 0.8919 0.7098 9.38 5.78 2 Adj R Number of firms (observations) 75 firms (225) 111 firms (333) Note: Long-term debt ratio is (long-term debts/total assets)* 100%. Short-term debt ratio is (short-term debts/ total assets)*100%. Sale No. is the number of related firms sold to which have trade amounts exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital of over 20%. Supply No. is the number of related firms purchased from which have trade amounts exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital of over 20%. Sale ratio is (dollar amount of sales to related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / total dollar amount of sales) *100%. Supply ratio is (dollar amount of purchases from related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / total dollar amount of purchases) *100%. Family member shareholding ratio is (shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total shares of the firm)*100%. Seats-shareholding divergence ratio is (family member seats ratio / family member shareholding ratio), in which the family member seat ratio = (seats held by the ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total seats of the firm)*100%; the family member shareholding ratio = (shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total shares of the firm)*100%. Total assets is the log of total assets. ROA is (net income after tax / average total assets) *100%. Long-term investment ratio is (long-term investment / shareholder equity)*100%. IT industry includes semiconductors, computer peripherals, optoelectronics, communications networks, components, electronic access, information services, and other electronics; in addition, if a firm fulfills any of the following requirements, it is classified as a family firm: (1) the positions of the chairman of the board of directors and the CEO are held by members of the same family; (2) the family controls more than 50% of the board seats (excluding friendly seats), while the friendly director seats ratio and the external director seats ratio are both lower than 33%; (3) the family controls more than 33% of the board seats while at least 3 directors or managers are from the ultimate controlling family; (4) the family-controlled shareholding ratio is higher than the controlling shareholding ratio (i.e., with the controlling shareholding ratio higher than 20%). ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. 22 From Table 5, we see that, for IT family firms, the long-term debt ratio and short-term debt ratio are significantly positively correlated with the related party sales ratio. The long-term debt ratio is also significantly negatively correlated with the related party sales number and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio. As for the IT non-family firms, the short-term debt ratio is significantly positively correlated with the related party sales number and significantly negatively correlated with the related party sales ratio. Furthermore, the long-term debt ratio is significantly negatively correlated with the related party supply number. Table 6 shows that, for NIT family firms, the short-term debt ratio is significantly positively correlated with the related party supply number and significantly negatively correlated with the related party sales ratio. The long-term debt ratio is significantly negatively correlated with the seats-shareholding divergence ratio. In addition, while the long-term investment ratio is significantly positively correlated with the long-term debt ratio of NIT family firms, it is significantly negatively correlated with the long-term debt ratio of NIT non-family firms. In addition, this study finds that the influence of related purchases and sales network linkages on capital structures is more evident in the IT industry (including family and non-family firms) and NIT family firms. For IT family firms, when the related party sales are more diverse (i.e., when the number of related firms sold to is high), the firm’s long-term debt financing is significantly lower. For NIT family firms, when the related party supply is more diverse (i.e., when the number of related firms purchased from is high), the firm’s short-term debt financing is significantly higher. Moreover, the related party sales ratio increases with the level of long-term and short-term debt financing levels for IT firms, but decreases with the short-term debt financing for NIT family firms. This shows that IT family firms tend to use debt to finance operational capital requirements arising from related party sales. 23 Table 6 NIT industry panel data linear regression analysis results Variables Related party sales no. Corporate governance Firm characteristics NIT non-family firms Short-term debt Long-term debt ratio ratio 0.360 (1.327) 1.181** (1.973) -0.102** (-2.541) -0.095 (-0.491) -0.249 (-0.595) -0.002 (0.936) -1.351 (-1.231) -1.032 (-1.337) 0.035 (0.246) 1.169 (1.360) 0.551 (0.912) -0.129 (-1.083) Related party supply ratio 0.003 (0.070) -0.022 (-0.826) -0.058 (-0.501) 0.113 (1.169) Seats-shareholding divergence ratio Total asset (LnTA) 0.450 (1.265) -0.478* (-1.735) -4.747*** (-4.816) 2.162*** (3.352) 33.984*** (3.745) 5.033 (0.682) -0.097 (-1.139) -0.115 (-1.636) 0.094*** (4.883) -0.566*** (-3.988) -0.283* (-1.774) -0.346** (-2.268) 99.018*** (6.418) -27.230*** (-2.766) Related party supply no. Network linkage NIT family firms Short-term debt Long-term debt ratio ratio Related party sales ratio Return on Assets (ROA) Long-term investment ratio Intercept Panel data Model tests F-test 16.76*** 8.29*** 15.29*** 17.09*** LM-test 195.59*** 106.13*** 43.09*** 30.60*** Hausman-test 10.33 11.83 18.51*** 17.94** Adj R2 0.8480 0.7226 0.8510 0.8690 Number of firms (observations) 102 firms (306) 27 firms (81) Note: Long-term debt ratio is (long-term debts/total assets)* 100%. Short-term debt ratio is (short-term debts/ total assets)*100%. Sale No. is the number of related firms sold to which have trade amounts exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital of over 20%. Supply No. is the number of related firms purchased from which have trade amounts exceeding NT$100 million or have paid-in capital of over 20%. Sale ratio is (dollar amount of sales to related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / total dollar amount of sales) *100%. Supply ratio is (dollar amount of purchases from related parties with transactions exceeding NT$100 million or with paid-in capital of over 20% / total dollar amount of purchases) *100%. Seats-shareholding divergence ratio is (family member seats ratio / family member shareholding ratio), in which the family member seats ratio = (seats held by the ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total seats of the firm)*100%; the family member shareholding ratio = (shareholdings of ultimate controlling shareholder in the family / total shares of the firm)*100%. Since the family member shareholding ratio is close to 0 in some of the NIT non-family firms, we do not include the seats-shareholding divergence ratio in the model. Total assets is the log number of total assets. ROA is (net income after tax / average total assets) *100%. Long-term investment ratio is (long-term investment / shareholder equity)*100%. NIT industry includes cement, food, plastics, textiles, electrical, chemicals, biotechnology, steel, rubber, automobiles, building materials, construction, shipping, trade, department stores, and others; in addition, if a firm fulfills any of the following requirements, it is classified as family firm: (1) the positions of chairman of the board of directors and the CEO are held by members of the same family; (2) the family controls more than 50% of the board seats (excluding friendly seats), while the friendly director seats ratio and the external director seats ratio are both lower than 33%; (3) the family controls more than 33% of the board seats while at least 3 directors or managers are from the ultimate controlling family; (4) the family controlled shareholding ratio is higher than the necessary controlling shareholding ratio (i.e., with the controlling shareholding ratio being higher than 20%). ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. 24 Moreover, the seats-shareholding divergence ratio is positively correlated with the short-term debt ratio for IT and NIT family firms, but is negatively correlated with the long-term debt financing. The results suggest that when the seats-shareholding divergence ratio is high, IT and NIT family firms prefer to use short-term debt financing, similar to the findings of Du and Dai (2005). That is, high divergence increases the risk-taking tendency in a firm’s capital structure. Finally, this study finds that NIT family firms prefer to use long-term debt financing for long-term investments. Whether this will result in agency problems where the family shareholders use debt financing as a way to engage in opportunistic behavior needs to be further studied. Based on the results in Table 5 and Table 6, we summarize the findings on the relationship between network linkages, industries, family governance and capital structures (short-term debt ratio, SD or long-term debt ratio, LD) on a relationship diagram as shown in Figure 1. The horizontal and vertical axes are family governance and the industry sectors, respectively. On the whole, the related party purchases and sales network linkages give rise to opposite results in terms of their influences on the capital structures in the family/non-family firms of different industries. For IT/NIT family firms, the related party sales ratio and long-term debt of IT family firms are positively correlated, while the related party sales ratio and long-term debt of NIT family firms are negatively correlated. In addition, the related party sales ratio has a negative effect on the short-term debt of IT family firms, while it has a positive influence on long-term debt, with the opposite results being found for NIT family firms. The results show that IT family firms tend to use debt financing to provide financial support to related parties through the sales network linkage. Consequently, we need to take note of whether this behavior will create agency problems in IT family shareholders. In terms of IT/NIT non-family firms, the related party supply number and supply ratio have positive effects on the short-term debt of IT non-family firms and negative effects on their long-term debt, with the opposite results being found for NIT non-family firms. Thus, the results show that the related party purchases network linkage increases the maturity risk in capital structures for IT non-family firms. 25 IT High related party sale no. – high SD*, high LD High related party supply no. – high SD, low LD* High related party sale ratio – low SD*, low LD High related party supply ratio – high SD, low LD High related party sale no. – high SD, low LD* High related party supply no. – high SD, high LD High related party sale ratio – high SD*, high LD* High related party supply ratio – low SD, high LD Non-family Family High related party sale no. – low SD, high LD High related party supply no. – low SD, high LD High related party sale ratio – high SD, low LD High related party supply ratio – low SD, high LD High related party sale no. – high SD, low LD High related party supply no. – high SD*, low LD High related party sale ratio – low SD*, low LD High related party supply ratio – high SD, low LD NIT Note: * represents a statistically significant relationship. SD is the short-term debt ratio. LD is the long-term debt ratio. Figure 1 Relationship diagram for network linkages, industries, family governance and capital structures 5. Conclusion In recent years, with the trend toward globalization and liberalization, corporations have faced increasingly fierce competition in the global market and a rapidly changing global economic environment. This has forced companies to develop closer working relationships with each other through network linkages in order to achieve resource sharing, business growth, and enhanced competitiveness. A network relationship is an important resource for constructing an effective value chain during a company’s development process as it can enhance the company’s competitive advantage and firm value, which is achieved through reduced debt financing levels. Therefore, capital structure issues can be examined from the perspective of network linkages. This can not only enable one to further analyze the firm’s financing leverage and its optimal financing level, but can also lead studies on capital structure to a new field. Therefore, this study contributes to the literature by examining the changes in 26 capital structure from the perspective of business transaction network linkages. This issue is under-researched by scholars and provides an area for innovative research. This study is based on a sample of TSE-listed and OTC business groups in Taiwan from 2006 to 2008. The sample is categorized into four subsample groups based on the industry sectors (IT/NIT industry) and business types (family/non-family). The related party purchases and sales linkages in the industrial cooperation system are used to proxy for network linkages. In addition to analyzing the relationship between family governance and network linkages in Taiwanese listed and OTC business groups, we construct the panel data linear regression model for network linkages and capital structure decisions. We include the effect of family governance on business groups in the model and analyze the relationship between the related party purchases and sales network linkages and capital structures of Taiwanese listed and OTC business groups. Overall, this study finds that shareholdings of family members and the seats-shareholding divergence ratio are negatively correlated with the related party sales and supply number. Therefore, the results indicate that when the seat control rights diverge from the voting rights, there is no clear evidence that family shareholders or large shareholders will use related party transactions to obtain personal benefits. Secondly, the effects of related party purchases and sales network linkages on capital structures have opposite results for family/non-family firms and different industries. The related party sales ratio is positively correlated with the debt of IT family firms, while it is negatively correlated with the debt of NIT firms. In addition, the related party supply ratio is negatively and positively correlated with the short-term and long-term debts of IT family firms, respectively. However, the results are reversed for NIT family firms. Moreover, the related party supply number and supply ratio have positive and negative effects on the short-term and long-term debt of IT non-family firms, respectively. The influences are again reversed for NIT non-family firms. Thus, the results indicate that IT family firms tend to use debt financing to fund the capital needs required by related party sales network linkages. However, we need to take note of whether this behavior will create agency problems for IT family shareholders and whether the related party purchases network linkages will increase the maturity risk in the capital structures of IT non-family firms. That is, for IT non-family firms, we need to take note of whether there will be an increase in 27 short-term debt financing when the number of related firms purchased from or the related purchases in dollar amounts is high. Finally, this study finds that the seats-shareholding divergence ratios of IT and NIT family firms are positively and negatively correlated with the short-term and long-term debt ratios, respectively, indicating that the seats-shareholding divergence ratios will influence the risk-taking tendency in firms’ capital structure decisions. To sum up, this study finds that network linkages do indeed influence firms’ capital structures. However, in analyzing the relationship between the related party purchases and sales network linkages and the capital structure, we need to take into consideration the industrial differences and the influence of family involvement in corporate governance. Future studies could examine the effect on companies’ capital structures by integrating the dynamic adjustments of network linkages and director linkages using the latent variable structural equation modeling approach and discuss the relationship between manifest variables, latent variables and disturbance variables. The simultaneous equations model could be used to estimate the regression coefficients between endogenous variables and exogenous variables, thereby enabling analyses to be performed on the direct effects, indirect effects and total effects on capital structures under dynamic adjustments to network linkages and director linkages. 28 References Aggarwal, R. (1981). “International differences in capital structure norms: An empirical study of large European countries.” Management International Review 21: 75-88. Aggarwal, R. and G. Baliga (1987). “Capital structure among Latin American companies.” Managerial Finance 13: 3-11. Agrawal, A. and C. Mandelker (1990). “Large shareholders and the monitoring of managers: The case of antitakeover charter amendments.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 25: 143-161. Almeida, H. and D. Wolfenzon (2005). “A theory of pyramidal ownership and family business groups.” Journal of Finance 61: 2637–2680. Anderson, R., S. Mansi, and D. Reeb (2003). “Founding family ownership and the agency costs of debt.” Journal of Financial Economics 68: 263-285. Anderson, R. and D. Reeb (2003). “Founding-family ownership and firm performance: Evidence from the S&P 500.” Journal of Finance 53: 1301-1328. Anderson, R. and D. Reeb (2004). “Board composition: Balancing family influence in S&P 500 firms.” Administrative Science Quarterly 49: 209-237. Arslan, O. and M. B. Karan (2006). “Ownership and control structure as determinants of corporate debt maturity: A panel study of an emerging market.” Corporate Governance 14: 312-324. Banerjee, S., S. Dasgupta, and Y. Kim (2008). “Buyer-supplier relationships and the stakeholder theory of capital structure.” Journal of Finance 63: 2507-2554. Barney, J. B. (1991). “Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage.” Journal of Management 17: 99-120. Baskin, J. (1989). “An empirical investigation of the pecking order hypothesis.” Financial Management 18: 26-35. Belkaoui, A. (1974). “A Canadian survey of financial structure.” Financial Management 4: 74-79. Berkman, H., R. A. Cole, and L. J. Fu (2009). “Expropriation through loan guarantees to related parties: Evidence from China.” Journal of Banking and Finance 33: 141-156. Bertrand, M., P. Mehta, and S. Mullainathan (2002). “Ferreting out tunneling: An application to Indian business groups.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 121–48. 29 Blankenburg H. D., K. Eriksson, and J. Johanson (1999). “Creating value through mutual commitment to business network relations.” Strategic Management Journal 20: 467-486. Bowen, R. M., L. A. Daley, and C. C. Hubert, Jr. (1982). “Leverage measures and industrial classification: Review and additional evidence.” Financial Management 11: 10-20. Bozec, Y. and C. Laurin (2008). “Large shareholder entrenchment and performance: Empirical evidence from Canada.” Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 35: 25-49. Burkart, M., F. Panunzi, and A. Shleifer (2003). “Family firms.” Journal of Finance 58: 2167-2201. Carney, M. and E. Gedajlovic (2002). “The coupling of ownership and control and the allocation of financial resources: Evidence from Hong Kong.” Journal of Management Studies 39: 123-146. Chang, S. (2003). “Ownership structure, expropriation, and performance of group-affiliated companies in Korea.” Academy of Management Journal 46: 238-254. Cheung, Y. L., Y. Qi, P. Raghavendra Rau, and A. Stouraitis (2009). “Buy high, sell low: How listed firms price asset transfers in related party transactions.” Journal of Banking and Finance 33: 914-924. Chung, C. N. (2001). “Markets, culture and institutions: The emergence of large business groups in Taiwan.” Journal of Management Studies 38: 719-745. Claessens S., S. Djankov, and L. H. P. Lang (2000). “The separation of ownership and control in East Asian corporations.” Journal of Financial Economics 58: 81-112. Coleman, J. S. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA. Collin, S. O. (1998). “Why are these islands of conscious power found in the ocean of ownership? Institutional and governance hypotheses explaining the existence of business groups in Sweden.” Journal of Management Studies 35: 719-746. Dammon, R. M. and L. W. Senbet (1988). “The effect of taxes and depreciation on corporate investment and financial leverage.” Journal of Finance 43: 357-374. DeAngelo, H. and R. Masulis (1980). “Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxation.” Journal of Financial Economics 8: 3-29. Demsetz, H. (1983). “The structure of ownership and the theory of the firm.” Journal of Law and Economics 26: 375-393. 30 Dierickx, I. and K. Cool (1989). “Asset stock accumulation and the sustainability of competitive advantage.” Management Science 35: 1504-1511. Du, J. and Y. Dai (2005). “Ultimate corporate ownership structures and capital structures: Evidence from East Asian economies.” Corporate Governance 13: 60-71. Dyer, J. and H. Singh (1998). “The relational view: Cooperative strategies and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage.” Academy of Management Review 23: 660-679. Elfring, T. and W. Hulsink (2003). “Networks in entrepreneurship: The case of high technology firms.” Small Business Economics 21: 409-422. Errunza, V. R. (1979). “Determinants of financial structure in the central American common market.” Financial Management, 8: 72-77. Faccio, M. and L. H. P. Lang (2002). “The ultimate ownership of Western European corporations.” Journal of Financial Economics 65: 365–95. Ferri, M. G. and W. H. Jones (1979). “Determinants of financial structure: A new methodological approach.” Journal of Finance, 34: 631-644. Filatotchev, I., Y. C. Lien, and J. Piesse (2005). “Corporate governance and performance in publicly-listed, family-controlled firms: Evidence from Taiwan.” Asia Pacific Journal of Management 22: 257-283. Fosberg, R. H. (2004). “Agency problems and debt financing: Leadership structure effects.” Corporate Governance 4: 31-38. Friend, I. and L. H. P. Lang (1988). “An empirical test of the impact of managerial self-interest on corporate capital structure.” Journal of Finance, 43: 271-281. Gerlach, M. L. (1992). “The Japanese corporate network: A blockmodel analysis.” Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 88-105. Gilles, P. L. (1999). “A fresh look at incentive plans for privately-held companies.” Compensation and Benefits Review 31: 61-72. Granovetter, M. (1995). “Coase revisited: Business groups in the modern economy.” Industrial and Corporate Change 4: 93-130. Granovetter, M. (2005). “Business group and social organization.” In N. Smelser and R. Swedberg (eds.), Handbook of Economic Sociology, 429-450. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Griliches, Z. and J. A. Hausman (1986). “Error-in-variables in panel data.” Journal of Econometrics 31: 93-118. Grossman, S. and O. Hart (1988). “Corporate governance: Voting rights and majority 31 rules.” Journal of Financial Economics 20: 203-235. Grossman, S. and O. Hart (1980). “Takeover bids, the free-rider problem and the theory of the corporation.” Bell Journal of Economics 11: 42-64. Guillen, M. F. (2000). “Business groups in emerging economies: A resource base view.” Academy of Management Journal 43: 362-380. Gulati, R. (1999). “Network location and learning: The influence of network resources and firm capabilities on alliance formation.” Strategic Management Journal 20: 397-420. Gulati, R. and J. Westphal (1999). “Cooperative or controlling? The effect of CEO-based relations and the content of interlocks on the formation of joint ventures.” Administrative Science Quarterly 44: 473-506. Harris, M. and R. Raviv (1988). “Corporate governance: Voting rights and majority rules.” Journal of Financial Economics 20: 203-235. Haugen, R. A. and L. W. Senbet (1979). “New perspectives on informational asymmetry and agency relationships.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 14: 671-694. Hausman, J. A. (1978). “Specification test in econometrics.” Econometric Society 46(6): 1251-1271. Hsiao, C. (1985). “Benefits and limitations of panel data.” Econometric Reviews 4: 121-174. Hsiao, C. (1991). “Identification and estimation of latent binary choice models using panel data.” Review of Economic Studies 58: 717-731. Hsiao, C. (2003). Analysis of panel data, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hsiao, C. and G. Taylor (1991). “Some remarks on measurement errors and the identification of panel data models.” Statistica Neerlandica 45: 187-194. Hutchinson, M. (2002). “An analysis of the association between firms’ investment opportunities, board composition, and firm performance.” Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting and Economics 9: 17-38. James, H. (1999). “Owner as manager, extended horizons and the family firm.” International Journal of the Economics of Business 6: 41-55. Jarillo, J. C. (1988). “On strategic networks.” Strategic Management Journal 9: 31-41. Jensen, M. (1986). “Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers.” American Economic Review 76: 323-329. 32 Jensen, M. C. and W. Meckling (1976). “Theory of the firm: management behavior, agency costs and ownership structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305-360. Joh, S. (2003). “Corporate governance and firm profitability: Evidence from Korea before the economic crisis.” Journal of Financial Economics 68: 287-322. Johanson, J. and L. G. Mattsson, 1987. “Interorganizational relations in industrial systems: A network approach compared with the transaction-cost approach.” International Studies of Management and Organization 17: 34-48. Johnston, R. and P. R. Lawrence (1988). “Beyond vertical integration – The rise of the value-adding partnership.” Harvard Business Review 88: 94-101. Johnson, S., F. La Porta, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny (2000). “Tunneling.” American Economic Review 90: 22–27. Keister, L. A. (1998). “Engineering growth: Business group structure and firm performance in China’s transition economy.” American Journal of Sociology 104: 404-440. Kester, W. C. (1986). “Capital and ownership structure: A comparison of United States and Japanese manufacturing corporations.” Financial Management 15: 5-16. Khanna, T. and K. Palepu (2000). “The future of business in emerging markets: Long-run evidence from Chile.” Academy of Management Journal 43: 268-285. Khanna, T. and J. W. Rivkin (2001). “Estimating the performance effects of business groups in emerging markets.” Strategic Management Journal 22:45-74. Kuo, H. C., L. H. Wang, and S. Wu (2000). “The determinants of capital structure for small and medium enterprises in Taiwan.” Advances in Pacific Basin Business, Economics, and Finance 4: 23-36. Kuo, H. C. (2006). “Network linkage and financial leverage.” Journal of Financial Studies 14: 95-123. Kuo, H. C., Li, Y. and H. S. Ho (2003). “Financial network linkages on capital structure.” The 11th Annual Conference on Pacific Basin Finance, Economics, and Accounting, Taipei, R.O.C. Leff, N. H. (1979). “Entreprencurship and economic development: The problem revisited.” Journal of Economic Literature 17: 46-64. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. (1999). “Corporate ownership around the world.” The Journal of Finance 54: 471–517. Lins, K. V. (2003). “Equity ownership and firm value in emerging markets.” Journal 33 of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38: 159–84. Luo, X. and Chung, C. (2005). “Keeping it all in the family: The role of particularistic relationships in business group performance during institutional transition.” Administrative Science Quarterly 50: 404-439. Mahaffy, P. A. (1998). “Shotguns, puts and calls: The advantages of buy/sell agreements for closely-held companies.” CMA Magazine 71: 23-25. Modigliani, F. and M. Miller (1958). “The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory on investment.” American Economic Review 48: 261-297. Moh’d, M. A., L. G. Perry, and J. N. Rimbey (1998). “The impact of ownership structure on corporate debt policy: A time-series cross-sectional analysis.” The Financial Review 33: 85-98. Morellec, E. (2004). “Can managerial discretion explain observed leverage ratios?” The Review of Financial Studies 17: 257-294. Morck, R., D.Wolfenson, and B. Yeung (2005). “Corporate governance, economic entrenchment and growth.” Journal of Economic Literature 43: 655–721. Myers, S. C. (1977). “The determinants of corporate borrowing.” Journal of Financial Economics 5: 147-175. Myers, S. C. and N. S. Majluf (1984). “Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have.” Journal of Financial Economics 13: 187-221. Naidu, G.N. (1983). “Country and industry norms of capital structure: Asian evidence.” Management International Review 23: 64-70. Porter, M. (1980). Competitive Strategy. Free Press: New York. Powell, W. W., K. Koput, and L. Smith-Doerr (1996). “Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation: Networks of learning in biotechnology.” Administrative Science Quarterly 41: 116-145. Prahalad, C. K. and G. Hamel (1990). “The core competence of the corporation.” Harvard Business Review 68(3): 79-91 Remmers, L., A. Stonehill, R. Wright, and T. Beekhuisen (1974). “Industry and size as debt ratio determinants in manufacturing internationally.” Financial Management 3: 24-32. Riyanto, Y. E., Toolsema, L. A. (2008). “Tunneling and propping: A justification for pyramidal ownership.” Journal of Banking and Finance 32: 2178–2187. Ross, S. A. (1985). “Debt and taxes and uncertainty.” Journal of Finance 40: 637-656. Ross, S. (1977). “The determinants of financial structure: The incentive signaling 34 approach.” Bell Journal of Economics 8: 23-40. Schneider, M. (2000). “When financial intermediaries are corporate owners: An agency model of institutional ownership.” Journal of Management and Governance 4: 207-237. Scott, D. F. and J. D. Martin (1975). “Industry influence on financial structure.” Financial Management 4: 67-73. Sekely, W. and J.M. Collins (1988). “Cultural influences on international capital structure.” Journal of International Business Studies, 19: 87-100. Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny (1986). “Large shareholders and corporate control.” Journal of Political Economy 94: 461-488. Smith, C. W. Jr. and R. L. Watts (1992). “The investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend, and compensation policies.” Journal of Financial Economics 32: 263-292. Stonehill, A., T. Beekhuisen, R. Wright, L. Remmers, N. Toy, A. Pares, A. Shapiro, D. Egan, and T. Bates (1974). “Financial goals and debt ratio determinants: A survey of practices in five countries.” Financial Management 4: 27-41. Stulz, R. (1988). “Managerial control of voting rights: Financing policies and the market for corporate control.” Journal of Financial Economics 20: 25-54. Thorelli, H. B. (1986). “Network: Between markets and hierarchies.” Strategic Management Journal 7: 37-51. Titman, S. (1984). “The effect of capital structure on a firm’s liquidation decision.” Journal of Financial Economics 13: 137-151. Titman, S. and R. Wessels (1988). “The determinants of capital structure choice.” Journal of Finance 43: 1-19. Uzzi, B. (1997). “Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: The paradox of embeddedness.” Administrative Science Quarterly 42: 35-67. Vicente-Lorente, J. D. (2001). “Specificity and opacity as resource-based determinants of capital structure: Evidence for Spanish manufacturing firms.” Strategic Management Journal 22: 157-177. Warner, J. B. (1977). “Bankruptcy costs: Some evidence.” Journal of Finance 32: 337-347. Wernerfelt, B. (1984). “A resource-based view of the firm.” Strategic Management Journal 5: 171-180. Wong, S. L. (1985). “The Chinese family firm: A model.” The British Journal of 35 Sociology 36: 58-72. Yammeesri, J. and S. C. Lodh (2004). “Is family ownership a pain or gain to firm performance?” Journal of American Academy of Business 4: 263-270. Yeh, Y. H., T. S. Lee, and T. Woidtke (2001). “Family control and corporate governance: Evidence for Taiwan.” International Review of Finance 2: 21-48. Yeh, Y. H. (2005). “Do controlling shareholders enhance corporate value?” Corporate Governance 13: 313-325. 36