CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Working Group 6: The Reform of the State Bureaucracy Coordinator: Byung-Kook Kim The Reform of the State Bureaucracy Béatrice Hibou* Session 4 questions A et C * Do privatisation, downsizing, deregulation and decentralisation do what they claim to do: raise efficiency, cut down deficits, expand consumer’s choice and further democratic consolidation ? * Has privatisation simply replaced public monopoly with private monopoly? What is the value of privatisation if it does not strengthen competition? * What shouldn’t reformers do when reforming state bureaucracy? What is privatization beyond a lesson in the rules of the market incarnated in competition? Privatization can no longer be thought of as the sole modality for the transfer of assets from the public sphere to the private sphere. Today, privatization is applied not only to public companies, but also public services (through concessions and delegations), economic resources (the appropriation and exploitation of natural resources and national heritage), functions once undertaken by the state (labor management, economic regulation), and even the regalian functions of the state (customs, the tax system, interior and exterior security). In other words, privatization now touches upon modes of government in and of * The following observations derive from research conducted over approximately ten years in African and North African countries, as well as in Greece and Portugal. 1/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou themselves. Beyond the effects of competition, this is no doubt the most important of its consequences. Evidently, according to elementary economic principles, the privatization of public enterprises and the transfer of property signifies: • a new mode of management • the primacy of the criteria of efficacy and profitability • the efficient allocation of productive resources • the realization of a true “market economy” • the inflow of new capital But the modalities and the results of privatizations of public enterprises are always a reflection of political systems, national historical trajectories, and the modes of insertion in the international domain. They reveal, then, the state of political and economic societies insofar as political logics also take place in the economic realm. The observation of concrete privatization practice (and, more generally, liberalization reforms) suggests that such reforms are in fact applied in a manner that deviates from the discursive precepts and logics set forth in theory. Moreover, the sociopolitical effects of these reforms also diverge significantly from planned results. For this session’s debate, I will underscore two important points. First, measures that seek to diminish the weight and interventions of the state in the economy do not signify real autonomy of the economic realm with respect to the political realm. Second, despite demands from civil society and conditionalities put forth in terms of “good government” and “capacity building,” reforms lead to the reinforcement of both elites and regimes in power. The link between economic and political 2/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou liberalization, which underlies the interventions of international founders and the prevailing ideology of the international community, is far from coming to pass. To the contrary, the margins for action for countries undergoing reform appear to be significant, at least from a political point of view. In this context, a point can be stressed. The myth of “rule of laws” stems from an approach that stresses procedures, rules, and the law over the substance of public action and regulation. Provisions are made for the determination of fixed and known rules that are identical for all. The disengagement of the state (downsizing and process of delegation to private entities) and privatizations are part of this framework insofar as they reduce pockets of specific regulation and thus tend to diminish discretionary behavior on the part of the political administration. Stability, transparency, and the predictability of rules and economic texts are supposed to secure economic actors, accelerate growth, and favor investment. And economic actions are supposed to be depoliticized due to strict definitions of the public and private spheres, as well as of relations between them. Ultimately, implicit definitions of the state and the public realm mobilize the concept of “rule of law.” The implicit model is the so-called Weberian model of the rational-legal state and the assumption that state interventions are bureaucratized and repetitive. This model presupposes a certain number of normative and circumstantial principles, which are often not made explicit as such. They include the unity of the principles of state action (legality, universality, bureaucratization, direct control) and the duality of organization (clear distinctions between economic and political goals, between the state and the market, between public and private, between legal and illegal), which is based on the idea of fixed and stable boundaries. Since the nature and the historicity of states vary from one country 3/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou to country, this model of the idealized state put forth by theories of European state formation and the attempt to impose the “rule of law” can only fail. Taking into account all these considerations, the privatization of public enterprises has necessarily a political signification, and a different signification in each country. Broadly categorizing it, these privatizations can involve: • a means of capturing resources for the profit of the reigning nomenklatura (Russia, Poland, most African countries where privatizations actually occurred). • simply cosmetic gestures that correspond to an organized resistance or strongly entrenched political and bureaucratic power (Iran, Egypt, and many African countries where privatizations were not actualized). • a true attempt at rupture with the preceding order (the case of the Landers in the eastern part of reunified Germany) • informal practices (Mozambique, Russia, China) • captured by parallel networks (Nigeria, Ivory Coast, Cameroon) • used as a means to launder money (Senegal, South Africa, Mozambique, Russia…) These privatizations are inscribed in particular historical trajectories and thus take on precise meanings with respect to political economy and modes of government. Therefore, the privatization of public enterprises can also correspond to: • the modification of modalities associated with an “economy of pillage” (SubSaharan Africa, Russia) • the exacerbation of factional struggles (Sub-Saharan Africa) 4/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou • a strategy for the displacement of exterior rents (Sub-Saharan Africa, North Africa) • the increased consolidation of a circle of influential actors (Morocco) • a strategy for the fragmentation of potential rivals (Tunisia) • the institutionalization and affirmation of the principles of federalism (the eastern Landers of Germany) • the end of a political parenthesis and the return of dominant economic actors (the case of Portugal at the end of the revolutionary period and the return of the “great families” to the national economy) In this context of privatization and liberal ideology, reforms of the state administration entail a certain number of practices or measures that must be avoided or regarded with circumspection The cosmetic ministers and the government of technocrats. Countries undergoing reforms generally know how to present the ideal profile of a minister: technical competence; apparent apolitical positions; the adoption of “modern” language and discourse, as well as the latest jargon. But reforms do not issue from ministers, nor do they simply arise from discourse. And hence one must take into account the real structures of power that are often situated outside (or at least partially) of government. Another version of this politics of facades lays in the formation of a government of technocrats. The international lending agencies and the “modernizing” elite are both tempted to think that economic and administrative reforms essential to the modernization and democratization of 5/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou the country will take place more easily through the technical means and the depoliticization of measures taken by the government. This of course denies the fact that reforms are necessarily political. By barring politics from the debate, political forces lose their credibility and the process of democratization is implicitly hindered. Government has to assume the political nature of reforms (be they economic, administrative or so on). Constituting and utilizing an efficient and isolated group in the heart of the administration. In anticipating the results of reform processes, governments and international lenders are often tempted to utilize such groups in order to put forth and make acceptable new texts, new modes of intervention, and new plans of action. But this strategy risks reinforcing the weaknesses, or even the demise, of the administration in place by: 1) demobilizing other parts of the administration, 2) removing select technocrats who are part of this central group from the difficulties involved with the concrete implementation of reforms, and 3) by aggravating the loss of legitimacy of the public sector and accelerating the creation of parallel economic and administrative structures; 4) taking time in reshuffling organization and getting bureaucrats to adjust to new institutional arrangements. Another variant: the partial and temporary privatization of public services. Facing the enormous constraints and sometimes the demise of the administration, there is a temptation to privatize certain regalian functions, such as customs, the tax system, and even national security for a temporary duration (the time to “get the administration up to level”). In these cases, private foreign companies (being mostly French, English, American, and Swiss) take over the verification of accounts and the administration of public services. This 6/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou measure is not only inefficient (due to the resistance of local people, the impossibility of escaping the political origins of administrative inefficiencies, the absence of apprenticeships), but it also often produces perverse effects, such as motivations for “wild privatizations”; the delegation of state sovereignty to third parties, which can lead to local resistance movements to foreign parties and the impossibility of continuing with administrative reforms. In theory, national solution is always possible and even sometimes preferred by government (but not always – for technical, political or corruption reasons). But in reality, it is most often foreign companies because of competence or capital. Of course, one can be less negative for privatization of enterprises. Anyway, the lack of competence to control the specifications and more broadly the terms of reference the contracts is a serious problem. So the government must not rely too much on concessionary companies, but must develop also a competence inside the administration to be able to control. The suppression of discretionary public interventions. The almost immediate and universal response to administrative corruption is to suppress the discretionary character of state interventions so as to avoid all personalized interactions between agents. However, the relationship between corruption and discretionality is not unequivocal. Indeed, corruption can allow for the creation of discretionality and flexibility when these are in short order. Corruption is not a matter of technique, but is a political concern. Government has to face this difficult issue politically. 7/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou • The establishment of of purely technical measures destined to eliminate fraud and illegal behaviour. Computerization, administrative restructurings, repressive techniques, the privatisation of surveillance, and so forth…obtain particularly poor economic results since they do not account for social and political phenomena that are inherent to fraud and illicit behaviour. On the contrary, these technical measures benefit those who are most able to take advantage of new modes of accumulation, and to act in the political realm in order to rework fraudulent techniques. In other words, fraud, smuggling, tax evasion, black market, money laundering etc. cannot be fight by technical measures only. In most country, there is an illusion of technicity. These phenomena are socially and politically embedded and it is by political measures that government can fight them. Government cannot only rely on technical measure (even if they can be useful, of course), but must have the courage to see the political dimension of it (that is to say let the judicial actors to do their work, punish the politicians that are implied…) The obsession with new rules. The concrete implementation of good intentions (establishing “rule of law” and legislating new rules) confronts the real functioning of the political economies of countries undergoing reforms. This is less a matter of the absences of rules, or the imperfect and even perverse nature of existing laws as it is a question of the systematic circumvention of these rules and laws. Problems arise because legal or official texts are not respected. Changes in legislation do not modify this behavior, which is based precisely on strategies that seek to play off rules. The inadequacy of rules is not at issue. Rather, the systematic non-respect of rules is what is at hand, both extant and new rules being subject to the same processes. It is not only a problem of implementation. It is also a 8/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou problem of conception of these new rules that are often “imported” from “models” in a technical and partial manner and forget all the environment that make a new rule efficient. The most obvious institutional arrangement to improve this situation is an efficient and functioning independent justice system and a curb to impunity (most often political impunity) . The myth of transparency. Transparency is today one of the master words evoked with reference to the principles underlying the rule of laws. Indeed, the virtues of transparency are obvious in theory. But in reality, they are far from proven: the dramatic increase in information – which often gives rise to contradictory facts – does not simplify, but rather destabilizes the formation of judgments and may even facilitate the expression of particular interests associated with particular kinds of information. Furthermore, objective information does not exist and its treatment is thus irrelevant. Finally, the myth of transparency goes hand in hand with the illusion of the possibility of the exhaustive incorporation of information (even though selectivity is the constitutive principle of the gaze) and the domination of simple ideas. Given this, more than transparency, one runs the risk of communicating or transferring opaqueness. Systematic liberal discourse. To the extent that administrative reforms (downsizing, privatization and deregulation) are inscribed in a more general process of liberalization reforms, they are inevitably subject to a congenital disease: the loss of credibility and legitimacy of the “public” domain. Without entering into the details of the consequences of such an approach, one point merits our attention: the absence of competent civil servants for the realization of reforms and the brain drain (either towards the private sector or 9/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou towards foreign countries). There is a contradiction between the liberal discourse on privatization, deregulation, downsizing on one hand and, in the other hand, the need of much more competence for the conception and implementation of these reforms. The dangers of wide-ranging and urgent conditionalities. In order to respond to the problem of widespread abuses and misappropriations, as well as the misuse of funds, international lenders tend to put pressure on recipient countries and hence both reinforce conditionalities and make compromise at all costs. In the case of most states and administrations undergoing reform, the result of this action is usually the inverse. Exterior pressures incite governments to utilize double language, to put forth pretences, to diversions and even illicit practices. The lenders often accept not quite orthodox arrangements, including dubious, makeshift, and provisional solutions. Often they fail to penalize abuses and counter-performances and doing so, they tend to weaken the very institutions that are to be strengthened via reforms (namely, the state bureaucracy). Recent experiences have tolled the bell for such conditionalities (which have been diverted by both recipient countries and donors themselves) and call for a return to the original and narrow definition of conditionality, that is to say, less a question of shorter list (which is different from each kind of reform) than a question of conception of the conditionality (and the original and narrow definition of conditionality was a financial one).. The consequence, for governments under reforms, is to discuss with the leading donors in order to come back to this original and narrow definition of financial consitionality. Conditionalities would be restricted to specific programs (financing electricity plants, for example) and not be 10/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou extended to reforms which are political processes before being economic or administrative ones. Emphasis put on sought-after results and not on actual practices. The donors’ attitudes, which insist upon desired results and disregard the means by which they are obtained, have one unintended consequence: the informal and non-institutional reinforcement of extant regimes. The priority placed upon objectives (“more market,” “less state,” and “reforms at all cost”) over means used to arrive at them is such that donors are particularly tolerant as to the ways and means by which African countries liberalize and, above all, privatize. For most donors, the emergence of capitalism depends upon the concentration of wealth and the rise of an entrepreneurial bourgeoisie. Moreover, the adoption of management techniques by rational enterprises and the anchoring of market mechanisms constitute the necessary and sufficient conditions for economic development. Finally, donors are not all that concerned with either modalities for accessing wealth or sociopolitical processes that accompany transformations in economic management. However, it seems that quite troubling sociopolitical effects can issue from particular manners of implementing reforms: increase of inequalities, of corruption, of patrimonialism, even criminalization. If they really want to reform, the governments have to get in mind all these sociopolitical effects to better negotiate. The dispersion and fragmentation of state decision-making. Through their expertise and their conditionalities, donors (World Bank, IMF, European Commission) contribute to the breakup of the state’s centers of decision-making. This dispersion of power and controls affects administrative efficiency, and hence its legitimacy. 11/12 CONFERENCE ON DEMOCRATIC TRANSITION AND CONSOLIDATION Béatrice Hibou Furthermore, by aggravating the fragmentation of the administration and society, central political power becomes more and more limited. The inversion of legitimacy. Due to the supremacy of the international over the domestic is particularly pernicious. It often has consequences for state legitimacy. For example, insofar as political leaders depend largely on external resources to balance their budgets (direct public funding; access to international financial markets because of “credibility” stemming from the signature of structural adjustment programs with Bretton Woods institutions; fiscal receipts obtained from large international investors - oil, mining assured by the adoption of reforms) or on access to modern administrative techniques, they tend to pay more attention to the financial exigencies of international lenders than the economic and political demands of citizens. Because international legitimacy is critical for both economic and financial realms, this reversal relegates the quest for political and social legitimacy to second rank. The loss of legitimacy of public power is thus accelerated by this external priority, which has damaging consequences for democratization. A political conclusion can be made: in terms of democratization and even in terms of efficiency of reforms, it seems better for government to accept the difficult task to impose a national political debate rather than to put the responsibility of difficulties on international lenders. In conclusion, two points can be underline in terms of recommendations: first, that we cannot think as if there was some “best” model or practice since all questions about reforms are politically and historically embedded; second, thinking in terms of techniques may be illusory since the roots of reforms (be they administrative, economic or institutional) lies in the politics. 12/12