CHALLENGES IN PRIVATE STRUCTURE INFRASTRUCTURE PROJECTS Presentation at the SAFIR Programme in Sri Lanka By S L Rao 1) Infrastructure in developing countries, as in most developed countries till a few years ago, has been an area in which the major investment in generating and providing the services was by governments. This was true in all areas: Electricity (not as much in oil and gas production though governments played a crucial role in giving support); Transport; Water and Sanitation; Railways; Road transport; Airports and Telecommunications. It was only in the 1980’s as privatization and less government swept economic policy, coinciding with the decline of the Soviet Union, that the provision of infrastructure services by private parties began to be seriously considered by some governments. The USA was a different case since private provision of many infrastructure services like power, oil and gas, road and rail transport and telecommunications, were in the private sector almost from the outset. 2) The developing economies had been subject to Marxist ideologies and believed that only government could be trusted to look after the interests of the most vulnerable sections of society in the provision of these services. Scarcity of resources, the lack of a thriving private sector and the superior ability of government to raise the required large resources domestically and overseas, were some reasons for government dominance of infrastructure investment. There was a common feeling in these countries (among many even today) that opening infrastructure to the private sector would hurt the interests of the many poor who could not afford to pay for their full costs, and given the low levels of usage might not get good quality service. Where the sector was already in government hands, their disinvestments to private parties was felt to be giving away national assets built by the State. In the case of new projects it was felt that at least some of private parties who came forward were bogus ones who did not have expertise and many times not even the finances, but were looking to raise it on the back of such a project. Private investors were expected to exploit consumers, raise tariffs, serve only prosperous customers, create private monopolies and prevent competition. 3) Private investors also saw many risks in investing in infrastructure projects in developing countries. There were payment risks, that they would not get paid for their services or paid inadequately. There was always the fear of government taking over the assets with little compensation. Public opinion seemed to disfavour private investment in these areas and governments and political parties were not very vocal in support. If private investment is to come about, there has to be an enabling environment for it and a long-term commitment to infrastructure development from government. This requires that governments are willing to take unpopular actions like forcing higher tariffs, stopping services to these who do not pay their bills, prosecuting thieves, etc. 4) What are some prerequisites if private investment is to enter into infrastructure areas? There must be a strong, fair, objective, unbiased regulatory framework. The institutional framework of consultants, lawyers, Courts, credit rating agencies, merchant bankers, etc must also be well established. The markets must be contestable so that anyone qualified to do so can enter as investor in the infrastructure area. There must be a competition policy in place as well as a specialist body to enforce competition so that the presence of competitors acts to discipline investors. To prevent public monopolies being replaced by private monopolies, contracts that have non-exclusivity periods and open entry to segments of service delivery like T & D are desirable. Ways must be found to generate reasonable rates of return for the investor. Management contracts could reduce costs and lessen leakages in production and distribution. Efficiency gains could enable cost recovery through the principle that the ‘consumer pays’. There is enough survey evidence that if user charges are reasonable and affordable, consumers often prefer efficient service delivery to receiving subsidized services that might not even reach them. At least for a transition period, governments should allocate funds to support service delivery to the poor. The private sector and civil society must be empowered to enable speedier implementation of reforms through effective representation and participation of private sector on infrastructure regulatory boards and management institutions. Then again privatepublic interagency committees within government line Ministries might review policy implementation at agreed times. Policy improvements are needed on three fronts: Efficiency issues in the management and reform of the public sector Governance issues of institutional transparency, reliability and accountability Private sector unity of purpose and willingness in public-private partnerships. Efforts to bring about these improvements must precede private entry into infrastructure. 5) To understand the extent of private entry into infrastructure it would be useful to see how many projects were cancelled. For this purpose we define cancellation of projects in one of three ways: those in which the private investor has sold its interest to the public sector; where it has physically abandoned the project; and where the private company has ceased to provide services to all customers or has halted construction on the project. . 6) Contrary to popular understanding the renegotiation or cancellation of private infrastructure projects in developing countries has been quite small. Data from the World Bank (PPI-Private Participation in Infrastructure Project Database) shows that 48 projects were cancelled out of a total of 2500 such projects that reached financial closure between 1990 to 2001. ‘Cancellation’ uses the criterion of whether the private sector continued to be active in a project or not, rather than a strict legal definition of exit from the project. Thus a project that has been abandoned by a private party and later revived by another is regarded as having been cancelled. But if the private party sold its interest to another without a cessation of service or abandonment, it is not a cancellation. On this definition, cancelled projects were only 1.9% with investment commitments of $24.2billion, amounting to 3.2% of the total investment of $754billion. On average, projects were cancelled four and a half years after financial closure. More than a third of cancelled projects were from the Mexican toll road programme and without these, the cancelled projects would be only 1.0% of projects that reached financial closure in this period. The second highest rate of cancellation was of projects in the water sector, followed by electricity projects in distribution and sale to final consumers. The eight cancelled projects in telecom were only 1.2% in number and 0.4% in investment value of projects in that sector. However it must be said that the second half of the 1990’s saw a higher trend of cancelled projects. 7) Does private entry necessarily mean significant improvement? Let us take a look at some experiences of private investment from a study of private electricity distribution utilities in India. Such a study could also help in avoiding structural and contractual inefficiencies in new private entries in infrastructure. Of the six private utilities, CESC had 23.4 % T & D loss in 2000-01 and the trend has been rising over the previous five years. Three other companies, despite serving urban areas and many bulk consumers, also had high losses. While receivables of these companies were at reasonable levels, manpower performance and cost showed wide variation, from an average cost per man month of Rs10200 in Noida to Rs. 5700 in Surat. Employee cost per unit sold varies from Rs0.11 for Tata, a predominantly generating company, to Rs. 0.05 for Noida and Rs. 0.21 for CESC. Significant investments are made in distribution assets with utilities in Bombay investing Rs. 2700million per year in distribution. Capital investment (Rs. per unit sold) by CESC is Rs. 2.78, the highest among distribution licensees in total investments and the current rate of investments. CESC investments are higher than the combined investments for Bombay’s utilities. Yet power quality is worse in Calcutta than in Bombay. Similarly the distribution costs also vary a lot and are particularly high in Calcutta and Bombay. Finally the regulator also has been tardy in Bombay in his readiness to hear tariff revision applications. Thus neither the operations of the present private distribution licensees nor the regulatory arrangements can be a model for the future. They must improve. 8) AES cancelled by walking out of the Orissa electricity distribution company CESCO that they were running. There are many aspects to the story. But they walked out while the other private investor BSES has stayed despite running three circles to AES’s one. This does suggest that AES approached the management of a former public utility in a somewhat aggressive fashion and in the process lost sympathy and support. The Orissa privatization of distribution exercise can be faulted on many grounds. It was based on poor information and it is surprising that BSES and AES entered despite this. The state is the most backward and poverty-stricken, with relatively inefficient governments, tariff uncertainty, high level of losses, high collection risks, lack of paying capacity of many consumers, problems of inherited staff, difficulties of imposing own management and bringing in own employees (as happened to AES who did so and found themselves unable to manage the enterprise), and poor information from the Orissa government. Perhaps private entry should take place only in States where governance is of good quality. 9) The privatization of electricity in Delhi and the proposals for it in Karnataka illustrate the difficulties of private entry into distribution in a developing country. Both governments decided that they could not by themselves revive the sector and that private entry was the only answer. Orissa has put off private investors who need a transition plan with well-defined sharing of risks and responsibilities between government, private investors and consumers. The main elements of such a transition plan are: Multi-year tariffs to enable licensees to plan efficiency improvements and investments and providing for 1. Pass-through of power purchase costs, not merely fuel price adjustments 2. Phased reduction and ultimate elimination of cross-subsidies 3. Tariffs based on standard costs and efficiency parameters and actual technologies in use Licensees commit to a binding multi-year programme to achieve the standard costs and efficiency parameters Need for subsidy during the transition period to bridge the gap between targets and actual1. With the cash deficit being financed by government. 2. From the Regulator, a tariff plan 3. From the Distcom an efficiency improvement plan 4. Subsidy commitment from government 5. Together to ensure break-even for the licensees 6. And a binding agreement among Government, Distcom and Regulator with the Regulator enforcing the commitments. Clearly the government and the SEB need to take a number of fundamental risk-mitigating actions prior to attempting privatization. These include: 1. Close to 100% metering, billing and collections. 2. Disconnection of illegal connections 3. Less one-sided terms with employees 4. Progressive reduction of cross-subsidies 5. Transfer of irrigation load to a separate organization. Private entry cannot take place without considerable prior hard and difficult decisions being implemented. 10) The essential problems of the Enron-Dhabhol project were its extremely high and apparently heavily padded capital costs, the suspicions about the backhanders paid on the project, the high levels of public distrust and the inability of consumers to pay the resultant tariffs. The Godbole Report came to some conclusions. Meanwhile the plant is still lying shut. Enron has been thoroughly discredited. Demand growth has been much slower in Maharashtra. The resumption of the project with the same foreign parties as before is very unlikely. It may restart under a state-owned enterprise. 11) Reasons for Cancellation of private projects in Electricity: In developing countries, electricity has become a right that many expect to be cheap and easily available. Dominance of government ownership has led to overstaffing, gross inefficiencies, tolerance of theft and collusion in theft, poor commercial and accounting practices, poor investment in maintenance and modernization, and rising deficits. Distribution and supply are the worst affected. Private investors are reluctant to take over hitherto state-run distribution unless they get guarantees on safeguards against risks as well as for adequate return. The governments are unwilling and unable to take the actions required to clean up the system in order to make the investment attractive for private investors. 12) Coimbatore By-pass and Bridge: This is an example where the role of government in a public-private partnership was questionable. An additional bridge to make the old two-lane into four-lane and a 27.77 km bypass were to be built on a BOT basis. The cost was to be recovered through tolls on both bypass and bridge. The contractors were allowed to charge tolls for twenty years on the bridge and for thirty on the bypass. While traffic risk was with the contractors the risk due to non-payment of tolls was with the government. Multiple users (state and private buses, taxis, trucks) did not want to pay for each trip and others did not want to pay for each trip when there had been no toll on the old bridge. The contractors were agreeable to concessional tolls for state and private buses with the financial loss to be made up by government. Police support to collect tolls was ineffective. After four years the contractors had lost Rs. 126 million. The usage of the bridge is heavy and has been a great convenience to users but there was unwillingness to pay tolls. Only one bidder, lack of preparation of public opinion, weak government commitment was some reasons for the unhappiness of all parties. 13) Mini Buses in Tamil Nadu was to supplement state and private bus transport in un-served rural areas. The project design was adapted to suit the demands of operators to allow some overlap with served areas. The bus size, design, distance traversed, number of trips, tariffs, etc were specified. While the public is happy the operators are not making sufficient profit. Partly this is due to competition. Minibus owners overcrowd the buses to make up and because the distances are limited, customers do not protest. Maintenance and fuel costs are high in relation to tariffs because of the poor quality of roads while inadequate fares depress the profitability. 14) Privatizing transport in Britain: This was an initiative of the Thatcher and Major governments and appears to have led to all round dissatisfaction, with poor timeliness, deterioration in safety, and poor overall performance. It raises questions about any wholesale privatization of public transport. 15) Reasons for Cancellation of Private Projects in Transport: The inability of governments to give the support that they had committed to the project-for example, in collecting tolls-is an important reason. The forecasted number of users is poorly estimated, consequent lower use of the tolled facilities, leading to revenue shortfalls. Users had alternative toll free facilities that they could use. In some cases tolls were imposed on the improved facilities when there were none charged on the earlier unimproved one. The tolls were set too high and did not make allowance for frequent and multiple users. Governments by accepting traffic risks made the private investor lazy. Investors did not do their own homework independently to check the traffic forecasts. Governments also failed to build public opinion in favour of such projects and the tolls that would have to be paid. 16) The Project for Water-supply & Sewerage in Pune suffered from similar deficiencies and was cancelled. Pune had high levels of unaccounted water, intermittent supply, low pressure, limited sewage treatment, rising river pollution and need to extend services to include an addition 0.8 million inhabitants. The project was to remedy deficiencies and meet future demand. Three different contracts for construction, operations and management, billing and collections management were to be awarded to one contractor. Financing was to be internal and external with Pune Municipal Corporation guaranteeing one-third of the cost from public funds and two-thirds to come from private funds to be arranged by contractor. PMC would create a special fund from octroi collections. Substantial tariff increases were proposed. The project was cancelled because of loss of political support despite being consistent with state policy on public-private partnerships for infrastructure development, close consultations at all government levels, and broad cross-party support. 17) The Tirupur Water supply Project has reached financial closure and is to commence with first phase completion in 2005. It was initiated by local industry in a town that manufactures knitted products for export. Tirupur knitwear accounts for a substantial part of India’s garment exports. There is insufficient water for domestic use and for the industry, and there are pollution and attendant problems. The focus of the project was on plugging the 25% leakage of water. There was local equity participation. It has received wide funding support and is expected to make good progress. 18) Reasons for Cancellation of Water Supply & sewage Projects: This is a sector in which tariffs have been much below costs and collections also have been very poor. Viability of new investments in this sector would depend greatly on plugging leakages of water and collections. Many times this is not enough and tariffs also may have to rise. Some of this might be done in advance of the entry of the private investor. But the capital investments required must be carefully evaluated for their impact on tariffs and the prospect of their being accepted by users. Public and political opinion must be mobilized in advance behind the project. Much prior work by the State is needed before private entry. 19) Telecom projects from which private investors have withdrawn are different from other infrastructure projects. The reasons for withdrawal have to do with high license fees in relation to the revenues, governments trying to impose artificial market structures (as in India), and inadequate demand. 20 and 21) SOME LESSONS: Private entry is not a magic wand that will resolve complex ills in an infrastructure area. It needs an enabling environment if it is to be effective. The owner, government, has to do a number of things in advance. It must create a commercial culture in the area. It must introduce professionalism in management. It must become demanding in terms of work and efficiency. It must provide rewards and punishments for performance. It must develop efficiency standards and try to reach them. To attract the maximum interest the project should be properly packaged; the balance sheet and accounting history should be clear, the assets must be listed and valued, the Detailed Project Proposal must be professionally prepared so that difficult issues are resolved in advance, and the risks must be well defined. The government must define its social objectives, estimate their costs over a specified time frame and provide for them, making the funds available to the enterprise in time. It must give law and order and other support to the contractor to ensure that the contractor gets his dues and is able to function as per the contract. It must enable independent, transparent and objective regulation of licensing, tariffs and other decision-making. It must have transparent procedures for selecting the project investor/s, have clearly laid down procedures for information, reporting, performance, etc. Private entry must not coincide with tariff shocks. Tariff rises will have to be phased and subsidy amounts estimated and provided.