From PLI’s Course Handbook 50th Annual Antitrust Law Institute #18840 4 MONOPOLIZATION R. Hewitt Pate Amanda L. Wait Hunton & Williams LLP These materials are current through February 25, 2009 i Table of Contents I. Sherman Act § 2 Overview ....................................................................................................1 A. Monopolization ..............................................................................................................1 1. Monopoly Power ......................................................................................................1 2. Willful Acquisition and Maintenance of Monopoly Power .............................................................................................................................3 B. Attempted Monopolization ............................................................................................5 1. Predatory or Anticompetitive Conduct ....................................................................5 2. Specific Intent to Monopolize..................................................................................5 3. Dangerous Probability of Achieving Monopoly Power...........................................6 C. Conspiracy to Monopolize .............................................................................................7 1. Combination or Conspiracy .....................................................................................7 2. Overt Act ..................................................................................................................8 3. Specific Intent to Monopolize..................................................................................8 II. Recent Attempts at Clarity and Guidance ..............................................................................8 III. The Monopoly Power Element: Practical Problems and Emerging Issues 12 A. Background ..................................................................................................................12 B. Defining Relevant Markets ..........................................................................................12 1. The Relevant Product or Service Market ...............................................................13 2. The Relevant Geographic Market ..........................................................................15 C. Defining Market Power................................................................................................15 1. Monopoly Power v. Market Power ........................................................................15 2. Presumptions Versus Proof ....................................................................................16 3. The Courts and the Enforcement Agencies ...........................................................16 4. Current Market Share Versus Historic or Future Market Share ............................................................................................................................17 IV. The Exclusionary Conduct Element: Recent Cases and Developing Issues ..........................................................................................................................17 A. Background ..................................................................................................................17 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. Predatory Pricing ...................................................................................................18 Predatory Purchasing/Raising Rivals’ Costs .........................................................20 Refusals to Deal .....................................................................................................22 “Price Squeeze” Claims .........................................................................................24 Exclusive Dealing ..................................................................................................25 ii 6. Bundled Discounts .................................................................................................27 7. Exclusionary Conduct in Standard Setting ............................................................30 8. Exclusionary Conduct in Category Captain Arrangements ...............................................................................................................32 V. Conclusion: More Guidance Is Needed ...............................................................................34 iii I. Sherman Act § 2 Overview Section 2 of the Sherman Act broadly prohibits monopolization, attempted monopolization, and conspiracies to monopolize. Section 2 provides that “[e]very person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony.”1 Unlike Sherman Act Section 1, which requires proof of concerted action, Section 2 prohibits offenses that can be accomplished unilaterally (as well as through concerted action). A. Monopolization To prove a violation of Section 2 for monopolization, a plaintiff must show (1) that the defendant has monopoly power, and (2) that the defendant willfully acquired, maintained, or created that monopoly power through exclusionary conduct.2 1. Monopoly Power The first element of a claim for monopolization under Section 2 of the Sherman Act requires a showing that the defendant has monopoly power. Monopoly power is “the ability to control prices and exclude competition in a given market.”3 To satisfy this element of monopolization, it is sufficient that monopoly power exists; it need not have been exercised.4 A plaintiff can prove the existence of monopoly power through “direct evidence of supracompetitive prices and restricted output” or by inference “from the structure and composition of the relevant market.”5 Market share in the relevant market typically is considered the most important factor in assessing whether monopoly power exists.6 Although no 1 15 U.S.C. § 2 (2004). 2 United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966). 3 Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. at 571. 4 Am. Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781, 811 (1946). 5 Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., 501 F.3d 297 (3d Cir. 2007). 6 United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 56-57 (D.C. Cir. 2001). 1 concrete rules exist, the Second Circuit famously noted that a market share of 90% “is enough to constitute a monopoly” but “it is doubtful whether sixty or sixty-four percent would be enough” and “certainly thirty-three per cent is not.”7 Other courts have said that market power is rare at market shares less than seventy percent,8 that “a share significantly larger than 55%” is required to show monopoly power,9 and that a share of 75-80% is “more than adequate to establish a prima facie case” of monopoly power.10 The Department of Justice’s recently released Report on Section 2 of the Sherman Act suggests that a safe-harbor for firms holding less than 50% of a market is appropriate: “[W]e are aware of no court that has found monopoly power when defendant’s share was less than fifty percent, suggesting instances of monopoly power below such a share, even if theoretically possible, are exceedingly rare in practice.”11 The DOJ would apply a rebuttable presumption that a firm possesses monopoly power if it “has maintained a market share in excess of two-thirds for a significant period and the firm’s market share is unlikely to be eroded in the near future… .”12 Great uncertainty exists for market shares between 50% and 70%.13 Market share, however, “is only a starting point for determining whether monopoly power exists, and the inference of monopoly power does not automatically follow from the 7 United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416, 424 (2d. Cir. 1945); see also Am. Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781, 813-814 (1946) (finding 90% market share sufficient to find monopoly power). 8 Exxon Corp. v. Berwick Bay Real Estate Partners, 748 F.2d 937, 940 (5th Cir. 1984). 9 United States v. Dentsply Int’l, Inc., 399 F.3d 181, 187 (3d Cir. 2005). 10 Id. at 188; see Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., 504 U.S. 451, 481 (1992) (It is generally accepted that a market share in excess of 70% can establish a prima facie finding of monopoly power.). See U.S. DEP’T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT 24 (2008), at www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/reports/236681.pdf [hereinafter DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT]. 11 12 DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at 30. 13 See ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 232 n.39 (6th ed. 2007) (collecting cases) [hereinafter ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS]. 2 possession of a commanding market share.”14 Additional factors considered in ascertaining the existence of monopoly power include the existence of barriers to entry (such as legal license requirements, control of natural resources or supplies, intellectual property rights, exclusivity arrangements, entrenched buyer preferences, and high capital costs), and network effects (which exist when the value of a product or service increases the more others use the same product or service).15 “A firm also lacks market power when its competitors have excess production capacity and can produce more than the market demands at a competitive price.”16 A plaintiff may also prove the existence of monopoly power through direct evidence of anticompetitive effects.17 Showing market power by direct effects does not relieve a plaintiff of the obligation to allege at least the “rough contours of a relevant market.” 18 Plaintiffs showing direct evidence of monopoly power, however, do not need to define the relevant market with the same level of precision as required when alleging monopoly power by showing market share.19 2. Willful Acquisition and Maintenance of Monopoly Power Monopoly power in the relevant market will give rise to Section 2 liability only if that power was willfully acquired or maintained, rather than resulting from “growth or development 14 Smith Wholesale Co. v. Philip Morris USA, Inc., 2007-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 75,620 (6th Cir. Feb. 27, 2007) (quoting Am. Council of Certified Podiatric Physicians & Surgeons v. Am. Bd. of Podiatric Surgery, Inc., 185 F.3d 606, 623 (6th Cir. 1999)). Cf. GSI Group v. Sukup Mfg. Co., 2007-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 75,880 (C.D. Ill. July 27, 2007) (noting “market share is not always sufficient to establish market power at summary judgment”). 15 ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS, supra note 14, at 233-38. 16 Smith Wholesale Co., 2007-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 75,620 (citing Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1441 (9th Cir. 1995)). 17 See In re Compensation of Managerial, Professional & Technical Employees Antitrust Litigation, 2008 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 63,633, at *6 (D.N.J. Aug. 20, 2008) (“If a plaintiff can show that a defendant’s conduct exerted an actual adverse effect on competition, this is a strong indicator of market power.”) (quoting Todd v. Exxon, 275 F.3d 191, 206 (2d Cir. 2001)). 18 Id. at *24. 19 Id. at *26. 3 as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.”20 Thus, a monopolist that simply competes aggressively and pursues legitimate business objectives will not be subject to Section 2 liability.21 The antitrust laws protect competition, not competitors. Therefore, “[c]onduct that merely harms competitors … while not harming the competitive process itself, is not anticompetitive.”22 To satisfy this element of a successful claim for monopolization under Section 2, the acquisition or maintenance of monopoly power must be the result of “competition on some basis other than the merits.”23 “Any conduct by the defendant that secures market share by means other than the competitive merits of the defendant’s product may qualify as anticompetitive.”24 If the conduct at issue is economically irrational but for an adverse impact on competition, it can give rise to liability.25 Additionally, conduct that contributes to monopoly power that also violates non-antitrust laws, such as business torts and violations of regulatory requirements, has given rise to Section 2 liability.26 Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. at 570-71; see Rambus Inc. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n, 522 F.3d 456, 463 (D.C. Cir. 2008) (“It is settled law that the mere existence of a monopoly does not violate the Sherman Act.”) . 20 21 See, e.g., Endsley v. City of Chicago, 230 F.3d 276, 283-84 (7th Cir. 2000). 22 Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., 501 F.3d 297, 308 (3d. Cir. 2007). Id. at 308 (citing Verizon Commcn’s Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004)); see also Cascade Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth, 502 F.3d 895, 904 (9th Cir. 2007) (“Anticompetitive conduct is behavior that tends to impair the opportunities of rivals and either does not further competition on the merits or does so in an unnecessarily restrictive way.”). 23 Univac Dental Co. v. Dentsply Int’l, 2008 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 46,910, at *16 (M.D. Pa. June 17, 2008). 24 25 See, e.g., Advanced Health-Care Servs. v. Radford Cmty. Hosp., 910 F.2d 139, 148 (4th Cir. 1990) (“[I]f a plaintiff shows that a defendant has harmed consumers and competition by making a short-term sacrifice in order to further its exclusive, anti-competitive objectives, it has shown predation by that defendant.”). 26 ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS, supra note 14, at 298-300. 4 With respect to the role of the monopolist’s intent, there is general agreement that a monopolist’s intent to win the competitive struggle is not damning. Rather, the focus must be on the propriety of the monopolist’s conduct, with intent simply informing the analysis of that conduct.27 Thus, proffered business justifications are an important factor in determining whether conduct reaches the level of “willful acquisition or maintenance of monopoly power.”28 B. Attempted Monopolization Similarly, a successful claim for attempted monopolization requires proof that the defendant (1) has engaged in predatory or anticompetitive conduct; with (2) a specific intent to monopolize; and (3) a dangerous probability of achieving monopoly power.29 1. Predatory or Anticompetitive Conduct The same conduct required to establish liability of a monopolization claim is required to establish a claim for attempted monopolization. Thus, the same analysis used to distinguish legitimate business behavior from anticompetitive behavior in monopolization cases is used to determine whether conduct constitutes an illegal attempt to monopolize.30 2. Specific Intent to Monopolize The second element required for a successful claim of attempted monopolization under Section 2 is that the defendant had a “specific intent to destroy competition or build monopoly.”31 “[S]pecific intent refers not to the defendant’s general intent to do a particular act, 27 See Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp., 207 F.3d 1039 (8th Cir. 2000). 28 Id. at 1062. 29 Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 456 (1993). 30 Spectrum Sports, 506 U.S. at 459-58; see Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., 501 F.3d 297, 317 (3d Cir. 2007); Kinderstart.com LLC v. Google, Inc., 2007-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 75,643. 31 Times-Picayune Publ’g Co. v. United States, 345 U.S. 594, 626 (1953). 5 but to an overall anticompetitive intent expressed through its actions to destroy competition or build monopoly.”32 An intent to drive a competitor out of business through legitimate means is not sufficient to show a “specific intent to monopolize.”33 Specific intent may be proven by direct evidence, or it can be inferred from evidence of anticompetitive acts.34 For example, in Aspen Skiing, the Supreme Court noted that evidence of irrational business conduct may be indirect evidence of a specific intent to monopolize.35 3. Dangerous Probability of Achieving Monopoly Power In assessing whether a defendant has a dangerous probability of achieving monopoly power, courts typically examine the same factors they would in assessing whether a defendant possesses market power, that is, market share and other market factors.36 A plaintiff must allege facts sufficient to show that the defendant has market power that, if the defendant’s alleged unlawful conduct remains unchecked, will approach monopoly power.37 32 Schoenbaum v. E.I. DuPont de Nemours & Co., 517 F. Supp. 2d 1125 (E.D. Mo. 2007) (citing Gen. Indus. Corp. v. Hartz Mountain Corp., 810 F.2d 795, 802 (8th Cir. 1987)); see Babyage.com, Inc. v. Toys “R” Us, Inc., 558 F. Supp. 2d 575, 586 (E.D. Pa. 2008) (finding plaintiffs had sufficiently alleged specific intent to monopolize by alleging that defendant sought minimum resale price maintenance agreements with the goal of acquiring a monopoly share in each of the relevant markets); Kinderstart.com LLC, 2007-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 75,643 (finding that the plaintiff did not sufficiently allege a specific intent to monopolize when the plaintiff described the anticompetitive conduct in the complaint but did “not allege that Google engaged in this activity with an intent to gain a monopoly”). 33 Abcor Corp. v. AM Int’l, Inc., 916 F.2d 924, 927 (4th Cir. 1990). 34 M&M Med. Supplies & Serv., Inc. v. Pleasant Valley Hosp., 981 F.2d 160, 166 (4th Cir. 1992); Schoenbaum, 517 F. Supp. 2d at 1146. 35 Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 608 n.39 (1985). 36 See, e.g., Kelco Disposal v. Browning-Ferris Indus., 845 F.2d 404, 409 (2d Cir. 1988) (explaining market share over 55%, along with other market characteristics, can establish dangerous probability of success); see also Rescue Phone, Inc. v. Enforcement Tech. Group, Inc., 2007-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 75,768 (E.D. Va. 2007) (“Facts relevant to a determination of ‘a dangerous probability of success’ in monopolizing the market include market share, ease of entry into the market, and unjustified exclusionary conduct.”). 37 DSM Desotech Inc. v. 3D Sys. Corp., 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 5980, at *21 (N.D. Ill. Jan. 26, 2009). 6 Courts specifically have considered the existence of barriers to entry in determining whether the plaintiff has a “dangerous probability” of achieving monopoly power.38 Less evidence is required to prove a “dangerous probability of achieving monopoly power,” than to prove that the defendant has monopoly power.39 A plaintiff, however, must allege something more than just “labels and conclusions.”40 As one district court recently explained: “Although Plaintiff need not necessarily quantify [the defendant’s] market share with precision, Plaintiff must assert some facts in support of its assertions of market power that suggest those assertions are plausible.”41 C. Conspiracy to Monopolize A plaintiff may also challenge conspiracy to monopolize under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. A successful claim for conspiracy to monopolize requires: (1) the existence of a combination or conspiracy; (2) an overt act in furtherance of the conspiracy; and (3) specific intent to monopolize.42 1. Combination or Conspiracy The first element of a claim for conspiracy to monopolize requires proof of a “combination or conspiracy,” as evidenced by an agreement to commit the underlying offense of monopolization. Such an agreement can be established by direct or indirect proof.43 As in See Babyage.com, Inc. v. Toys “R” Us, Inc., 558 F. Supp. 2d 575, 586 (E.D. Pa. 2008) (finding that the plaintiffs sufficiently had alleged the “dangerous probability” element by alleging “significant barriers to entry in the form of stringent industry regulation and high startup cost” in the relevant markets). 38 39 See Tops Mkts., Inc. v. Quality Mkts., Inc., 142 F.3d 90, 100-01 (2d Cir. 1998) (finding that the same evidence supports an attempt to monopolize, but not a monopolization claim). 40 See Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, at 555 (2007). 41 Korea Kumho Petrochemical v. Flexsys Am. LP, 2008 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 68,559 (Mar. 11, 2008). 42 United States v. Yellow Cab Co., 332 U.S. 218, 225 (1947). 43 Am. Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781, 809 (1946). 7 Section 1 cases, the question of whether a combination or conspiracy exists is typically a factual question.44 Unlike the other possible offenses under Section 2—monopolization and attempted monopolization—which can be committed by a single actor acting unilaterally, an agreement to conspire to monopolize necessarily requires two or more distinct entities. Pursuant to the doctrine enunciated in Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp.,45 a parent and its wholly owned subsidiary constitute a single economic entity that is incapable of conspiring with itself. The Copperweld doctrine is applicable to conspiracy to monopolize claims. A plaintiff challenging conduct as an anticompetitive conspiracy to monopolize must allege distinct entities that are legally capable of conspiring with each other. 2. Overt Act While an overt act that is itself a violation of the antitrust laws will satisfy this element, any overt act in furtherance of the conspiracy will suffice.46 3. Specific Intent to Monopolize As in a claim for attempted monopolization, specific intent may be proven by direct evidence or it can be inferred from evidence of anticompetitive acts.47 II. Recent Attempts at Clarity and Guidance The application of Section 2 of the Sherman Act to unilateral conduct currently is quite confused. One antitrust scholar in the United States has written that exclusionary conduct doctrine “uses a barrage of conclusory labels to cover for a lack of any well-defined criteria for sorting out desirable from undesirable conduct that tends to exclude rivals.”48 Another charges that “[a] number of contemporary cases on exclusionary practices tend to be noncommittal if not 44 Seagood Trading Corp. v. Jerrico, Inc., 924 F.2d 1555, 1573-75 (11th Cir. 1991). 45 467 U.S. 752, 776 (1984). 46 See Am. Tobacco Co., 328 U.S. at 809. 47 Id. 48 Einer Elhauge, Defining Better Monopolization Standards, 56 STAN. L. REV. 253, 342 (2003). 8 obfuscatory” in their usage of terms such as “anticompetitive.”49 Commentators on the other side of the Atlantic have been similarly unsparing.50 Many commentators have called for increased clarity and improvement of Section 2 legal standards.51 In recent years, the Department of Justice has attempted to distill from the Supreme Court’s Section 2 case law an objective, transparent, and economically based framework for assessing single-firm conduct.52 The “no economic sense” test advocated by the DOJ in its Amicus brief in Trinko is consistent with the case law as it has developed up to this point.53 On September 8, 2008, the Antitrust Division released a report entitled “Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act.”54 This report originated in an eleven-month series of hearings on Section 2 of the Sherman Act conducted jointly by the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission. The hearings began on June 20, 2006, and were intended to “encompass a thorough examination of 49 Eleanor Fox, What is Harm to Competition? Exclusionary Practices and Anticompetitive Effect, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 371, 383 (2002). 50 See, e.g., John Vickers, Abuse of Market Power, Speech to the 31st Conference of the European Ass’n for Research in Industrial Economics, Berlin (Sept. 3, 2004), available at http://www.oft.gov,uk/NR/rdonlyres/948B9FAF-B83C-49F5-B0FAB25214DE6199/0/spe0304.pdf; see also Competition Committee, Directorate for Financial and Enterprise Affairs, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Competition on the Merits – Background Note, DAF/COMP(2005) 3 n.4 (May 9, 2005) (collecting sources). See REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS, ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM’N, at recommendation 15 (2007), available at www.amc.gov. 51 52 See Br. for the United States and the Fed. Trade Comm. as Amici Curiae Supporting Petitioner 17, Verizon Commcn’s, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f201000/ 201048.pdf (proffering an approach which would require a court to examine whether, on the basis of information available to a firm at the time of the challenged conduct, the challenged conduct would have made economic sense even if it did not reduce or eliminate competition). 53 See id. at 16 (citing Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 608, 610-11 (1985); General Indus. Corp. v. Hartz Mountain Corp., 810 F.2d 795, 803 (8th Cir. 1987); Stearns Airport Equip. Co. v. FMC Corp., 170 F.3d 518, 523-524 & n.3 (5th Cir. 1999); Advanced Health-Care Servs. v. Radford Cmty. Hosp., 910 F.2d 139, 148 (4th Cir. 1990)). 54 DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12. 9 single-firm conduct under the antitrust laws.”55 Panelists at the hearings considered a broad range of issues relating to Section 2 of the Sherman Act, including: bundled loyalty discounts and market share discounts; product tying and bundling; exclusive dealing; predatory pricing; refusals to deal; product design; and misleading or deceptive statements or conduct. For several types of conduct that may implicate Section 2, the DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT outlined specific tests and safe harbors. These specific tests and safe harbors are discussed in detail below. When one of those specific tests does not apply, however, the Division took a slightly different analytical direction from its prior advocacy of the “no economic sense” test and advocated a “disproportionality” test as a general enforcement analytical tool. Although the Division outlined conduct-specific tests and safe harbors, “in general, the Department believes that, when a conduct-specific test is not applicable, the disproportionality test is likely the most appropriate test identified to date for evaluating conduct under section 2.”56 The disproportionality test finds conduct anticompetitive if the anticompetitive harm substantially outweighs the procompetitive benefits. The Division has not, however, entirely abandoned the “no economic sense” test. One of the Division representatives involved in drafting the Report noted that, for ex ante counseling, the “no economic sense” test is a useful tool, but it has enforcement drawbacks.57 Obtaining clarity in the law of Section 2 was a goal of both the Division and Federal Trade Commission for these hearings.58 Ultimately, however, such clarity did not result. The Division’s Report was not joined by the Federal Trade Commission. In fact, the same day the Division’s Report issued, three of four current FTC Commissioners issued a statement 55 Overview of the Hearings, available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/hearings/single_ firm/sfchearing.htm#overview. 56 DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at 46. James J. O’Connell, Deputy Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, Dep’t of Justice, Analysis of DOJ’s Section 2 Report (Dec. 11, 2008). 57 58 See DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at 1 (noting that the debate surrounding Section 2 was the two agencies’ motivation for embarking on the lengthy series of hearings). 10 repudiating certain elements of the DOJ’s report.59 Specifically, Commissioners Harbour, Leibowitz, and Rosch proclaimed that the Report, “if adopted by the courts, would be a blueprint for radically weakened enforcement of Section 2 of the Sherman Act.”60 The three Commissioners particularly were agitated by the Division’s advocacy of the “disproportionality” test. They were concerned that the test places a thumb on the scale in favor of the defendant and thereby places a nail in the coffin of Section 2.61 The current lack of clarity in the law of Section 2 of the Sherman Act is further complicated by the new Obama Administration. President Obama has nominated former FTC Commissioner Christine Varney as Assistant Attorney General for the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice. As of this writing her nomination has not been confirmed. However, what is clear, is that new leadership will take over the reigns of the Antitrust Division and uncertainty exists regarding how this new leadership will apply the 2008 Report released under the Bush Administration. Other jurisdictions also continue to struggle with the application of competition laws to unilateral conduct. For example, the European Commission recently released a Guidance Paper on its enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to abusive exclusionary conduct by dominant firms.62 As with the DOJ Report, the EC Guidance is also the result of extensive public consultation. The EC received over one hundred comments which were See Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm’n, FTC Commissioners React to Department of Justice Report, “Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act” (Sept. 8, 2008), at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2008/09/section2.shtm. 59 60 Press Release, Statement of Commissioners Harbour, Leibowitz and Rosch on the Issuance of the Section 2 Report by the Department of Justice (Sept. 8, 2008), at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2008/09/080908section2stmt.pdf. Id. (“At almost every turn, the Department would place a thumb on the scales in favor of firms with monopoly or near-monopoly power and against other equally significant stakeholders.”). 61 Comm’n of European Communities, Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings, Feb. 9, 2009, available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/art82/index.html. 62 11 discussed at public hearings and open debates starting in 2006.63 The analytical approach employed in the EC Guidance arguably reflects a move towards the approach to unilateral conduct followed by the United States and other jurisdictions. The Guidance, however, may provide only limited insight into the EC’s enforcement approach. The insights offered by the Guidance do not extend much beyond that which was already available in the case law. On a positive note, in areas in which a settled test for the lawfulness of conduct under Section 2 of the Sherman Act does not exist, antitrust counselors can make use of the “no economic sense” test to guide businesses away from the conduct that is most likely to lead to Section 2 liability. Passing the “no economic sense” test may not guarantee protection against liability under Section 2, but failing it almost certainly will give rise to it. Recent case law addressing specific elements and types of Section 2 offences are discussed below in detail. III. The Monopoly Power Element: Practical Problems and Emerging Issues A. Background Determining whether a firm has monopoly power for purposes of a Section 2 case is a critical and complicated endeavor. The practitioner or court must define the relevant product market(s), define the relevant geographic market(s), calculate the various competitors’ market shares in those markets, and analyze the general structure of the market for factors such as barriers to entry and capacity constraints. Then, the practitioner or court must apply those factors to the case law on monopoly power, which is clear at the extremes but murky in the middle. B. Defining Relevant Markets Defining the relevant market is an issue of central importance in antitrust law, including Section 2 of the Sherman Act. How the relevant market is defined often determines whether the activity at issue is deemed to violate the antitrust laws. In defining the relevant market, the courts and enforcement agencies have looked to a number of factors—primarily related to the product and geographic markets. It is often difficult to predict where a court will draw the 63 See Background, http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/art82/index.html. 12 boundary of a market between the extremes of perfect and imperfect substitutes, leading to uncertainty and increased transaction costs. The Supreme Court has recognized this problem: For every product, substitutes exist. But a relevant market cannot meaningfully encompass that infinite range. The circle must be drawn narrowly to exclude any other product to which, within reasonable variations in price, only a limited number of buyers will turn; in technical terms, products whose “cross elasticities of demand” are small.64 While the Supreme Court has set forth the standard, there obviously exists a great distance between that standard and the ultimate conclusion regarding market definition reached by a court. In that gap exists a variety of practical problems related to defining relevant markets. The DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT suggests that “continued consideration and study is warranted regarding how to appropriately determine relevant markets” for purposes of Section 2.65 1. The Relevant Product or Service Market a. Reasonable Interchangeability of Use If products are reasonably interchangeable in use, then they are considered to be within the same market.66 This “reasonable interchangeability” is determined from the perspective of the end consumer.67 A market that is not defined in terms of the reasonable interchangeability of use for the alleged products is legally insufficient.68 In determining whether a consumer considers products reasonably interchangeable, courts may consider, among other factors: customer views regarding interchangeability, price, cross-elasticity of demand, the perception in the industry or public opinion regarding the scope of the market, 64 Times-Picayune Publ’g Co. v. United States, 345 U.S. 594, 612 n.31 (1953). 65 DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at 27. 66 See, e.g., Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325-326 (1962); United States v. E.I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 395-400 (1956). 67 See Truck-Rail Handling, Inc. v. Burlington N. & Santa Fe Ry. Co., 2007-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 75,788 (9th Cir. July 13, 2007). 68 See Campfield v. State Farm Mutual Auto. Ins. Co., 532 F.3d 1111, 1118 (10th Cir. 2008). 13 the firm’s own views regarding its competitors, differentiation in the consumer market, and any differences in the means of bringing the goods to market. b. Submarkets Submarkets may also exist within broad product market categories. The term “submarket” is somewhat of a misnomer. A plaintiff alleging a product “submarket” must still be able to show that the alleged “submarket” is an economically distinct relevant market. 69 The question whether a submarket exists interjects significant uncertainty into the analysis. As explained by the Court in Brown Shoe: The boundaries of . . . a submarket may be determined by examining such practical indicia as industry or public recognition of the submarket as a separate economic entity, the product’s peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices, sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors.70 The factors listed by the Court in Brown Shoe are many of the same factors used to define a market initially. This overlap has lead many courts and commentators to criticize use of the term “submarket.”71 Thus, even when a market has been defined in favorable terms, the practitioner must still be on the look out for the possibility that the court will define, on unfavorable terms, a submarket of that market. c. The Battle of the Experts Due to its complex nature, the issue of market definition often devolves into a battle of economic and industry experts. When one side cannot clearly win that battle, then summary judgment will likely be denied.72 69 See, e.g., Portney v. Ciba Vision Corp., 2008 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 106,551, at *15 (June 17, 2008). 70 Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325. See, e.g., Allen-Myland, Inc. v. IBM, 33 F.3d 194, 208 n.16 (3d Cir. 1994) (“The use of the term ‘submarket’ is somewhat confusing, and tends to obscure the true inquiry.”); Satellite Television & Associated Res., Inc. v. Cont’l Cablevision of Va., Inc., 714 F.2d 351, 355 n.5 (4th Cir. 1983) (“The use of the term ‘submarket’ is to be avoided; it adds only confusion to an already imprecise and complex endeavor.”). 71 14 2. The Relevant Geographic Market The Supreme Court has defined the relevant geographic market as the “area of effective competition … in which the seller operates, and to which the purchaser can practicably turn for supplies.”73 Courts consider a variety of factors in determining the bounds of a geographic market, including: Sales patterns, Transportation costs, and Geopolitical barriers to trade. As is evident from this list of factors often considered, a geographic market is often malleable and may change significantly over short periods of time. C. Defining Market Power 1. Monopoly Power v. Market Power The more typical question that arises in Section 2 litigation is whether a firm possesses monopoly power. As defined by the courts, monopoly power is “the power to control market prices or exclude competition.”74 The Supreme Court has stated that “[m]onopoly power under § 72 See, e.g., Spirit Airlines, Inc. v. Northwest Airlines, Inc., 431 F.3d 917, 945 (6th Cir. 2005) (“We conclude that this ‘intellectual disagreement’ among the parties’ experts creates material factual disputes on the relevant market and the appropriate measure of costs for the service at issue so as to preclude an award of summary judgment.”). 73 Tampa Elec. Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320, 327 (1961) (emphasis omitted); see Portney v. Ciba Vision Corp., 2008 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 106,551, at *15 (June 17, 2008) (noting that a relevant geographic market is not necessarily defined by the geographic area in which a seller operates if buyers could not practically turn to certain geographic areas in which the seller operates for supplies). 74 United States v. E.I. Du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 294, 391 (1962); see Hypertherm, Inc. v. Am. Torch Tip Co., 2007 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 67,579, at *19-20 (Sept. 11, 2007) (“[M]arket power consists of having sufficient economic muscle to permit [the monopolist] to raise prices well in excess of competitive levels without inducing customers to turn elsewhere.”) (quoting SMS Sys. Maint. Servs., Inc. v. Digital Equip. Corp., 188 F.3d 11, 16 (1st Cir. 1999). 15 2 requires . . . something greater than market power under § 1,”75 but there is no generally accepted description of where market power ends and monopoly power begins. The overlap between the definitions of monopoly power and market power has led commentators to criticize the current doctrine: The Court defines “monopoly power” as “the power to control prices or exclude competition.” This definition raises a problem because the standard economic definition of any “market power” is a power to raise prices over the competitive level. Given this, doesn’t all market power necessarily give a defendant “control” over its prices and thus make it a monopolist?76 2. Presumptions Versus Proof In Illinois Tool Works, Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., the Supreme Court reversed the Federal Circuit’s conclusion that a patentee should be presumed to possess market power in the market for its patented product or process.77 The Supreme Court emphasized the possible procompetitive bases for tying arrangements as reasons for eliminating a presumption of market power.78 Independent Ink may reflect a shift in the Court away from presumptions relating to market power. The Court expressed its unwillingness to allow a market to be defined by the scope of a legal right. Instead, the Court seemed more intent upon requiring proof of the actual contours of the market as defined by consumers. 3. The Courts and the Enforcement Agencies Courts have at times used a variety of verbal formulations in an attempt to describe the nature of market power.79 75 Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., 504 U.S. 451, 481 (1992). 76 Einer Elhauge, Defining Better Monopolization Standards, 56 STAN. L. REV. 253, 25758 (2003) (footnotes omitted). 77 126 S.Ct. 1281 (2006). 78 See, e.g., id. at 1291-93. See, e.g., Eastman Kodak Co., 504 U.S. at 464 (“Market power is the power ‘to force a purchaser to do something that he would not do in a competitive market.’ It has been described as ‘the ability of a single seller to raise price and restrict output.’”) (quoting Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 4 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 14 (1984); Fortner Enters., Inc. v. U.S. Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 503 (1969)). 79 16 The Horizontal Merger Guidelines, issued jointly by the Federal Trade Commission and the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice define market power as “the ability profitably to maintain prices above competitive levels for a significant period of time.”80 4. Current Market Share Versus Historic or Future Market Share Another issue that arises in the determination of monopoly power is whether courts should examine market power as a snapshot, or assess market power over some period of time. The enforcement agencies have explained that: The Agency normally will calculate market shares for all firms (or plants) identified as market participants in Section 1.3 based on the total sales or capacity currently devoted to the relevant market together with that which likely would be devoted to the relevant market in response to a 'small but significant and nontransitory' price increase.81 Section 1.3 clarifies that, “[t]hese supply responses must be likely to occur within one year and without the expenditure of significant sunk costs of entry and exit… .”82 Applying this “small but significant and nontransitory price” (“SSNIP”) increase analysis in the Section 2 context after the exercise of monopoly power could result in markets being defined too broadly.83 IV. The Exclusionary Conduct Element: Recent Cases and Developing Issues A. Background The canonical formulation of the exclusionary conduct element of monopolization is in United States v. Grinnell Corp.84 In Grinnell, the Supreme Court described exclusionary conduct as “the willful acquisition or maintenance of [monopoly] power as distinguished from U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm’n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 0.1 (1997) [hereinafter Horizontal Merger Guidelines]; see also U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm’n, Commentary on the Horizontal Merger Guidelines 1 (March 2006). 80 81 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, supra note 81, § 1.41. 82 Id. § 1.32. See DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at 26 (explaining the “Cellophane 83 Fallacy”). 84 384 U.S. 563 (1966). 17 growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.”85 Unfortunately for firms trying to conduct their business without running afoul of Section 2, the Grinnell formulation provides very little guidance. Over three decades after Grinnell, a court surveying the jurisprudential landscape could accurately observe that “[a]nticompetitive conduct can come in too many different forms, and is too dependent on context, for any court or commentator to have enumerated all the varieties.”86 Notwithstanding the vague Grinnell standard and the wide variety of conduct that has been found to be exclusionary, courts have provided more intelligible guidance (at least marginally) with respect to certain categories of allegedly exclusionary conduct. A review of governing law and recent developments in the most prominent of these categories follows. B. Recent Cases 1. Predatory Pricing One type of exclusionary conduct for which the Supreme Court has been able to provide more concrete guidance is predatory pricing.87 In addition to the other elements of its claim, a plaintiff alleging predatory pricing must prove (1) pricing below an appropriate measure of costs, and (2) the possibility of recoupment or actual recoupment.88 This is a high standard, intended to guard against false-positives that could deter legitimate price-cutting that benefits consumers.89 There is a long-standing split in the case law on what constitutes the appropriate measure of cost in the price-cost comparison element of predatory pricing.90 The starting point for every cost discussion is the Areeda-Turner test: (1) a price at or above the defendant’s average variable 85 Id. at 570-71. 86 Caribbean Broad. Sys. Ltd. v. Cable & Wireless PLC, 148 F.3d 1080, 1087 (D.C. Cir. 87 See Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993). 88 Id. at 222. 89 Id. at 222-23. 90 See, e.g., McGahee v. N. Propane Gas Co., 858 F.2d 1487, 1501-04 (11th Cir. 1988). 1998). 18 cost is conclusively deemed lawful, and (2) a price below the defendant’s average variable cost is conclusively deemed unlawful.91 The courts generally have not adopted this test, but instead have some adopted some variation.92 The Supreme Court has adopted the parties’ agreement to use average variable cost as the appropriate measure of cost in one case, but declined to fully adopt it as the correct measure in all cases.93 This leaves the question of the appropriate measure of costs to use in predatory pricing cases unsettled. In Spirit Airlines, Inc. v. Northwest Airlines, Inc., the Sixth Circuit reversed a grant of summary judgment on a predatory pricing claim using average variable costs as the appropriate measure under the Brooke Group test.94 Spirit claimed that Northwest had driven it out of the market through a combination of predatory pricing and expansion of capacity on the routes for which it priced below costs. The Sixth Circuit rejected the district court’s claim that Spirit’s expert’s opinion on the price-cost comparison made “no economic sense,” and instead held a jury could reasonably find that the expert’s economic model and calculations demonstrated marginal or average variable costs fell below price. 95 The court likewise held that a jury reasonably could find, based on Spirit’s expert’s analysis, that Northwest recovered its losses within months of Spirit’s exit from the market.96 Spirit Airlines, therefore, demonstrates 91 See Philip Areeda & Donald Turner, Predatory Pricing and Related Practices Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 88 HARV. L. REV. 697, 733 (1975). 92 See, e.g., Spirit Airlines, Inc. v. Northwest Airlines, Inc., 431 F.3d 917, 938 (6th Cir. 2005) (“[I]f the plaintiff proves that the defendant's prices were below average variable cost, the plaintiff has established a prima facie case of predatory pricing and the burden shifts to the defendant to prove that the prices were justified without regard to any anticipated destructive effect they may have on competitors.” (internal quotation marks and citations omitted)); McGahee, 858 F.2d at 1503 (explaining that if price is above average total cost, there is no predation; if price is below average total cost and above short run marginal cost, there is circumstantial evidence of predation; if price is below short run marginal cost, there is a presumption of predation). 93 See Brooke Group, 509 U.S. at 222 n.1. 94 431 F.3d 917 (6th Cir. 2005). 95 Id. at 945. 96 Id. at 947-48. 19 the critical nature of expert testimony in a predatory pricing case. The grant and reverse of summary judgment turned largely, if not solely, on the credibility of Spirit’s experts. It also demonstrates that predatory pricing claims can make it past summary judgment, albeit rarely. The DOJ, however, did not adopt the “average variable cost” measure used in Spirit Airlines in its Section 2 Report. The Report explained that “a major shortcoming of average variable cost is that it measures the average cost of the entire output, not just of the incremental output that is the focus of the predation claim.”97 The DOJ advocated “average avoidable cost” as the correct measure of cost.98 The Report defines “average avoidable cost” as including “all costs, including both variable costs and product-specific fixed costs, that could have been avoided by not engaging in the predatory strategy.”99 The calculation “omits all fixed costs that were already sunk before the time of the predation… .”100 A successful predatory pricing claim also requires a showing of a “dangerous probability” that the defendant will recoup its below-cost losses. The DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT indicates that the Division would be willing, in appropriate cases, to consider both in- and out-ofmarket effects in assessing recoupment.101 2. Predatory Purchasing/Raising Rivals’ Costs In 2007, the Supreme Court held in Weyerhaeuser v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co. that the test applied to predatory pricing claims in Brooke Group also applies to predatory bidding claims.102 Plaintiff Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co. alleged that Weyerhaeuser attempted to monopolize the finished alder lumber market by overbidding on inputs and raising Ross-Simmons’ costs. The jury found for Ross-Simmons and awarded a verdict that was trebled 97 DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at 63. 98 See id. at 67. 99 Id. at 64. 100 Id. 101 Id. at 69. 102 549 U.S. 312, 314 (2007). 20 to approximately $79 million. The Ninth Circuit affirmed on appeal.103 The Court of Appeals rejected Weyerhaeuser’s principal argument: that Brooke Group’s high standards for liability on the sell-side of the market should also apply on the buy-side. The court reasoned that “an important factor distinguishes predatory bidding cases from predatory pricing cases: benefit to consumers and stimulation of competition do not necessarily result from predatory bidding the way they do from predatory pricing.”104 The Ninth Circuit held that it was enough that the defendants purchased more inputs than needed and paid a higher price for the inputs than necessary to establish the anticompetitive conduct element.105 The Supreme Court unanimously reversed, holding that the Brooke Group test for predatory pricing claims also applies to predatory bidding claims.106 The Court explained that “the general theoretical similarities of monopoly and monopsony combined with the theoretical and practical similarities of predatory pricing and predatory bidding convince us that our twopronged Brooke Group test should apply to predatory-bidding claims.”107 The “first prong of Brooke Group’s test requires little adaptation for the predatory-bidding context. A plaintiff must prove that the alleged predatory bidding led to below-cost pricing of the predator's outputs.”108 Because of the risk of “chilling procompetitive behavior with too lax a liability standard,” “only higher bidding that leads to below-cost pricing in the relevant output market will suffice as a basis for liability for predatory bidding.”109 With regard to the second prong of the Brooke Group test, a “predatory-bidding plaintiff also must prove that the defendant has a dangerous 103 Confederated Tribes of Siletz Indians of Ore. v. Weyerhaeuser Co., 411 F.3d 1030, 1036 (9th Cir. 2005), cert. granted sub nom., Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., Inc., 549 U.S. 312 (2007). 104 411 F.3d at 1037. 105 Id. at 1037 n.8. 106 Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., Inc., 549 U.S. 312, 314 107 Id. at 325. 108 Id. 109 Id. (2007). 21 probability of recouping the losses incurred in bidding up input prices through the exercise of monopsony power.”110 As with predatory pricing, the recoupment prong requires “a close analysis of both the scheme alleged by the plaintiff and the structure and conditions of the relevant market.”111 Because Ross-Simmons conceded that it failed to satisfy the Brooke Group standard, the Court held that its predatory bidding theory of liability could not support the jury’s verdict.112 Similarly, a district court upheld a plaintiff’s allegation of “predatory hiring.” Predatory hiring “occurs when talent is acquired not for purposes of using that talent but for purposes of denying it to a competitor.”113 3. Refusals to Deal Absent an anticompetitive purpose, a business may deal with whomever it chooses. Mere refusal to deal, without an agreement or conspiracy, does not violate the antitrust laws.114 The DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT underscored this principle, by explaining that “antitrust liability for unilateral, unconditional refusals to deal with rivals should not play a meaningful part in section 2 enforcement.”115 This leaves open the possibility that conditional refusals to deal may be subject to liability under Section 2. In Verizon Communications, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, the Supreme Court held that a purchaser of local telephone services failed to state a Section 2 claim against local telephone monopolist Verizon, who the plaintiff alleged had limited market entry by denying to its rivals interconnection services required by the Telecommunications Act of 110 Id. 111 Id. at 326 (quoting Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 226 (1993)). 112 Id. 113 McCabe Hamilton & Renny, Co., Ltd. v. Matson Terminals, Inc., 2008 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 47,428, at *17 (D. Haw. June 17, 2008) (citing Univ. Analytics, Inc. v. MacNealSchwendler Corp., 914 F.2d 1256, 1258 (9th Cir. 1990)). 114 United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300, 307 (1919); see also Hilton v. Children’s Hosp.–San Diego, 2007 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 16,517 (S.D. Cal. Mar. 7, 2007). 115 DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at 129. 22 1996.116 The Court concluded that Verizon’s alleged failures to fulfill its duties to its rivals under the 1996 Act did not constitute anticompetitive conduct.117 According to the Court, “Verizon’s alleged insufficient assistance in the provision of service to rivals is not a recognized antitrust claim under this Court’s existing refusal-to-deal precedents,” and neither the 1996 Act nor “traditional antitrust principles” justified “adding the present case to the few existing exceptions from the proposition that there is no duty to aid competitors.”118 The principal significance of Trinko lies in its skeptical stance toward judicial policing of refusals to deal. The effect of this stance was to sharply limit Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp.,119 the Court’s “leading case for § 2 liability based on refusal to cooperate with a rival.”120 In Aspen Skiing, the Court upheld a jury verdict in a case brought by the owner of one ski area against the owner of the other three skiing areas in Aspen. The parties had previously cooperated in issuing a joint, multiple-day, all-area ski ticket. After the defendant canceled the joint ticket program, “[t]he plaintiff, concerned that skiers would bypass its mountain without some joint offering, tried a variety of increasingly desperate measures to recreate the joint ticket, even to the point of in effect offering to buy the defendant’s tickets at retail price.”121 In Trinko, the Court emphasized the apparent profit sacrifice involved in the Aspen Skiing defendant’s conduct. “The unilateral termination of a voluntary (and thus presumably profitable) course of dealing suggested a willingness to forsake short-term profits to achieve an anticompetitive end.”122 There was no comparable profit sacrifice alleged in Trinko. Moreover, there was no discrimination in Verizon’s alleged refusal to cooperate because the 116 540 U.S. 398, 415-16 (2004). 117 Id. 118 Id. at 410-11. 119 472 U.S. 585 (1985). 120 Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408. 121 Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408-09 (citing Aspen Skiing, 472 U.S. at 593-94). 122 540 U.S. at 409. 23 services sought—unbundled telecommunications services—were not otherwise marketed or available to the public.123 The lower courts are in the process of determining how to implement Trinko’s emphasis on profit-sacrifice considerations in refusal-to-deal cases. In MetroNet Servs. Corp. v. Qwest Corp.,124 the Ninth Circuit stated that a unilateral refusal to deal claim must “entail a sacrifice of short-term profits for long-term gain from the exclusion of competition” to fall within the Aspen Skiing exception to the general rule of no duty to deal with competitors.125 However, other courts have declined to dismiss complaints that lack specific profit-sacrifice allegations.126 4. “Price Squeeze” Claims In February 2009, the Supreme Court found that Trinko bars price-squeeze claims when the parties have no duty to deal under antitrust law. 127 In linkLine, the plaintiffs were independent Internet service providers who leased wholesale DSL transport services from the defendant, AT&T, which also competed with the plaintiff for the provision of DSL service at the retail level.128 Although the Federal Communications Commission had largely dispensed with the obligation of incumbent telephone companies to sell transmission service to independent DSL providers, the FCC still required AT&T to provide interconnections as a condition of its recent merger with BellSouth.129 The plaintiffs, the beneficiaries of these mandatory interconnection requirement, claimed AT&T unlawfully “squeezed” their profit margins by 123 Id. at 410. 124 383 F.3d 1124 (9th Cir. 2004), cert. denied, 544 U.S. 1049 (2005). 125 Id. at 1134. 126 See Covad Communications Co. v. Bell Atl. Corp., 398 F.3d 666, 675–76 (D.C. Cir. 2005); A.I.B. Express, Inc. v. FedEx Corp., 2004-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 74,621 (S.D.N.Y. 2004); Creative Copier Servs. v. Xerox Corp., 344 F. Supp. 2d 858, 865–66 (D. Conn. 2004). 127 Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc’ns, Inc., No. 07-512, slip op. at 1 (S. Ct. Feb. 25, 2009). 128 Id. at 2. 129 Id. at 2. 24 setting a high price for the wholesale DSL transport service at the same time as charging a low price for DSL service to its retail customers.130 The defendant, AT&T, moved for dismissal, arguing that AT&T did not have an antitrust duty to deal with the plaintiffs in this case at either the retail or wholesale level and, therefore, the plaintiffs’ claims were barred under Trinko.131 The district court agreed that AT&T did not have an antitrust duty to deal with the plaintiffs, but noted that Trinko did not address price-squeeze claims and denied the AT&T’s motion.132 On interlocutory appeal, the Ninth Circuit also held that Trinko did not involve price-squeeze claims and, therefore, the plaintiffs’ complaint “stated a potentially valid claim under §2.”133 The question presented to the Supreme Court was “whether such a price-squeeze claim may be brought under §2 of the Sherman Act when the defendant is under no antitrust obligation to sell the inputs to the plaintiff in the first place.”134 The Court noted that although it is “technically true” that Trinko did not address “price-squeeze” claims, “AT&T could have squeezed its competitors’ profits just as effectively by providing poor-quality interconnection service to the plaintiffs, as Verizon allegedly did in Trinko.”135 Finding that Trinko applies to “price-squeeze” claims, the Supreme Court reversed the Ninth Circuit and remanded the case for further proceedings.136 5. Exclusive Dealing Exclusive dealing arrangements expressly of implicitly require a buyer to purchase all or substantially all of their supply of a specific good or service from the seller. One possible antitrust concern with exclusivity clauses is that “unilaterally imposed quantity discounts can 130 Id. at 1. 131 Id. at 3. 132 Id. at 3-4. 133 Id. at 4. 134 Id. at 1. 135 Id. at 10. 136 Id. at 17. 25 foreclose the opportunities of rivals when a dealer can obtain its best discounts only by dealing exclusively with the dominant firm.”137 Express contract language requiring exclusivity is not required in order for an agreement with a customer to “effectively foreclose[] the business of competitors” in violation of Section 2.138 In LePage’s, the plaintiff alleged that 3M entered into express exclusivity contracts with some customers and made payments to other customers “that were designed to achieve solesource status.”139 The court found that, even in the absence of express exclusivity clauses, “[o]nly by dealing exclusively with 3M in as many product lines as possible could customers enjoy the substantial discounts.”140 The court upheld the jury’s finding that the conduct violated Section 2.141 Exclusive dealing clauses can be procompetitive, even when engaged by firms with large market shares. They have been upheld when there is no significant adverse effect on competition or where the arrangements were supported by procompetitive justifications.142 Exclusive dealing can enable manufacturers to overcome free-rider issues misaligning the incentives to verticallyrelated firms to satisfy the demands of consumers most effectively.143 LePage’s Inc. v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141, 158 (3d Cir. 2003) (citing 3A PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 768b2, at 148 (2d ed. 2002)). 137 138 LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 141. 139 Id. at 157. 140 Id. at 159. 141 Id.; see also United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 64 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (condemning exclusivity agreements between Microsoft and OEMs, internet access providers, and other market participants on the ground that they barred Microsoft’s rivals from the only “cost-effective” means of distribution); see also United States v. Dentsply Int’l Inc., 399 F.3d 181, 191-93 (3d Cir. 2005) (finding that Dentsply excluded its rivals from access to dealers by refusing to sell to distributors that carried other suppliers’ products in violation of Section 2). 142 See J.B.D.L. Corp. v. Wyeth-Ayerst Labs., 485 F.3d 880, 891 (6th Cir. 2007) (dismissing plaintiff’s Section 2 claims for exclusive dealing). 143 See DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at 131. 26 The DOJ has proposed a safe harbor for exclusive dealing arrangements: Any arrangement that forecloses less than thirty percent of existing customers or effective distribution should not be illegal.144 Some lower courts have considered similar safe harbors.145 6. Bundled Discounts One business practice that has received increasing scrutiny as exclusionary conduct is the bundling of rebates allegedly leading to de facto exclusive dealing. As the Ninth Circuit explained in 2007, “[b]undling is the practice of offering, for a single price, two or more goods or services that could be sold separately [and a] bundled discount occurs when a firm sells a bundle of goods or services for a lower price than the seller charges for the goods or services purchased individually.”146 One important recent case addressing the antitrust implications of bundled discounts is LePage’s, Inc. v. 3M.147 LePage’s contended that “3M used its monopoly power over its Scotch tape brand to gain a competitive advantage in the private label tape portion of the transparent tape market . . . through the use of 3M’s multi-tiered ‘bundled rebate’ structure, which offered higher rebates when customers purchased products in a number of 3M’s different product lines.”148 The jury found for LePage’s, and the Third Circuit, sitting en banc, affirmed.149 The standard for exclusionary conduct emerging out LePage’s is murky. The Third Circuit’s en banc opinion recited a litany of cases in which exclusionary conduct had been found,150 observed that bundled rebates have the potential to “foreclose portions of the market to a potential competitor who does not manufacture an equally diverse group of products and who 144 Id. at 141. 145 See, e.g., Stop & Shop Supermarket Co. v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of R.I., 373 F.3d 57, 68 (1st Cir. 2004) (considering thirty to forty percent safe harbor); Minn. Mining & Mfg. Co. v. Appleton Papers Inc., 35 F. Supp. 2d 1138, 1143 (D. Minn. 1999) (same). 146 Cascade Health Solutions v. Peacehealth, 515 F.3d 883, 894 (9th Cir. 2008). 147 324 F.3d 141 (3rd Cir. 2003) (en banc). 148 Id. at 145. 149 Id. at 169. 150 Id. at 153-54. 27 therefore cannot make a comparable offer,”151 and concluded that “[t]he jury could reasonably find that 3M used its monopoly in transparent tape, backed by its considerable catalog of products, to squeeze out LePage’s.”152 The Court of Appeals also credited evidence “that could have led the jury to believe that rebates and discounts to [certain key accounts] were designed to induce them to award business to 3M to the exclusion of LePage’s.”153 The Third Circuit gave short shrift to 3M’s proffered business justification defense, reasoning that “3M’s business justification defense was presented to the jury, and it rejected the claim.”154 According to the court, “[t]he jury’s verdict reflects its view that 3M’s exclusionary conduct, which made it difficult for LePage’s to compete on the merits, had no legitimate business justification.”155 With respect to defining exclusionary conduct, the Third Circuit’s opinion in LePage’s is notable more for what it rejected than what it accepted. There was no dispute that 3M’s prices after applying the bundled rebates were above cost (however cost is calculated). 156 But the court rejected 3M’s attempt to import the Brooke Group standard from predatory pricing into bundled discounts.157 The Third Circuit also failed to follow the lead of the Southern District of New York’s decision in Ortho Diagnostic Systems, Inc. v. Abbott Laboratories, which requires the plaintiff to “allege and prove either that (a) the monopolist has priced below its average variable cost or (b) the plaintiff is at least as efficient a producer of the competitive product of the defendant, but that the defendant’s pricing makes it unprofitable for the plaintiff to continue to produce.”158 In fact, the Third Circuit neither required LePage’s to show that it was unable to 151 Id. at 155. 152 Id. at 157. 153 Id. at 158. 154 Id. at 164. 155 Id. 156 Id. at 147 n.5. 157 Id. at 147-52. 158 920 F. Supp. 455, 469 (S.D.N.Y. 1996). 28 make offers comparable to 3M’s nor that it would have been impossible for an equally efficient rival to compensate for 3M’s offers.159 When 3M petitioned for certiorari, the Supreme Court invited the views of the Solicitor General. Although the Solicitor General recommended against granting certiorari, this was due more to the state of the record in the case rather than because the Third Circuit’s analysis was correct or even helpful.160 The Solicitor General’s brief, in fact, lamented that “the court of appeals’ failure to identify the specific factors that made 3M’s bundled discount anticompetitive may lead to challenges to procompetitive programs and prospectively chill the adoption of such programs.”161 The Supreme Court denied certiorari,162 and substantial uncertainty remains about how antitrust courts are to evaluate claims based on bundled rebates. Further complicating the standard for exclusionary conduct in bundling cases, the Ninth Circuit in 2007 outright rejected the Third Circuit’s standard in LePage’s. In Cascade Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth, the Ninth Circuit considered whether bundled discounts provided to insurers for primary, secondary, and tertiary healthcare violated Section 2 of the Sherman Act.163 Cascade and PeaceHealth operated the only two hospital systems in the Lane County, Oregon, area. Cascade filed suit against PeaceHealth alleging that its practice of offering discounts for tertiary care violated Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act. Specifically, Cascade alleged that PeaceHealth offered discounts for tertiary care in the range of thirty-five to forty percent to insurers in exchange for making the PeaceHealth system their exclusive provider for primary, See LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 175 (Greenberg, J., dissenting) (“LePage’s did not even attempt to show that it could not compete by calculating the discount that it would have had to provide in order to match the discounts offered by 3M through its bundled rebates, and thus its brief does not point to evidence along such lines.”); id. at 177 (Greenberg, J., dissenting) (discussing concession of LePage’s expert that LePage’s was less efficient than 3M). 159 See Br. for the United States as Amicus Curiae, 3M Co. v. LePage’s Inc., No. 02-1865 (S.Ct. 2004), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f203900/203900.pdf. 160 161 Id. at 18. 162 542 U.S. 953 (2004). 163 515 F.3d 883 (9th Cir. 2008). 29 secondary, and tertiary care.164 On appeal, the Ninth Circuit considered whether PeaceHealth’s use of exclusive bundled services provisions satisfied the “anticompetitive conduct” element of its attempted monopolization claim. The Ninth Circuit rejected the Third Circuit’s standard for cost allocation in LePage’s. Instead, the Ninth Circuit adopted a “discount attribution” test by which the entire discount for all services is allocated to the single product for which the plaintiff claims exclusion. “If the resulting price of the competitive produce or products is below the defendant’s incremental cost to produce them, the trier of fact may find that the bundled discount is exclusionary for the purpose of § 2.”165 No consensus exists among courts as to considering the legality of bundled discounts. The DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT suggests that when a firm offers a bundled discount and some bundle-to-bundle competition is possible (i.e., there are other firms that could offer the same bundle of goods) courts should consider the discount to be lawful if the price of the bundle taken as a whole is not below an appropriate measure of cost of that bundle.166 However, when bundle-to-bundle competition is not possible, the DOJ advocates considering whether the price of competitive goods is above cost after allocating the entire discount to the competitive goods.167 7. Exclusionary Conduct in Standard Setting The law of Section 2 as applied to conduct within the standard setting context lacks clearly defined guidance. Recent enforcement actions by the FTC have challenged deceptive conduct and the enforcement of royalty rights relating to standards. Unfortunately, these enforcement actions have provided little guidance for antitrust practitioners. The FTC has brought two enforcement actions challenging deception in the standard setting context. In both Rambus and Unocal, the FTC alleged that participants in a standard setting organization misled the organization regarding their ownership and control of patents 164 Id. at 891-92. 165 Id. at 906. 166 See DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at 101. 167 See id. at 101-02. 30 which ultimately were incorporated into a standard.168 The Commission’s concerns in Unocal were resolved by consent decree.169 After proceedings, the Federal Trade Commission found Rambus liable under Section 2 for its failure to disclose a patent and several pending patent applications that involved specific technologies ultimately adopted in a standard.170 On appeal, the D.C. Circuit reversed the Commission’s decision, finding the Commission failed to prove that the standard setting organization would have adopted alternative technology if Rambus had disclosed the patent ownership.171 The Supreme Court denied certiorari in February 2009.172 Although reversing the FTC’s finding of liability in this case, the D.C. Circuit left open the possibility that deceptive conduct in standard setting organizations could constitute a violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act. The FTC also considered whether enforcement of patent royalty rights could violate the antitrust laws in its investigation of Negotiated Data Solutions LLC (N-Data). In this case, National Semiconductor (National) participated in setting a standard for a technology known as “NWay.”173 National fully disclosed its patent interests and agreed to accept a token royalty if its patents were included in the standard, which they ultimately were.174 Years later, National sold the relevant patents to Vertical Networks, Inc. (Vertical), who for a period of time continued See Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm’n, FTC Finds Rambus Unlawfully Obtained Monopoly Power (Aug. 2, 2006), at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2006/08/rambus.shtm [hereinafter Rambus Statement]; Statement of the Federal Trade Commission In the Matter of Union Oil Company of California, Docket No. 9305 and In the Matter of Chevron Corporation and Unocal Corporation, File No. 051-0125, Docket No. C-4144, Aug. 2, 2005, at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0510125/0510125.shtm [hereinafter Unocal Statement]. 168 169 See Unocal Statement, supra note 169. 170 See Rambus Statement, supra note 169. 171 See Rambus Inc. v. Fed. Trade Comm’n, 522 F.3d 456 (D.C. Cir. 2008). 172 See Certiorari - Summary Dispositions, at http://www.supremecourtus.gov/orders/courtorders/022309zor.pdf. 173 Complaint, In the Matter of Negotiated Data Solutions, LLC, FTC No. 051 0094 (Jan. 23, 2008), at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0510094/index.shtm. 174 Id. 31 to not enforce the patent rights or seek royalties.175 After several years, however, Vertical began enforcing the patents, seeking exorbitant licensing fees.176 Vertical then sold the patent rights to N-Data, which continued to seek the exorbitant licensing fees. 177 The FTC entered into a consent decree with N-Data to settle its concerns that N-Data’s conduct violated Section 5 of the FTC Act.178 Notably, the FTC did not allege a violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act. 8. Exclusionary Conduct in Category Captain Arrangements There has been much commentary, but little case law, on the widespread practice known as “category management” and “category captaincy.” Category management is a retail technique in which the management of the retail establishment is broken down into categories. Category captains are suppliers, usually the largest supplier, to which the retailer looks for advice in managing the category.179 There are generally three antitrust concerns expressed regarding category captaincy: (1) it can be used to facilitate a price-fixing conspiracy among retailers in violation of Section 1; (2) it can be used by a dominant supplier to drive a competitor out of the market in violation of Section 2; and (3) it can be a form of discrimination in violation of the Robinson-Patman Act. Two federal cases have addressed the concept of category captaincy from the antitrust perspective; both cases focused on Section 2. In Conwood Co., L.P. v. U.S. Tobacco Co., the plaintiff (Conwood) alleged that the defendant (USTC) used its category captain position to facilitate monopolization and attempted monopolization of the market in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act.180 Specifically, USTC “pursued strategies . . . to exclude competition in the 175 Id. 176 Id. 177 Id. Statement of the Fed. Trade Comm’n In the Matter of Negotiated Data Solutions LLC, File No. 0510094, Jan. 23, 2008, at http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/0510094/index.shtm. 178 179 Federal Trade Commission Staff, Report on the Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Slotting Allowances and Other Marketing Practices in the Grocery Industry, at 47 (Feb. 2001), available at http://www.ftc.gov/bc/slotting/index.htm. 180 290 F.3d 768 (6th Cir. 2002), cert. denied, 537 U.S. 1148 (2003). 32 moist snuff market” including convincing retailers to have “exclusive” racks in their stores and “routinely discard[ed] hundreds of thousands of Conwood racks.181 The jury held for the plaintiff, returning a $350 million verdict that was trebled to over $1 billion. The Sixth Circuit affirmed. The case did not adjudge the category management relationship at issue to be illegal, but held that abuse of the category captain position could be a way of unfairly excluding competitors. As the Sixth Circuit explained: [T]here was . . . evidence . . . that [the defendant] used its position as category manager to exclude competition by suggesting that retailers carry fewer products, particularly competitor’s products; by attempting to control the number of price value brands introduced in stores; and by suggesting that stores carry its slower moving products instead of better selling competitor products. … [T]hat evidence was … probative of [the defendant’s] intent to exclude competition.182 The court found USTC’s actions harmed both Conwood specifically and competition in the moist snuff market generally in violation of Section 2. In El Aguila Food Products Inc. v. Gruma Corp., a plaintiff (El Aguila) challenged the defendant’s (Gruma’s) payment of money to become a category captain and its actions as a category captain as violations of Section 1, Section 2, and the Robinson-Patman Act.183 The court rejected all of these claims, and the Fifth Circuit affirmed.184 Although these courts did not validate (or reject) the concept of category captaincy, the district court especially noted evidence of the efficiencies associated with such a system.185 Neither Conwood nor El Aguila are very clear legal markers by which to judge category captain conduct with respect to Section 2 or any other legal theory. This issue will continue to be worked out in future cases. 181 Id. at 775, 778. 182 Id. at 785-86. 183 301 F. Supp. 2d 612 (S.D. Tex. 2003). 184 131 Fed. App’x. 450 (5th Cir. 2005). 185 301 F. Supp. 2d at 623-24. 33 V. Conclusion: More Guidance Is Needed Despite laudable efforts by enforcement agencies in the United States, the application of Section 2 of the Sherman Act to single-firm conduct in the United States remains confused. In light of the agencies’ recognition that “[c] ompetition and consumers are best served if section 2 standards are sound, clear, objective, effective, and administrable,”186 the agencies should continue their efforts to provide transparency and guidance to antitrust practitioners and their clients in this area of the law. 186 DOJ SECTION 2 REPORT, supra note 12, at vii; see Deborah Platt Majoras, Chairman, Federal Trade Commission, Remarks, The Consumer Reigns: Using Section 2 to Ensure a “Competitive Kingdom”, June 20, 2006, available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/sectiontwohearings/index.shtm. 34