The Politics of Oil: Interest Groups and Oil Policy in the Beaufort Sea

advertisement
THE POLITICS OF OIL:
INTEREST GROUPS AND OIL POLICY IN THE BEAUFORT SEA REGION
Melissa Shaffer-O’Connell
Lake Superior State University
mshafferoconnell@lssu.edu
ABSTRACT
Federalism often creates additional decisions for interest groups in determining how best
to advocate for their policy recommendations. Should they focus their advocacy at the local,
state, or national level of government? What activities should they use at each level of
government? In this paper, the results of sixteen interviews with groups active in Beaufort Sea
oil policy in the United States and Canada are used to answer these questions. The results show
that in many cases groups are influenced by which level of government has greatest jurisdiction
over the policy, at what stage in the policy process the issue is, and the resources and goals of the
group.
Prepared for the Western Political Science Association’s Annual Conference, Panel 3.13 on
Utilizing Legal/Administrative Pathways and Tools, Seattle, WA,
April 17-19, 2014.
1
INTRODUCTION
Overlapping policies and the influence of binational institutions offer multiple
opportunities for interest groups in federal systems, but also increase the costs associated with
advocacy. Due to a lack of time and resources, interest groups must act strategically. How do
these groups decide at which level of government to target their actions? How do they determine
the tactics that they would use? The interest group literature has addressed the organization of
interest groups and the tactics they use, but little research has been done on how interest groups
choose which level of government to target in federal systems or which tactics to use (Hamm &
Hogan 2004). Some scholars have used large-scale studies to try to answer similar questions to
these1, yet, as Andrews and Edwards (2004: 492) point out, studies focused on a narrow issue or
policy area can often better test rival explanations and specific causal mechanisms. For this
reason, I focus on the intersection of oil policy and environmental policy in the Beaufort Sea
region to test multiple explanations of group behavior. I do this through interviews with
representatives of 16 interest groups from Canada and the United States that were active on
Beaufort Sea oil policies in 2010-2013.
Why the intersection of environmental policy and oil policy in the Beaufort Sea region?
Oil policy is quite broad, covering onshore and offshore oil development, taxation,
environmental issues, etc. However, focusing on the intersection of oil policy and environmental
policy limits the issues while maintaining a wide variety of active groups and retaining current
political salience. Throughout this paper I will be using both terms (oil policy and environmental
policy), but the focus remains on the point where the two intersect.
1
For studies focused on national groups, see Schlozman & Tierney 1986, Berry 1989, Walker 1991, Heinz et al.
1993, and Baumgartner & Leech 1998. For studies on groups at the state level, see Gray & Lowery 1996 and
Nownes & Freeman 1998.
2
One benefit of this case is that it is contained to a specific geographic area and yet crosses
the border between the two countries, allowing for natural controls of geographic and issue
specific peculiarities. The Beaufort Sea straddles the border between Canada and the United
States; thus geography and natural resources are similar in both countries.
In addition, oil policy is shared between the states and the national government in the
United States, and natural resource policy is increasingly being shifted to the provincial level in
Canada, which has led to a tricky and evolving legislative environment for interest groups. This
offers interest groups the opportunity to choose to focus their efforts at either level of
government. Finally, there is a wide diversity of groups that are active, ranging from the more
traditional business and environmental groups to recreational and Native American/First Nations
groups and from small local groups to international interest groups.
The following section details the methodology of the data collection, followed by a
section on the hypotheses derived from the following theories: neoinstitutionalism, elite theory,
organizational theory, and political opportunity structures theory. I then have a short section
describing the range of groups interviewed before moving into the analysis of hypotheses based
on the interview data. The analysis is broken into two sections: the first is on the targeted level of
government and the second on choice of tactics. The final section discusses the conclusions that
can be drawn from the analysis.
METHODOLOGY
As the questions that are the basis of this research are about how groups make decisions,
the most direct route to find answers was to ask representatives of the groups, specifically the
staff members that make the decisions. First, however, I had to determine what groups to contact.
It is exceedingly difficult to define the population of interest groups that are active within a
3
particular policy area (Doyle and McEachern 2001, 61). As Salisbury (1992: 167) found in
attempting to delineate the participants in agriculture, energy, health, and labor policy, there is no
existing list of participants in most public policy areas, including oil, natural resource, and
environmental policy. In fact, it is virtually impossible to define the population of groups
involved because it can vary so widely and include groups that have very little interest in the
policy area in general but may be active on one particular issue.
So for this research, names of groups active in oil policy were compiled from media
accounts2, coalition listings, and suggestions from prior interviewees.3 A list of the groups
interviewed is in Appendix A. The interviews were conducted by phone or by email with
presidents, directors, or individuals in more specialized positions dealing with legislative policy
and focused on interest group decisions within the past two years.4
The interviews generally followed a questionnaire that was designed to elicit open-ended
responses about the two dependent variables. The first dependent variable in this research is the
level of government that interest groups target. This was addressed through a series of questions
about which level of government the group targeted and why they targeted that particular level or
combination of levels of government. Although this research is concerned with the national and
state and territorial levels, some of the groups targeted local or international government or
institutions as well. These responses are recorded and analyzed even though they do not fit into
the levels of government specifically of interest to this research, as the reason groups opt to
target those levels may support a given hypothesis.
2
Prior research on the history of group activities used newspaper accounts spanning 1940-2000. Names of groups
mentioned in those accounts were compiled and then the groups that were no longer active in 2010 were eliminated.
3
This list included 59 interest groups that were active on Great Lakes water quality policies in 2010. Of the 59
groups, 26 were interviewed and 33 declined to be interviewed for a response rate of 42 percent.
4
The interviews, for the most part, were conducted in 2011 to 2013 and reported political conditions reflect that
time period. Follow-up email discussions occurred for some of the interviews and secured additional information or
clarified earlier comments. These email conversations happened between 2011 and 2013.
4
The second dependent variable is tactics used by the interest group in attempting to
influence legislative policy at each level of government. All tactics used were included in this
investigation, but three were of particular interest: coalition building, lobbying, and grassroots
mobilization. The definition of lobbying varies between scholars. Some scholars consider it to be
any activity a group takes in order to be politically represented, which may include grassroots
mobilization, donation to PACs, or coalition formation (Graziano 2001). Other scholars
characterize lobbying as solely the face-to-face meetings with legislators to convey information
and make arguments (Salisbury 1992). Much of this confusion stems from the activities of
professional lobbyists, who often do a little of everything. For this research, lobbying includes
gaining access to policy makers, creating a favorable view of the group for the policy maker, and
influencing the policy maker by a senior member of a group or a paid lobbyist (Thomas 2004).
Contact with legislators by the group membership will be considered grassroots mobilization.
Grassroots mobilization and coalition building are discussed as tactics separate from lobbying.
Lobbying is an important tactic for groups: Schlozman and Tierney (1986: 150) found
that over 95 percent of groups use lobbying tactics. According to Browne (1998: 360),
federalism allows for more opportunities to lobby at all levels or “all-directional advocacy”:
“there always is someone who occupies a political office who will eventually listen to nearly any
interest”. Groups do not just lobby allies, but may spread lobbying across allies, opponents, and
legislators that are still undecided about a piece of legislation (Leech & Baumgartner 1998).
Grassroots mobilization is the exertion of pressure on lawmakers by citizens and has
become more popular with advances in communications technology (Berry 1997; Cigler &
Loomis 1995; Goldstein 1999; Kollman 1998). It is used frequently in the United States and
Canada (McCarthy 2005), even though it has been found to be less effective with large-scale,
5
impersonal mail and email campaigns (Berry 1997). It is also an important tactic for interest
groups: Schlozman and Tierney (1986: 150-55) found that 80 percent of the groups that they
surveyed use grassroots lobbying and that use has increased among those groups.
Coalition building is an influential tactic for groups because it shows unity of purpose,
combines resources and abilities, and also activates a larger “reference public”, or group of
constituents (Lipsky 1968). Lawmakers are more likely to listen to a large coalition than to a
small, independent interest group. This is especially true with the plethora of groups that exist in
the United States and Canada since the 1960s (Hula 1995). For these reasons, more groups are
showing an interest in forming and working within coalitions (Rochon & Meyer 1997).
However, due to the diversity in goals and resources within a coalition, these coalitions are often
difficult to form and maintain (Duffy 2003, 113; Hula 1995). Even with these drawbacks, Milne
et al. (1996) found that at least two-thirds of environmental interest groups form coalitions with
other groups.
There were two primary questions during the interviews designed to determine use of
tactics: a question about what tactics the group uses in general and another question about
whether and how those tactics are tailored by the level of government. The first question gets to
the issue of which tactics are utilized most frequently by the groups, while the second determines
whether different tactics are used at different level of governments.
In addition to those questions, other information was collected during the interview,
including the organization’s purpose and goals, how many paid staff members the group
employed, what the budget was, how many members and what types of members the group had,
and what year the group was created. To conclude, the group representative was asked to
describe a recent campaign dealing with oil policies in the Beaufort Sea region that illustrated the
6
responses given prior to that point. Some of this data are expressly required to test specific
hypotheses detailed below, while the rest are used for control variables.
HYPOTHESES
Neoinstitutionalism, elite theory, organizational theory, and political opportunity
structures theory all propose different answers to the research questions. Neoinstitutionalism
suggests institutions are the driving explanatory variable behind individual and group behaviors.
Elite theory places elite interactions at the forefront of investigation. Meanwhile, organizational
theory suggests tradition and resources of the organization are the primary determinants of
organizational behavior. Political Opportunity Structures theory states that political variables,
such as the party in power, are the important variables in group decision-making. Each of these
will be described in more depth below, with hypotheses on targeted level of government number
H1 to H4 and hypotheses on tactics number H5 through H8.
Neoinstitutionalism
There are several variations of neoinstitutionalism. What each of these types of neoinstitutionalism share is an emphasis on institutions as important variables in political research
(Peters 2005) and an “opinion that institutions can and should be seen as ‘rules’ which, in one
way or another, influence behaviour of political and social actors” (Keman 1998: 110). It
recognizes the agency of individual groups while emphasizing that their behaviors are
constrained by institutions and context (Thelen and Steinmo 1992).
Federalism, especially, is important in the environmental arena, as “whether people live
in healthy or polluted environments depends very much on the joint activities of local state, and
national officials” (Anton 1989, 1). The term ‘federalism’ is used to describe the division of
powers between national and subnational governments (Riker 1975). Which level of government
7
has the most authority over a particular issue depends on the level of policy centralization. The
level of policy centralization is a result of the division of powers in a federal system and the way
the courts interpret that division. It is usually specified in the constitution, although there is often
jurisdictional overlap with more than one government having authority within an issue area
(Bowman 2002).
In addition to the impact federalism has on environmental policy and resultant
environmental conditions, it also allows for multiple venues of participation for interest groups
determining policy, so it is important to interest groups as well. However, as mentioned above,
the level of centralization is not static, but rather it changes over time with court decisions and
shifts in jurisdiction. It is important to recognize the impact of these on interest group behavior.
Due to the division of power in federal systems, interest groups must apportion their time
and resources between regional and national governments when jurisdiction is split between the
two (Pross 1975; Schultz 1980). Most research on interest groups has focused on interest group
activity at one level of the federal system, without analyzing why interest groups chose to target
that level rather than other levels of government (Thomas 2004). Shaffer5 (1995), in a survey of
94 environmental groups in the United States, found that approximately twenty-five percent
focus on the national and state levels each, while nearly half focus on the local level. However,
in further analysis, Shaffer combines national and state lobbying into one category, thereby
losing the ability to determine why interest groups chose to lobby one level of government over
the other.
In some cases, groups may react to disliked legislation at one level by attempting to
change venues. Pralle (2006: 26) studied interest groups involved in forestry policy in California
and British Columbia and found that the groups practice venue shopping: “venue shopping refers
5
Shaffer and I are of no relation.
8
to the activities of advocacy groups who seek out a decision setting where they can air their
grievances with current policy and present alternative policy proposals.” Pralle (2006) found that
interest groups changed venue when they perceived that they would have more success in a
different venue and avoided government venues with little authority over the issue of concern.
This leads to the neoinstitutional hypothesis:
H1: Interest groups are more likely to target the level of government which has the
greatest jurisdiction over environmental policy in the group’s issue area than a level with
less authority.
For groups in the United States, this would be the national level for most environmental
policy issues and for oil development in the Beaufort Sea region. Yukon Territory has recently
(in the 1990s and 2000s) had jurisdiction over natural resources transferred to territorial control,
so Canadian groups in the case study should focus on the territorial level.
The degree of centralization within federal systems also has an effect on the choices
made by interest groups in terms of tactics. Interest groups have a variety of tactics to choose
from and it is reasonable to believe that they will use the most influential for the level of
government at which most legislation is passed. Personal lobbying has been shown to be one of
the most influential tactics at both the national level (Berry 1977; Milbrath 1963) and state level
(Zeigler & Baer 1969).
Interest groups are also expected to reserve the more expensive tactics for the level of
government with greatest jurisdiction. Even when interest groups may be attempting to influence
a level of government that has lesser jurisdiction over the issue, they will be less likely to use
resource-intensive tactics at that level. If this is the case, then interest groups would be more
likely to use expensive tactics, such as personal lobbying, at the targeted level of government
than at an alternate level of government. While personal lobbying is influential, it is also quite
9
expensive, especially at the national level (Schlozman & Tierney 1986); one of the most
expensive tactics for interest groups to pursue. However, inexpensive tactics, such as grassroots
mobilization can be expected at both the targeted and non-targeted venues. This leads to
neoinstitutional hypothesis regarding tactics:
H5: Interest groups are more likely to use the most influential, but expensive, tactics,
such as personal lobbying, at the level of government that has the most jurisdiction.
Thus, we would expect that interest groups are more likely to use personal lobbying on the
targeted level of government than a secondary level. If groups do not use personal lobbying at
the targeted level, use it at the secondary level, or use it at both levels, then this hypothesis will
be shown false.
Elite Theory
Elite theory disregards the impact of institutions and focuses on elites as explanatory
variables. Elite theorists posit that most governmental decisions are centralized, made by the
elites in government and society (Bachrach & Baratz 1962). While Presthus (1973) includes
leaders in the non-profit sectors as members of the elite, many elite theorists focus on economic
elites as dominant decision makers (Bachrach & Baratz 1962, 1970; Bond 2007). Presthus
(1973) has argued that elite theory is especially useful for understanding the Canadian political
system and interaction with interest groups due to the centralization of power in the cabinet,
cleavages in the society, and the culture of deference to authority. Traditionally, elite theory has
focused on who the elite are, what their policy stances are, how representative of the masses they
are, and how elite accommodation affects policy outcomes (Higley & Pakulski 2000, 35);
however, it also suggests a few hypotheses regarding my research questions as well.
10
In order to avoid societal conflicts, elites discuss issues and make decisions among
themselves, therefore relying on more interpersonal means of communication and decision
making. Rather than constant interaction about specific legislation, elites rely on frequent social
interaction with occasional lobbying or pressure on important legislation by a united coalition
(Presthus 1973, 61). For this reason, and because they often want to keep a low profile, economic
elites are most likely to intervene when the status quo is being threatened (Bachrach and Baratz
1970, 49-50). Rather than appear demanding by constantly pressuring political elites, economic
elites typically wait until their interests are being threatened by environmental legislation to
make their voices heard. Thus, according to elite theory, corporations and businesses would be
most likely to target the level of government where they perceive a threat to the status quo, in the
form of perceived anti-business legislation.
H2: Corporate and business elites target the level of government that is making
pro-environment or perceived anti-business legislation.
The expectation is that business groups mobilize when pro-environment or anti-business
legislation is being introduced or debated at either level of government, but otherwise maintain a
low profile. If there is mobilization to introduce pro-business legislation or no action when proenvironment legislation is introduced then this theory will be disproven.
According to elite theory, members of the elite share many common characteristics, such
as education, socio-economic class, membership in associations, etc. This leads to a connection
among the members of the elite (Farazmand 1999; Presthus 1973). They are more comfortable
conversing privately among themselves and making decisions outside of the public sphere. In
terms of tactics, this would suggest a prominence of lobbying over more public activities such as
grassroots mobilization (Doyle & McEachern 2001). This is confirmed in the finding by Presthus
11
(1973) that Canadian groups were more likely to use personal lobbying over grassroots
mobilization, especially business groups. Thus,
H6: Business and economic groups will be more likely to use personal lobbying at all
levels of government.
This hypothesis would be quickly disproven if groups used grassroots mobilization more
frequently or rarely used lobbying.
Organizational Theory
Organizational studies argue, in part, that groups become bureaucratized and
professionalized over time, often relying on tradition to determine action (Campbell 2005).
Additionally, conflict within the group over how decisions are made and by whom they are
made, lead to prescribed rules of action and routine decision making (Olsen 1998).
Organizational studies also emphasize the role of organizational resources (Campbell 2005). The
overall resources of the group may determine which level of government a group is able to
target. For example, it is more expensive for a small group to target the national government than
to target the state legislature, especially if there is physical distance with which to contend
(Kolby 2009). This leads to the hypothesis:
H3: Groups with more resources are more likely to target the national government than
groups with fewer resources.
If all groups, regardless of resources, target the same level of government then that would
indicate that this hypothesis is incorrect.
Tradition plays an important role in the choice of tactics, according to organizational
theorists. Groups have the tendency to use those tactics which they have always used because the
organizational capabilities related to those tactics are already developed. For example,
12
Staggenborg (1991) found, in a study of pro-choice groups, that leaders tended to bureaucratize
and formalize operations of a group, which often meant a reliance on the same tactics over time.
The hypothesis derived from this theory is:
H7: Group tactics do not change over time.
This differs from institutional theories which posit that group tactics will shift for different levels
of government and changes in jurisdiction.
Political Opportunity Structures Theory
The Political Opportunity Structures (POS) literature within social movement literature
focuses on the influence of political institutions on social movements and social movement
organizations (SMOs) (McAdam, McCarthy, & Zald 1996; Tarrow 1994). POS posits that
movements and groups act within a set of political conditions that influence their behavior
through constraints on action and the opening of opportunities (McAdam et al. 1996). In many
ways, this theory would produce similar hypotheses as neoinstitutionalism; however there are a
few differences that would generate competing hypotheses. The primary component of the
political environment that may impact which level of government a group may target is the
presence or absence of political allies within elites (Campbell 2005). Political allies can refer to
individual persons or to a party that is receptive to the goals of the group. Young and Everitt
(2004) found that the receptivity of the government is directly tied to the party in power and the
correspondence between the goals of the interest group and those of the party. Many scholars
recognize that Leftist governments are more receptive to environmental groups, while parties
toward the Right are more receptive to business groups (Dalton et al. 2003). Interest groups
recognize this receptivity and are more likely to focus their attention on receptive lawmakers
13
rather than those that are not receptive to the group’s goals (Milbrath 1963; Bauer, Pool, and
Dexter 1963). A hypothesis derived from this is:
H4: Groups are more likely to target the level of government in which there is a political
party receptive to their goals.
If groups target a level of government with a party in power that is not receptive to their goals
then that would disprove this hypothesis.
POS scholars argue that groups should, and do, use tactics which are more likely to bring
them success within a system (Dalton et al. 2003). However, in challenging the status quo of the
current system, groups would be more likely to use grassroots mobilization to show broad
support, while groups working to maintain the current system would be more likely to use more
conventional methods such as lobbying. As advocacy groups are more likely to be challenging
the status quo and business groups more likely to support the state quo:
H8: Advocacy groups are more likely to use grassroots mobilization at all levels of
government than business groups.
If business groups are found to use grassroots mobilization at the same, or at higher levels, than
advocacy groups, then this hypothesis will be shown false.
Before testing these hypotheses, it is important to know the number and types of groups
in the analysis, especially since many of the hypotheses are specific to a type of group or the
location (Canada or the United States) of the group. The following section gives an overview of
the type, origin, membership, and age of the groups in the sample.
THE GROUPS
While there is a large literature on interest groups, there is no single agreed-upon
definition of interest group among interest group scholars. A broad definition, and the one used
for this research, is offered by Thomas (2004: 4): “An interest group is an association of
14
individuals or organization… that, on the basis of one or more shared concerns, attempts to
influence public policy in its favor.” This definition includes a wide variety of groups which may
be active within environmental policy, including traditional membership groups, organizational
interests and for-profit groups.
Ten of the groups I interviewed were citizen groups: nine conservation groups and one
environmental group. The remaining six groups were industry groups. Although there are fewer
industry groups interviewed, there are also fewer industry groups contacted, so the response rate
for industry groups (40% response rate) was not significantly different from that of citizen
groups (44% response rate). No indigenous groups agreed to an interview.
This is a comparative study of United States and Canada and groups from both countries
were interviewed. Additionally, binational and international groups that operated in one of the
two countries were included in the sample pool. Of the 16 groups that I interviewed, two were
based in Canada, 13 were from the United States, and one was international. A much higher
number of groups in the United States than in Canada can be expected: the United States has a
larger population and more interest groups in general than Canada.
The groups ranged in age, with the oldest group established in 1927 (Canadian
Association of Petroleum Producers) and the youngest in 2001 (Oceana); however half of the 16
groups were established during the environmental movement in the 1960s and 1970s. The
resources of the groups (membership, paid staff, and budget) were also very different.
Membership variance was difficult to capture in a graph as it varied from groups with no formal
membership (for example, Canadian Arctic Resources Committee) to groups with individual
members in the millions (Defenders of Wildlife) to groups made up entirely of groups or
businesses (Alaska State Chamber of Commerce) or a combination of individuals and groups
15
(Arctic Power). As Baumgartner and Leech (1998: 33) found, membership is a “deceptively
complicated concept”. Similarly, paid staff varied from having only one paid staff member
(Canadian Arctic Resources Committee) to groups with staffs into the hundreds (National
Audubon Society). However, six of the 16 groups in the sample had staffs between 1 and 20
people. Finally, budgets of the groups range from the hundreds of thousands up into the millions,
although seven of the 16 groups are between $1 million and $20 million. Six groupa declined to
give a budget and several gave a range rather than a number.
While the sample size is small, as shown above, there is a range of groups represented.
There was variation of type, origin, age, membership, and budget. This is important in order to
be able to test the hypotheses described in the section above. The sample is too small to have
statistically significant findings, but as the interviews were meant to get at the reasons for the
decisions rather than correlations between factors, it still led to some fascinating and telling
results.
RESULTS
This section begins with a general discussion of which level of government groups
targeted and then moves on to a more detailed analysis of the results in relation to the
hypotheses. For targeted level of government, the neoinstitutional and organizational hypotheses
have the greatest support. This is followed by a general discussion of choice of tactics, followed
by analysis of the hypotheses for choice of tactics. For tactics, no one hypothesis was strongly
supported, although the organizational theory hypothesis is best supported by the interview data.
Most groups are active at both the national and state/territorial levels of government.
However, if one level of government was targeted more than 50 percent of the time then the
group's response was coded as targeting that level of government. Three groups responded that
16
either they are active equally at each level of government or that they do not target one level of
government over another. More groups targeted the national level than state/territorial: eight
groups target the national level and four target the state/territorial level. One group split its time
equally between the national and territorial level: Canadian Association of Petroleum Producers.
The neoinstitutional (H1) and the organizational theory (H3) hypotheses were best
supported by the interviews. The aggregate data from these interviews (Figure 1) support H1 in
both countries, and many of the individual responses support the hypothesis. Seven United
States' groups did target the national level. However, three U.S. groups also targeted the state
level of government; while another two split their time equally between all levels of government
(this includes the international level). Of the groups that do target the national government in the
United States, four indicated that the reason for that is because that is where the legislation is
being passed. As one representative stated (who asked not to be identified): “the federal
government is the one that makes the decisions, so that is where we are active.” Adrian Herrera,
the DC Coordinator for Arctic Power, a group that is focused on gaining approval for oil
exploration within the Arctic National Wildlife Refuge, put it succinctly: “the decision has to be
made by Congress, that’s why” (2013, March 12. Telephone Interview).
17
Figure 1: Targeted Level of Government by Country (n=16)
8
7
6
5
State or Territorial
State or Territorial/National
4
National
3
All
2
1
0
Canada
United States
International
One problem that came up with the interview methodology had to do with multi-tiered
organizations. In the case of a group with a national group and subgroups, I chose to interview
the level of the organization that did the most work within the Great Lakes region. The national
League of Conservation Voters handles the oil policy activism for the arctic region, so I
interviewed the national group for that case study. This does impact the rationale of the groups
for targeting a certain level. The legislative director of the National Audubon Society, Brian
Moore, reaffirmed this: “they [state Audubon Societies] work with their state legislature and
state agencies on a regular basis and then when it comes to doing things nationally or
coordinating nationally or working here in Washington with the Congress... we do that” (2013,
May 21. Phone Interview.). I interviewed three multi-tiered groups in the United States (there
were no multi-tiered Canadian groups): two national level groups and one state level group. If
18
these groups are eliminated from the analysis, then three groups would have targeted the state
level and five the national level. This still supports the hypothesis in the U.S.
No Canadian groups exclusively targeted the territorial level of government. Both
Canadian groups targeted a combination of the territorial and national governments or all levels
of government (this included local and international). The reason given by both groups was that
both levels are currently involved in oil policy. As Aaron Miller, of CAPP, pointed out,
“devolution is not going to happen overnight” (2013, April 11. Telephone Interview).
Organizational theory was supported in the aggregate for staff members (Figure 2), but
not for budget. No responses supported the theory. The one group with staff of over 200 did
focus on all levels of governments. A plurality of groups with staffs of 1 to 20 people targeted
the state level, but groups with that staff size also targeted the national and all levels of
governments.
Figure 2: Targeted Level of Government by Staff (n=15)
4.5
4
3.5
3
1 to 20
2.5
21-60
2
61-100
101-200
1.5
201 or more
1
0.5
0
State or Territorial
State or
Territorial/National
National
19
All levels
The results for targeted level of government by budget were inconclusive. While, in
general, larger groups target higher levels of government, some of the smallest groups target the
national government and some of the largest groups target the state/territorial governments.
Groups with mid-range budgets are spread across all levels. As with staff size, no groups
indicated that this factor was important in deciding which level of government to target.
Political Opportunity Structures theory (H4) posits that groups target the level of
government at which there is a party receptive to the group’s goals. At the time of the interviews,
in Canada the Conservatives were in power at the national level and while Yukon was dominated
by the Yukon Party, which is a conservative party, it had only a slim majority of seats. In the
United States, a divided government existed at the national level with the Senate and presidency
held by Democrats and the House of Representatives held by Republicans. Alaska remained
Republican during the interviews. In general then, according to this hypothesis, citizen groups in
the United States are most likely to target the national government, while industry targets the
state level. In Canada, it is expected that industry groups may target either level, while citizen
groups may be more likely to target the territorial level. However, there was no clear pattern for
either citizen groups or industry groups in either country. In Canada, the industry group targeted
both the territorial and national government, but so did the citizen group. In the United States, a
higher number of citizen groups targeted the national government and a higher number industry
groups targeted the state level, but the responses indicate it has more to do with the favorability
of the level of government than the party in power. However, one environmental group
representative, who asked not to be named, responded that the state government (under a
Republican administration) was not supportive of their work, so they focused almost entirely on
the national government. This was the only response by a U.S. group that supported this
20
hypothesis and referenced the party in power as playing a role in decision-making about which
level of government to target. The fact that the representative did not want to be directly quoted
or named when giving their response seems to indicate a reticence on the part of groups to give
that particular response, which may bias the data.
According to elite theory, H2, business and industry groups should target the level of
government that is passing unfavorable legislation. The targeted level of government would shift
with the type of legislation. However, with the exception of one industry group (in Canada), the
industry group representatives clearly indicated that they targeted one level of government more
than any other. However, there was some indication that it played a role in the decision-making
for some groups. For example, a few industry groups cited legislation as issues the group was
active on rather than a broad issue area, which seems to indicate a reaction to legislation rather
than proactive measures on an issue area. Again, while not explicit, it does seem to indicate a
reactive stance. If this offers any support for this hypothesis, it is only weak support in that it was
deduced from responses rather than clearly stated.
For targeted level of government, neoinstitutionalism and organizational theory had the
most support, but what about for the choice of tactics? First, a discussion of what tactics the
groups used in general. When asked to give the top two or three tactics used by the group in
general, not all groups answered with specific tactics. One group representative emphasized that
they did not lobby legislators but rather educated them on the issues. This distinction is important
for charitable groups, especially in Canada, as they are limited in what they can do. However, for
the sake of this research, those responses have been coded as lobbying of legislators, as I use a
broader definition of lobbying which includes educating legislators.
21
Lobbying was the number one tactic mentioned: every group mentioned lobbying as one
of the top two or three tactics. Grassroots mobilization was also listed frequently, with ten of the
16 groups listing it among the top two or three tactics. Only three groups listed coalition-building
as a tactic; however, it was not because they are not members of coalitions. In one of the
interview questions, I specifically ask if they are part of any coalitions or formally affiliated with
other groups. Almost all of the groups responded affirmatively to this answer, some with
multiple coalitions. I see three possible reasons for this. First, it may be that the question order
led groups to believe it was unnecessary to include coalition-building as a tactic since they had
already responded about affiliations and coalitions in an earlier question. Second, it could be that
many groups do not consider coalition-building a tactic. Lastly, if groups do consider it a tactic,
they may not consider it one of the top two or three tactics and thus not include it for that reason.
Group representatives were also asked whether they use different tactics at different
levels of government. Ten of the respondents said no, five said they do at least some tailoring of
tactics by level (one did not give a clear answer). Most of the representatives that said they did
not change tactics by level, did tailor tactics based on issue or campaign.
The organizational theory hypothesis (H7) that groups will rely on the same tactics over
time seems to be best supported, though not strongly supported. All groups still appear to rely on
traditional lobbying as the tactic of choice. In addition, many groups continue to rely on
grassroots mobilization. However, at least for citizen groups, how they mobilize the grassroots
has changed. Those groups frequently mentioned using newer forms of grassroots mobilization
(through social media, for example) that have sprung up in recent years. Two groups mentioned
having staff members whose roles are exclusively to update social media and communicate with
22
members through this social media. None of the industry groups interviewed mentioned using
social media as a tactic.
The neoinstitutional theory hypothesis, H5, posits that groups will use personal lobbying
and other expensive tactics at the level of government with the most jurisdiction. The results are
inconclusive for Canada and are not supported for this hypothesis in the United States. In
Canada, this would be the territorial level. Of the two Canadian groups interviewed, both listed
the territorial level in combination with one or more other levels of government. In the United
States, most jurisdiction is at the national level. None of the group respondents (who target more
than one level of government) stated that they are more likely to use lobbying at the national
level than the state level.
The similar rate of usage of grassroots mobilization by citizen groups and industry groups
(Figure 3) does not support the political opportunity structures theory that advocacy groups are
more likely to use grassroots mobilization than industry groups (H8). Additionally,
representatives of advocacy groups did not emphasize grassroots mobilization in their responses.
23
Figure 3: Tactics by Type of Group
12
10
8
Lobbying
6
Grassroots Mobilization
Coalition-building
4
2
0
Citizen Group (n=10)
Industry or Business Group (n=6)
For the elite theory hypothesis (H6), the aggregate data does show that industry groups
are slightly more likely to use lobbying, but not significantly more. Additionally, two industry
groups emphasized that lobbying is influential because of the personal relationships: “it's about
communication and relationship and you need to be able to establish a relationship with either a
federal legislator or a state legislator... it's all about building trust and relationships so that you
can forward what in your view is the best way forward for the industry or for the government”
(Moriarty, K. 2012, October 15. Telephone Interview). This is done both formally and “a lot of
informal conversations, and informal meetings and phone calls” (Buckner, K. 2013, March 22.
Telephone Interview). Both of these statements would fit the expectations of elite theory; that
industry groups would rely on relationships with decision-makers. Like many of the theories on
tactics, there were one or two comments that supported the hypothesis or some weak support in
the aggregate data, but no one theory explained the choice of tactics well.
24
One frequent response for the decision of which tactics to utilize was not covered well by
these hypotheses: variance by issue. A number of groups said that tactics depend on the issue, or
a similar expression, in describing how they made the decision of which tactic to use. When
asked to explain what this meant, group representatives often had a difficult time explaining how
and why it varied by issue. For some, it had more to do with the status of the legislation and the
stage in the process. For others it seemed to do more with the salience of the issue. As Adrian
Herrera explained, Arctic Power relies more heavily on lobbying than other tactics, but also
utilizes grassroots mobilization when an issue is particularly salient for the population: “you go
for the heart of the matter, operating outside the beltway when an issue is hot. That's when you
do that.” (2013, March 13. Telephone Interview). Conversely, the issue may not be salient for
legislators. David Gladders, of the Canadian Arctic Resources Committee, described their work
mapping caribou calving grounds and caribou movements in the arctic region and stated that
“you have to put this into perspective: we're dealing with caribou in terms of caribou
vulnerability, we would probably never talk to Stephen Harper” (2013, April 4. Telephone
Interview.). It may also have to do with the amount of resources they were willing to devote to a
particular issue. This seemed to be as much about how important the group saw the issue as how
many resources the group had.
CONCLUSIONS
What can be concluded from this research? No one theory was strongly supported for
both targeted level of government and choice of tactics, although organizational theory had weak
support for both. This is most likely because there are multiple factors influencing group
decision-making rather than just one or two factors. As noted above for tactics, one of those
reasons were not covered by any of the hypotheses.
25
The factors that seemed to have the most influence in choosing the level of government
to target were institutional features (level of centralization) and organizational capacity. Groups
appeared responsive to which level had jurisdiction over the issue with which they were
concerned, but were also cognizant of the capabilities of their organization. This implies that
federalism and institutions do matter, but are not the only variable that matters.
For choice of tactics, there are more variables that influenced the groups in this sample.
Institutions (level of centralization) did matter for some groups, as well as capacities (tactics
used traditionally). I did not find a lot of variation between industry and citizen groups; however,
only six industry groups were included in the sample so that may be a function of sample size
rather than a concrete result. A similar research design in a larger issue area with a larger sample
may be able to pinpoint which of these variables is more important or which variables are more
important for different types of groups.
APPENDIX A: LIST OF GROUPS INTERVIEWED
Interest Group
Alaska Oil and Gas Association
Country
United States
Type
Industry
Interview Method
Phone interview
Alaska State Chamber of Commerce United States
Industry
Phone interview
Alaska Support Industry Alliance
United States
Industry
Email interview
Alaska Wilderness League
United States
Conservation
Phone interview
Arctic Power
United States
Industry
Phone interview
Canadian Arctic Resources
Committee
Canada
Multi-issue
Phone interview
Canadian Association of Petroleum
Producers
Canada
Industry
Phone interview
Center for Biological Diversity
United States
Conservation
Phone interview
Defenders of Wildlife
United States
Conservation
Phone interview
League of Conservation Voters
United States
Conservation
Phone interview
National Audubon Society
United States
Conservation
Phone interview
Northern Alaska Environmental
United States
Environmental
Phone interview
26
Center
Ocean Conservancy
United States
Conservation
Phone interview
Oceana
International
Conservation
Phone interview
Resource Development Council
United States
Industry
Phone interview
Wilderness Society
United States
Conservation
Phone interview
27
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Andrews, K. T., & Edwards, B. (2004). Advocacy organizations in the U.S. political process.
Annual Review of Sociology 30, 479-506.
Bachrach, P., & Baratz, M. S. (1962). Two faces of power. APSR 56(4), 947-952.
Bartley, T., Andersson, K., Jagger, P., & Van Laerhoven, F. (2008). The contribution of
institutional theories to explaining decentralization of natural resource governance.”
Society and Natural Resources, 21(2), 160-174.
Bauer, R. A., Pool, I. S., & Dexter, L. A. (1963). American Business and Public Policy: The
Politics of Foreign Trade. Chicago, IL: Aldine Atherton.
Baumgartner, F. R., & Leech, B. L. (1998). Basic interests: The importance of groups in politics
and in political science. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Berry, J. M. (1977). Lobbying for the people: The political behavior of public interest groups.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Berry, J.M. (1989). The interest group society: 2nd Edition. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman, &
Little, Brown.
Berry, J. M. (1997). The interest group society (3rd Ed.) New York, NY: Longman.
Bond, M. (2007). Elite social relations and corporate political donations in Britain. Political
Studies 55, 59-85.
Bowman, A. O. (2002). American federalism on the horizon. Publius 32(2), 3-22.
Browne, W. P. (1998). Lobbying in the public: All-directional advocacy. In Cigler, A. J., &
Loomis, B. A. (Eds.). Interest group politics (pp. 343-63). Washington, DC: CQ Press.
Caldwell, L., & Bartlett, R. (Eds.). (1997). Environmental politics: Transnational issues and
national trends. Westport, CT.: Quorum Books.
Campbell, J. L. (2005). Where do we stand? Common mechanisms in organizations and social
movement research. In Davis, G. F., McAdam, D., Scott, W. R., & Zald, M. N. (Eds.).
Social movements and organization theory (pp 41-68). New York, NY: Cambridge
University Press.
Cigler, A. J., & Loomis, B. A. (Eds.). (1995). Interest group politics (4th Ed.) Washington DC:
CQ Press.
Dalton, R. J., Recchia, S., & Rohrschneider, R. (2003). The environmental movement and the
modes of political action. Comparative Political Studies 36, 743-771.
Doyle, T., & McEachern, D. (2001). Environment and politics (2nd Ed.). New York, NY:
Routledge.
Duffy, R. J. (2003). The green agenda in American politics: New strategies for the Twenty-first
Century. Kansas City, KS: University Press of Kansas.
Farazmand, A. (1999). The elite question: Toward a normative theory of organizational elite.
Administration and Society 31 (3), 321-360.
Goldstein, K. M. (1999). Interest groups, lobbying, and participation in America. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Gray, V., & Lowery, D. (1996). The population ecology of interest representation: Lobbying
communities in the American states. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
Graziano, L. (2001). Lobbying, pluralism, and democracy. New York, NY: Palgrave.
28
Hamm, K. E., & Hogan, R. E. (2004). Legislative lobbying: Placing research on legislative
lobbying in a comparative context. In C.S. Thomas (Ed.), Research Guide to U.S. and
International Interest Groups (pp.167-75). Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.
Heinz, J. P., Laumann, E. O., Nelson, R. L., & Salisbury, R. H. (1993). The hollow core: Private
interests in national policymaking. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Higley, J., & Pakulski, J. (2000). Epilogue: Elite theory versus Marxism: The twentieth century’s
verdict.” In Higley, J., and Lengyel, G. (Eds.). Elites after state socialism: Theories and
analysis (pp 229-242). New York: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc.
Hula, K. (1995). Rounding up the usual suspects: Forging interest group coalitions in
Washington. In Cigler, A. J., & Loomis, B. A. (Eds.). Interest group politics (4th Ed.) (pp.
55-76). Washington DC: CQ Press.
Inscho, F. R., & Durfee, M. H. (1995). The troubled renewal of the Canada-Ontario Agreement
respecting Great Lakes Water Quality. Publius, 25(1), 51-70.
Kelemen, R. D. (2004). The rules of federalism: Institutions and regulatory politics in the EU
and beyond. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Keman, Hans. 1998. “Public Institutions and Public Governance.” In Institutions and Political
Choice: On the Limits of Rationality. Amsterdam: VU University Press.
Kollman, K. (1998). Outside Lobbying. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Leech, B. L., & Baumgartner, F. R. (1998). Lobbying friends and foes in Washington. In Cigler,
A. J., & Loomis, B. A. (Eds.). Interest group politics (pp. 343-63). Washington, DC: CQ
Press.
Lipsky, M. (1968). Protest as a political resource. APSR 62, 1144-58.
McAdam, D. W., McCarthy, J. D., & Zald, M. N. (Eds.). (1996). Comparative perspectives on
social movements. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
McAdam, D. W., & Scott, R. (2005). Organizations and movements.” In Davis, G. F., McAdam,
D. W., Scott, R. W., & Zald, M. N. (Eds.). Social movements and organization theory (pp
4-40). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
McCarthy, J. D. (2005). Persistence and change among nationally federated social movements.
In Davis, G. F., McAdam, D., Scott, W. R., & Zald, M. N. (Eds.). Social Movements and
Organization Theory (pp.193-225). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Milbrath, L. W. (1963). The Washington lobbyists. Chicago, IL: Rand McNally.
Nownes, A. J., & Freeman, P. (1998). Interest group activity in the states. Journal of Politics 60:
86-112.
Peters, B. Guy. 2005. Institutional Theory in Political Science: The ‘New Institutionalism’, 2nd
Edition. New York: Continuum.
Pralle, S. (2006). Branching out, digging in: Environmental advocacy and agenda setting.
Washington D.C.: Georgetown University Press.
Presthus, R. (1973). Elite accommodation in Canadian politics. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge
University Press.
Pross, P. (Ed.). (1975). Pressure group behavior in Canadian politics. Toronto, ON: McGrawHill Ryerson.
Rabe, B. G. (2000). Power to the states; the promise and pitfalls of decentralization. In Vig, N.
J., & Kraft, M. E. (Eds.). Environmental Policy: 4th Edition (pp. 32-54). Washington DC:
CQ Press.
Riker, W. (1975). Federalism. In Greenstein, F., & Polsby, N. (Eds.). Handbook of Political
Science (pp 93-172). Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company.
29
Rochon, T. R., & Meyer, D. S. (1997). Coalitions and political movements. Boulder, CO: Lynne
Reinner.
Salisbury, R. H. (1992). Interests and institutions: Substance and structure in American politics.
Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Schlozman, K. L. , & Tierney, J. T. (1986). Organized interests and American democracy. New
York, NY: Harper and Row.
Schultz, R. J. (1980). Federalism, bureaucracy and public policy: The politics of highway
transport regulation. Montreal, QC: McGill-Queen’s University Press.
Shaffer, M. B. (1995). The internal dynamics of environmental organizations: Movement interest
groups, communal advocacy groups, and the policy process.” Policy Studies Review 14,
183-194.
Staggenborg, S. (1991). The pro-choice movement. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Tarrow, S. (1994). Power in movement: Collective action, social movements and politics.
Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Thomas, C. S. (Ed.). (2004). Research guide to U.S. and international interest groups. Westport,
CT: Praeger.
Walker, J. L., Jr. (1991). Mobilizing interest groups in America. Ann Arbor, MI: University of
Michigan Press.
Young, L., & Everitt, J. (2004). Advocacy Groups. Vancouver, BC: UBC Press.
Zeigler, L. H., & Baer, M. A. (1969). Lobbying: Interaction and influence in American state
legislatures. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.
30
Download