Microsoft Word - UWE Research Repository

advertisement
THE INCOMPATIBILITY OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT POLICIES FOR RURAL
AREAS IN ENGLAND.
Nigel Curry
Countryside and Community Research Institute,
Dunholme Villa,
The Park,
Cheltenham,
Gloucestershire,
GL50 2RH
T: 01202714126
E: ncurry2@glos.ac.uk
Submission to: localeconomy@lsbu.ac.uk
3,783 words without references
1|Page
THE INCOMPATIBILITY OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT POLICIES FOR RURAL
AREAS IN ENGLAND.
ABSTRACT
Four different and incommensurate economic development policies currently pertain in
rural England: the pursuit of productivity, well-being, endogenous development and
income support. This paper describes these policies as they pertained in 2007 in different
Government Departments and evaluates salient changes in Departmental positions in
respect of these policies since that time to the end of 2009. The impacts of these
policies, and their shifts, on rural areas are assessed.
1. Four rural economic development policies
Since at least the beginning of the Millennium in England, the Treasury, the (now)
Department of Business Innovation and Skills (BIS) 1, the Department of Communities
and Local Government and the Regional Development Agencies have been committed to
national policies of economic growth through improvements in productivity (Treasury et
al, 2006). A range of Departmental Pubic Service Agreements (PSAs) has determined
that this should be measured using Gross Value Added (GVA) per head, using output,
rather than income-based measures. The drivers here have been both to increase GVA
nationally and to reduce regional disparities, both of which have been considered to have
met with some success (Treasury et al., 2006).
This objective also pertained specifically in rural areas up until the end of 2007. The
Department for Environment and Rural Affairs (Defra) sought to reduce regional
disparities in GVA productivity by improving the performance of the rural parts of the
This is the third name for the ‘economy’ Government Department since June 2007 when it was the
Departmement of Trade and Industry. Its successor, the Department for Business, Enterprise and Regulatory
Reform lasted less than 2 years.
1
2|Page
weakest regions (Courtney et al., 2004) through the PSA 4 target (Defra, 2005). No
acknowledgement was made by Defra in these performance requirements, of differences
between rural and urban local authorities.
Quite separately, the same Government Departments have required local authorities,
under part one of the Local Government Act 2000 (Office for Public Sector Information,
2000) to pursue economic (and social and environmental) well-being for their areas
through the production of a community strategy. The economic element of this wellbeing should pursue ‘local prosperity’ (the Treasury and ODPM (2003), page 5) In
amplifying this, the 2006 Local Government White Paper (DCLG, 2006) committed to the
development of a single performance framework for local authorities, proposing that
they select up to 35 performance targets from a set of 198 National Indicators (only 33
of which pertain to the local economy (DCLG, 2007) and some 70 of which have no
available means of being measured (Commission for Rural Communities, 2010a) to
provide flexibility in determining the nature of well-being in their locality: well-being is
likely to be different in different rural areas. The Commission for Rural Communities
(2008) notes that, for rural areas this broadens the scope for interpreting economic
performance.
There is no clear relationship between these two notions of productivity and well-being.
Of the 198 National Indicators used to measure well being (DGLG, 2008a) none of them
includes any measure of productivity, and of the Treasury’s (2001) six drivers of
productivity: employment, skills, investment, innovation, entrepreneurship and
competition, only two are mentioned. NI 151 is the measure of the overall employment
rate in a local area, and NT 174 is concerned to reduce skills gaps in the current work
force as reported by employers. Essentially, productivity and well-being are not strongly
connected.
3|Page
In addition, specifically for rural areas, European rural policy (implemented through
Defra) has for some time made endogenous development a policy priority. The European
Integrated Rural Development Programmes of the late 1970s and early 1980s formalised
this approach by focusing on the unlocking of skills and the development of communities
and societies within the context of the local economy. This endogenous approach was
considered the most reasonable at the European level in the face of inherent rural
problems of remoteness and peripherality, agricultural dependence or pressures from
urbanisation. The approach was consolidated through the LEADER programmes (LEADER
I (1992) and II (1994)) and reasserted in the Cork Declaration of 1996. This declared,
rhetorically at least, the importance of participative, bottom-up approaches to rural
economic development, driven by the local community (Ray 2000).
Since this time, endogenous approaches have been the spine of the LEADER +
programmes (Shucksmith 2000) and from 2008, have been incorporated into the Rural
Development Programme for England (Pillar II of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP))
through Axis IV which applies the LEADER approach in support of the other three Axes,
particularly in relation to the developmental functions of Local Action Groups (Dwyer, et
al 2008). Importantly, this endogenous approach is finding favour in a number of rural
areas through movements such as the Carnegie Trust’s local asset-based development
(Carnegie Trust Rural programme, 2009), the Transition Towns Movement (Hopkins,
2008) and the Market Towns Movement (sponsored by DCLG) (Caffyn, 2004).
A fourth set of rural economic development measures is encapsulated in Pillar I of the
CAP (again implemented by Defra) which provides income support to farmers through
two means – simply giving them money (direct payments) or supporting the prices for
agricultural products at artificially high (above world market) prices (market subsidies).
This is, in effect, the converse of pursuing productivity objectives because such direct
and indirect subsidy actually discourages efficient production: it removes incentives to
modernise and innovate (South West Farming and Food, 2006). It is perhaps not
4|Page
surprising in this context that the value of agricultural subsidy has been greater than
total income derived from agriculture between 2004 and 2007, (figure 1) and the total
cost of the CAP to EU citizens is about €100 billion a year, half of which is borne by
taxpayers and half by consumers as a result of higher food prices OECD (2005).
Interestingly, in the context the full panoply of economic development policies for rural
areas, regional state financial support for agriculture (antithetic to productivity) is
approximately three times state financial support for productivity measures through the
Regional Development Agencies (Curry and Owen, 2009).
Figure 1 - agricultural support in England, post foot and mouth disease
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2,759
2,945
2,996
2,995
2,960
Total income from farming (£ million)
2,839
2,556
2,171
2,303
2,538
Agriculture’s contribution to the
0.8
0.7
0.5
0.5
0.5
Agricultural subsidy to farmers
(£ million)
economy (gross value added)
Source: http://statistics.defra.gov.uk/esg/publications/auk/default.asp
Although Pillar I support payments are set to decline to 2013 through a shift into Pillar II
support, they still comprised 88% of the total CAP budget in 2007 (Ward and Lowe
2007), and most of Pillar II anyway is set to remain in agriculture (Lowe and Ward,
2007).
5|Page
2. Productivity and Well-being: shifting priorities
Whilst endogenous and income support measures are continually adjusted through
successive reforms of the CAP (and for the former also by rural communities
themselves), the Treasury Sub-national Review of 2007, (Treasury et al., 2007) has had
a significant impact on priorities for productivity and well-being. Sometimes changes
here have been subtle and sometimes more wide-ranging but they have caused
increasing inconsistencies in economic development policies for rural areas, both
between and within Government Departments.
The Review affirmed that local authorities would ensure that local economic development
increases well-being in their localities (page 23), this time through a sustainable
community strategy or, for county and unitary authorities, their Local Area Agreements.
Such well-being should reflect the distinctive identity of the area (page 43), whilst
increasing local prosperity. RDAs would continue the pursuit of growth through GVA
productivity measures per head, but now though a single regional strategy, a specific
growth objective and a growth focussed framework (page 93).
In this context, Defra abandoned PSA 4 and indeed any specifically rural PSA targets,
and by 2008, had introduced a second order Departmental Strategic Objective (DSO) to
pursue ‘strong rural communities’ (Defra, 2008a). This is measured in turn by two
‘intermediate outcomes’ (IO) which reflect both the national preoccupation with
productivity and the local authority concern with well-being (Defra 2008b). The first was
(and remains) supporting economic growth in rural areas with the lowest levels of
performance and the second was to pursue the evidenced needs of rural people and
communities through mainstream public policy – measured through a selection of
National Indicators of well-being.
6|Page
This approach was roundly criticised by House of Commons Environment, Food and Rural
Affairs Committee (2008). Of the first IO, they felt (paragraph 30) that:
“focusing the economic intermediate outcome solely on low-performing areas is a wasted
opportunity”.
Of the second IO, they couldn’t see how it could be measured for individual rural areas.
Generally, they felt that the DSO overlooked the diversity of rural areas and anyway,
Defra did not have policy influence over the variables in the DSO and therefore couldn’t
readily influence it. The Committee also was not pleased with the relegation of rural
economic policy to a DSO from a PSA as it gave other government Departments the
opportunity to ignore it.
Potentially more significant for rural areas, however, the Review introduced the primacy
of economic planning at the sub-regional scale. This came about for at least four
reasons. Firstly, the way in which individual local authorities had dealt with economic
development had been extremely variable, with some smaller (mainly rural) authorities
showing little evidence of attention to this portfolio at all, or having insufficient capacity
to collect evidence on which to base economic development policies (DCLG and BERR,
2008). These problems could be overcome through sub-regional co-operation between
authorities.
Secondly, the sub-regional scale was felt by the Review to be the scale at which placespecific economic advantages are often present (for example, pools of labour, higher and
further education colleges, suppliers and so on), which provide place-specific returns to
scale (DCLG, 2008b). Thirdly, the relationship between ‘economics’ and ‘place’ needed to
be strengthened because ‘place’ was where productivity drivers come together and
where the life chances of individuals are played out (DCLG, 2008c). Finally, sub-regional
7|Page
arrangements, where they did exist, were considered to be fragmented, confused,
variable and lacking in capacity, accountability and leadership (Treasury et al., 2007).
The Sub-National Review (Treasury et al. 2007) thus proposed the development of subregional economic strategies through Multi-area Agreements (MAAs), first mooted in the
Local Government White Paper of 2006 (DCLG, 2006). These were to be voluntary at the
point of creation but, if local authorities so wished, they could establish statutory subregional authorities (DCLG and DBERR, 2008). These functional sub-regional areas were
not that easy to define, although the Local Government Association (2007) has
attempted this. The LGA work suggests, and the implication in much of the Sub-national
Review literature is, that these functional economic areas as sub-regions will cohere
around the notion of the city-region (OECD, 2006). This, too, has significant implications
for rural areas, as many rural districts are not even in a city region. By the end of 2009,
16 MAAs had been produced across England and all cohere around metropolitan or urban
areas(Morphet, 2009). As Morphet states: “ MAAs have been seen as an urban
approach” (page 12).
But further to complicate matters of appropriate scale, the Local Democracy, Economic
Development and Construction Act 2009 (Office of Public Sector Information, 2009) now
places a Statutory Duty on county and unitary authorities to undertake ‘economic
assessments’ which are to be used downstream in the Local Development Frameworks of
all authorities and upstream in sub-regional and regional strategies. Local authority
partnerships are encouraged for the purposes of this information collection because the
Act advocates that it should be collected for ‘functional areas’, which are considered to
be those defined by economic geography, rather than administration. The ‘economic
geography’ of rural areas remains to be defined. The sanction in the Act for not doing
this information collection is a much lower likelihood of economic development support
funding from the Homes and Communities Agency.
8|Page
The most recent economic development volte-face has come from the DCLG. The
Government’s new planning policies for prosperous economies were produced in May
2009 in a consultation paper on Planning Policy Statement (PPS) 4 (DCLG, 2009a). This
paper was built around using the spatial panning system to pursue two principal
objectives: increases in GVA productivity and increases in employment. Productivity was
considered substantively in 23 separate places in the paper. The paper was to base
national economic development policy on the premise that there were no spatial
differences in productivity in England, outside of London:
“rather than being the poor relation to urban areas in terms of productivity, rural areas
are in fact major contributors to the national economy on a par with all urban areas
outside of London. The evidence also shows clearly that there is no such thing as a
separate ‘rural economy’ – the economies in rural and urban areas are similar, in terms
of the mix of businesses and employment and are closely inter-related” (page 7, author’s
emphasis).
This was a curious foundation for spatial economic planning indeed. It made a nonsense
of Defra’s ‘lagging regions’ policy which was based on providing special support for the
44 most lagging (relative to other rural districts) rural districts in GVA productivity
terms. It also made a nonsense of the first of Defra’s IOs in their 2008 DSO about
reducing productivity disparities in rural areas. It also flew in the face of considerable
research evidence that charts differences in rural productivity by different types of
district authority (for example, Webber et al, 2009).
The report of the consultation exercise (DCLG, 2009b) omits any reference at all to
measures of productivity or their importance in influencing planning decisions, which is
curious, as the finally published PPS4 (DCLG, 2009c) has also removed reference to
productivity altogether, in respect of both its measurement and its influence over
planning decisions. Economic development in the new PPS4 will be determined not by its
9|Page
influence on productivity but (Policy E10) its ability to limit carbon emissions; minimise
climate change impacts; minimise traffic impacts; ensure good design, and have a
positive impact on regeneration, social inclusion and local employment. The PPS4 has
changed its title from ‘planning for prosperous economies’ to ‘planning for sustainable
growth’.
It is perhaps no coincidence that the Sustainable Development Commission published its
significant ‘no growth’ sustainable economies report (Jackson, 2009) in between the
consultation over PPS4 and its final form.
Again, this significant DCLG shift in emphasis of economic development policies away
from productivity begs further realignment: the objectives of economic development
agencies, particularly the Regional Development Agencies, still require the singular
pursuit of GVA productivity goals. Yet ‘new’ planning policies are unlikely to be
sympathetic to this precept. The new PPS4 also appears to promote a fifth economic
development goal to sit alongside those of productivity, well-being, endogenous
development and income support: sustainable economic growth. The Sustainable
Development Commission (Jackson, 2009) considers this term to be an oxymoron.
3. Shifting priorities and their implications for rural areas
The Sub-national Review (Treasury HM et al., 2007) has an overwhelming urban
orientation and does not acknowledge the particular characteristics of rural areas at all.
Thus, in setting out the context for the review:
“economic restructuring gives a key role to cities and towns ..... decision-making
structures therefore need to ensure that cities and towns have the necessary flexibility to
develop their own economic niches” (paragraph 4.6, page 48).
10 | P a g e
In developing sub-regional plans, partnerships between the private sector and local
authorities will be conducted through Urban Regeneration Companies who will conduct
city summits and generate city business cases and eventually develop into City
Development Companies (page 25 – authors’ italics). In determining functional economic
areas at the sub-regional level, “cities and towns are particularly important” (paragraph
4.13, page 49). The model planning framework, too, Multi-area Agreements (MAAs), is
based on precedents developed by a number of cities (Page 89) and the first MAAs were
to be in place for cities by June 2008 (page 90).
In acknowledging that functional economic areas are to be based around the city-region,
DCLG (2008b) nevertheless recognises that this runs the risk of residualising many rural
districts, because some 25% of them are not in any city-region (SQW and Cambridge
Econometrics, 2006). It maintains (DCLG 2008c) that many remoter areas are simply
too small to be encompassed by sub-regional economic systems. Smaller rural councils
and towns, it claims (DCLG, 2008a) are feeling particularly threatened by the city region
agenda. SQW and Cambridge Econometrics (2006) also note that the functionality of
city-regions appears to be premised primarily on car-based commuting. They question
the sustainability of this approach particularly as a number of recent Local Development
Frameworks, for example, have backed away from polices of dispersal, favouring
instead, polices of urban concentration This economic development focus on the city
region was of particular concern for Defra’s 44 the most lagging rural districts in case
studies conducted by Annibal and Doyle (2007).
Much of this concern about the residualisation of, particularly remoter, rural areas in
spatial economic policy stems from the particular GVA basis of measuring economic
performance that remains prevalent in some parts of government all of the time and
most parts of government some of the time. Not surprisingly, Annibal and Doyle’s
(2007) survey of Defra’s 44 most lagging districts, indicates that they themselves
favoured a broader approach to measuring such performance.
11 | P a g e
These calls for different performance measures for rural areas are buttressed by
research evidence. Keeble and Tyler (1995) in their studies, for example, found rural
firms to be overwhelmingly independent, locally owned and locally managed relative to
their urban counterparts. There also is evidence that they are both younger and smaller
than urban firms (Keeble and Nachum, 2002, Jarvis and Dunham, 2003) and that most
rural new firm founders are in-migrants to the area (Mitchell and Clark, 1999) rather
than, by contrast to urban firms, from within the locality in which the firm was founded.
But non-economic factors also have a strong influence on rural economic activity.
‘Quality of life’ factors have been noted as determinants of rural firm location since the
late 1950s (Greenhut, 1956) where lower returns were perceived to be more than
compensated for by pleasant environments and secure communities (Tiebout, 1957).
Pleasant rural environments have acted as a spur to relocate (North, 1998) and have
had an influence on levels of satisfaction in the workforce. (Johnson and Rasker, 1995).
Residential motivation, too, has influenced the location of economic activity where
villages are perceived as pleasant places to live (Courtney and Moseley, 2008).
This evidence would seem to suggest that many working in rural areas deliberately
choose to eschew productivity goals for more endogenous ones. Courtney et al. (2004),
for example undertook a series of qualitative surveys in ‘well performing’ and ‘poorer
performing’ district authorities (defined in GVA productivity terms) and found a number
of factors relating to the environmental and cultural quality of life to be perceived as
being significant in determining broader notions of economic performance. They can lead
to what Deakins et al. (2003) call lifestyle firms. In their study, they found, for example,
that 86% of their sample of small rural businesses actually did not want growth. As
Bryden et al. (2000), put it, rural development is something done by people rather than
to people.
12 | P a g e
In this context, Slee (2008) calls for a relocalisation of work, energy production, food
production and the use of leisure time. It is the pursuit of a number of these ‘nongrowth’ characteristics that is enjoying increasing popularity amongst rural communities
themselves - quintessentially sustainable development goals. Thus, ‘bottom up’
initiatives such as community land trusts (Countryside Agency, 2005), community
finance solutions (Dayson et al., 2008) alternative foods, local foods, farmers markets
and the like (Winter, 2003) are all naturally adopting Slee’s (2008) notions of
relocalisation on the ground. Transition towns in particular offer the pursuit of many of
what Richard Layard (2005) the economic pursuit of happiness in a movement that sits
largely outside of public policy but is gaining considerable momentum from the
‘community up’ (Hopkins, 2008).
4. Conclusions
It would seem that because of remoteness (Curry and Webber, 2010), the desire of rural
dwellers to pursue quality of life objectives and even because of the wishes of
communities themselves, many rural areas might more appropriately pursue well-being,
endogenous or even ‘sustainable growth’ objectives rather than those of productivity. It
is perhaps unfortunate in this context to classify England’s 44 most ‘lagging’ local
authority districts in productivity terms when they have some of the highest quality
environments in the country: prime assets for other forms of economic development. To
classify them as ‘lagging’ against productivity criteria when, since 2000 they have been
instructed to pursue well-being objectives is perhaps a little inappropriate.
But rather than deciding which kind of economic development policy is most appropriate
for rural areas, it is perhaps more pressing to seek greater clarity from within Central
Government over which kind of economic development policy is most appropriate at
different times in different rural places and at different spatial scales. Whilst DCLG has
abandoned productivity objectives in the new PPS4 in favour of ‘sustainable growth’
13 | P a g e
ones, the Treasury, BIS and the RDAs (HM Government, 2009) have reasserted the
primacy of productivity-driven growth as the fastest way out of recession. DCLG also is
the Government sponsor of the well-being objective and through a whole raft of
community empowerment initiatives (DCLG, 2008b, 2008c) also is seen to champion
endogenous development approaches. Defra severally champions all four: productivity
through its IO1; well-being through its IO2; endogenous development through Pillar 2 of
CAP and income support through Pillar 1. The Commission for Rural Communities
(2010b) appears to favour the well-being approach specifically for rural areas.
As for appropriate spatial scales, the raison d’etre of the Treasury et al’s (2007) sub
national review was, in championing the optimality of the sub-region, that the scale of
the region was too large for the planning of economic development and the scale of the
local authority was too small. Yet these are the two scales that have been given renewed
emphasis for the pursuit of productivity in the case of the RDAs (HM Government, 2009)
and for well-being in the case of local authorities. Indeed the well-being power has been
extended to an even smaller scale – the parish level – with the enactment, in April 2009,
of the Local Government and Public Involvement in Health Act 2007 (Commission for
Rural Communities, 2010b): a scale in the opposite direction to the Treasury’s notion of
sub-regional optimality.
The resultant confusion to a significant degree stems from the nationally-centralised
approach to policy formulation. Whilst policy is firmly generated and asserted at the
national level it is neither horizontally nor vertically integrated. Thus at the national level
there is no horizontal integration of policy between all government departments with a
responsibility of economic development and for some, even within departments. From
the national level, there is then no vertical integration between national departments,
regions, sub regions, local authorities and now, even parishes: each scale of devolution
has a different set of objectives.
14 | P a g e
Whilst these differences might appear mere technicalities to some, they are operationally
problematic, particularly at the local authority level where principal accountability for the
delivery of many policies lies. At this level, it is often hard to understand what priorities
should be in pursuit of economic success, even harder to know when or whether they
have been achieved, and with whom they are to work in partnership in the whole
process of economic development.
References
Annibal I P and Boyle P (2007) Productivity and Place: Economic Performance in Remote
Areas. Local Government Analysis and Research. Local Government Association
September, London.
Bryden J, Atterton J, Courtney P, Hart K Munro G Timm A (2000) Differential Economic
Performance in Rural Areas, International Conference on European Rural Policy at the
Crossroads. University of Aberdeen, Kings College: The Arkleton Centre for Rural
Development Research. June 29-July 1 2000.
Caffyn A (2004) Market Town Regeneration; Challenges for Policy and Implementation
Local Economy, 19(1) 8–24, February.
Carnegie Trust Rural Programme (2009) A manifesto for rural communities: inspiring
community innovation, the Carnegie Trust, Dunfermline, October.
Commission for Rural Communities. (2008). State of the Countryside Report.
Commission for Rural Communities: Cheltenham.
Commission for Rural Communities (2010a) Seminar on Economic Well-being, 18,
January, Birmingham.
15 | P a g e
Commission for Rural Communities (2010b) Understanding Economic Well-being, CCP
109, the Commission, Cheltenham, January
Countryside Agency (2005). The State of the Countryside 2004. Countryside Agency:
Cheltenham.
Courtney P and Moseley M (2008) Determinants of local economic performance:
experience from rural England. Local Economy, 23(4) 305 - 318
Courtney P., Agarwal S., Errington A., Moseley M. and Rahman, S. (2004) Determinants
of Relative Economic Performance of Rural Areas, Final Research Report Prepared for
DEFRA, July, University of Plymouth and Countryside and Community Research Unit.
Curry NR and Owen S (2009) Rural Planning In England: A Critique of Current Policy
Town Planning Review, 80 (6), 575 – 596
Curry NR and Webber DJ (2010) Economic Performance in Rural England. Regional
Studies, in press.
Dayson K., Paterson B., Salt A. and P. Vik (2008) Lloyds TSB operational sustainability
research project – final technical report, Community Finance Solutions, University of
Salford, February.
Deakins, D., Galloway, L. & Mochrie, R. (2003) The Use and Effect of ICT on Scotland's
Rural Business Community. Research Report for Scottish Economists’ Network
Department for Communities and Local Government (2006) Strong and prosperous
communities - the local government white paper, DCLG, London, October, Cm 6939-1
16 | P a g e
Department for Communities and Local Government (2007) The New Performance
Framework for Local Authorities and Local Authority Partnerships: Single Set of National
Indicators, October, London.
Department for Communities and Local Government (2008a) National Indicators for
Local Authorities and Local Authority Partnerships: Handbook of Definitions. April, DCLG,
London.
Department for Communities and Local Government (2008b) Communities in control:
real people, real power, DCLG, London
Department for Communities and Local Government (2008c), Creating Strong, Safe and
Prosperous Communities: Statutory Guidance, DCLG, London, July.
Department for Communities and Local Government (2009a) Consultation paper on a
new Planning Policy Statement 4: Planning for Prosperous Economies, May, DCLG,
London.
Department for Communities and Local Government (2009b), Draft Planning Policy
Statement 4: Planning for prosperous economies (PPS4) - Summary of public
consultation responses, December, DCLG, London.
Department for Communities And Local Government (2009c), Draft Planning Policy
Statement 4: Planning for sustainable economic growth (PPS4) December, DCLG,
Department of Communities and Local Government and the Department for Business
Enterprise and Regulatory Reform (2008) Prosperous Places: Taking Forward the Review
of Sub-national Economic Development and Regeneration, DCLG and DBERR, 31 March.
17 | P a g e
Department for the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (Defra) (2005) Defra
classification of local authority districts and unitary authorities in England: An
Introductory Guide, Defra: London, July.
Department of the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (2008a) Comprehensive
Spending Review 2007 - Performance Framework, Defra, London.
Department of the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (2008b) Departmental Strategic
Outcomes and their Intermediate Indicators,
http://www.defra.gov.uk/corporate/busplan/spending-review/pdf/dso-io-indicatorsrevfeb08.pdf
Dwyer, J, Mantino, F, Schiller, S, Baldock, D, Farmer, M, Knickel, K, Prazan, J,
Trantinova, M, Lewis, N, Thomson, K, Kambites, C, Kirwan, J, Tarangioli, S, Monteleone,
A, Bolli, M, Clark, M, Bradley, D, Bartley, J, Hart, K, Keenleyside, C, Fagiani, P, Storti, D,
Molnarova, A. (2008) Review of Rural Development Instruments: DG Agri project 2006G4-10. Final Report July 2008. European Commission (at
http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/analysis/external/rurdev/index_en.htm )
from the English Experience Sustainable Development Vol 15, pp 307–317
Greenhut M. L. (1956) Plant Location in Theory and Practice. University of North Carolina
Press.
HM Government (2009) New industry, new jobs: building Britain’s future, April.
Hopkins R (2008) The transition handbook: from oil dependency to local resilience,
Green Books, Totnes
18 | P a g e
House of Commons Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Committee (2008) The potential
of England’s rural economy Eleventh Report of Session 2007–08, London: The Stationery
Office Limited, 29 October.
Jackson T (2009) Prosperity without growth: the transition to a sustainable economy
Sustainable Development Commission, London.
Jarvis D and Dunham P(2003) Conceptualising the 'competitive' strategies of rural
manufacturing SMEs. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie 94(2), 246–257.
Johnson J D and Rasker R (1995) The role of economic and quality of life values in rural
business location Journal of Rural Studies 11. 405 – 416.
Keeble D and Tyler P (1995) Enterprising Behaviour and the Urban-Rural Shift Urban
Studies, 32(6) 975-997
Keeble D, Nachum L, 2002, "Why do business service firms cluster? Small consultancies,
clustering and decentralization in London and Southern England" Transactions of the
Institute of British Geographers, New Series 27 67 – 90
Layard, R., (2005), Happiness: lessons from a new science, Penguin; Harmondsworth
Local Government Association (2007) Prosperous Communities II: Vive La Devolution,
LGA, January.
Lowe P and Ward N (2007), Sustainable Rural Economies: Some Lessons
19 | P a g e
Mitchell S and Clark D. (1999). Business adoption of information and communications
technologies in the two-tier rural economy: some evidence from the South Midlands.
Journal of Rural Studies 15: 447–455.
Morphet (2009) Sub-regions to offer alternatives, Planning, December.
North, D. (1998), Rural Industrialisation. In: B. Ilbery, ed., The Geography of Rural
Change, pp. 161–188. Harlow: Longman
OECD (2005), ‘Agricultural Policies in OECD Countries: Monitoring and Evaluation 2005’,
Paris
OECD (2006) The New Rural Paradigm: Policies and Governance. OECD: Paris.
Office of Public Sector Information (2000) Local Government Act, 2000, Chapter 22,
OPSI, London.
Office of Public Sector Information, (2009) Local Democracy, Economic Development and
Construction Act 2009, Chapter 20, OPSI, London.
Ray, C. (2000) The EU LEADER programme: rural development laboratory. Sociologia
Ruralis 40 (2) pp. 163–171
Segal Quince Wicksteed & Cambridge Econometrics (2006) Economic Performance of
Rural Areas Inside and Outside of City Regions. Final report to Defra, September.
Shucksmith, M. (2000) Endogenous development, social capital and social inclusion:
perspectives from LEADER in the UK. Sociologia Ruralis 40 (2) pp. 208–218
20 | P a g e
Slee RW (2008) Sustainable solutions: dreams, dilemmas, dangers, Rural Futures
Conference, Rural future, Dreams, Dilemmas, Dangers, University of Plymouth, UK,
April.
South West Farming and Food (2006) Farming and Food Strategy, South West Regional
Development Agency, Exeter.
Tiebout C. M. (1957) Location theory, empirical evidence, and economic evolution, Pap.
Reg. Sci. Ass. 3, 7446.
Treasury, HM. (2001) Productivity in the United Kingdom: 3 – The Regional Dimension,
HM Treasury, London
Treasury HM and the Office of the Deputy Prime Minister (2003) Productivity in the UK 4:
the local dimension, June
Treasury HM, Department for Business, Enterprise and Regulatory Reform and
Department for Communities and Local Government (2007) Review of sub-national
economic development and regeneration PU300, London, July ISBN 978-1-84532-317-2
Treasury HM, Department of Trade and Industry and the Department of Communities
and Local Government (2006) Regional Economic Performance Progress to date, London,
December.
Ward N and Lowe P (2007) Blairite Modernisation and Countryside Policy. The Political
Quarterly, Vol. 78, No. 3, July-September.
Webber DJ, Curry NR and A Plumridge (2009) Business Productivity and Area
Productivity in Rural England, Regional Studies, 43(5), 661 – 675.
21 | P a g e
Winter, M. (2003) Embeddedness, the new food economy and defensive localism.
Journal of Rural Studies 19 (1) pp. 23 – 32
22 | P a g e
Download