A Small Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Economy of Kazakhstan Bulat Mukhamediyev Al-Farabi Kazakh National University The oil price dynamics has a significant impact on economic development of both oil-importing and oil exporting countries. In recent years the price of oil has risen above $ 100 a barrel and remains above this level even in the face of the continuing economic crisis caused by the economic slowdown in developed countries. The increase of oil prices in a developed economy puts pressure on domestic prices due to rising production costs and loss of productivity. And for an oil producing country contraction of economic activity in partner countries leads to a reduction in demand for hydrocarbons and a decrease of income countries that export resources. But even in favorable conditions for the country providing oil to the world market, there is a risk of Dutch disease and uncontrolled growth of domestic prices for goods and services due to excessive oil revenues. In Kazakhstan after the global economic crisis favorable period from 2000 to 2007with high GDP growth rates was replaced by a period of moderate growth. According to estimates of monetary policy rules, performed by the author, the National Bank of Kazakhstan concentrated its focus on inflation targeting after the surge of prices up to 18.7 percent in 2008 and on stabilization of the exchange rate. In this article an analysis of the different options of monetary policy for a small model of the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium was performed. The model estimation results reveal that an increase of the share of oil revenues allocated to current consumption has a debilitating effect on the consequences from shocks on oil price and global oil demand rise to economic indicators of the country. Model A small model of the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium in an open economy which is based on the standard model of an open economy and its development and takes into account the specific characteristics of the economy of Kazakhstan is presented. The structure of the model corresponds to an approach developed in the work of Gali & Monacelli (2005) , Gunter (2009), Obstfeld & Rogoff (2001), Silveira (2006) and is based on their proposed designs. The model takes into account the specific features associated with oil production, accumulation and use of oil revenues in the economy of Kazakhstan. Domestic Households It will be convenient to start a description with a presentation of a model of two countries. It is assumed that all households in each country have identical preferences and have equal conditions. In the country named Home (H) a continuum of households indexed as j ∈ [0, n) resides. And in another country named Foreign (F), j ∈ [n, 1] households inhabit. The so-called new model of a small open economy can be considered as a limit case of the model of two countries when n tends to zero. Each household is an owner of monopolistically competitive firm that produces a diversified commodity i ∈ [0, n) in the country H or a commodity i ∈ [n, 1] in the country F. It is assumed that the law of one price for all goods is in place, and all goods are traded. A representative household seeks to maximize the utility function 饾憽 ∑∞ 饾憽=0 饾浗 饾惛0 { 饾憲 饾憼饾憲 1+饾湋 饾憲 (饾惗饾憽 − 饾渹饾惗饾憽−1 )1−饾湈 1−饾湈 − 饾憗饾憽 1+饾湋 }, (1) under the sequence of budget constraints 饾憙饾憽 饾惗饾憽 + 饾惛饾憽 [饾憚饾憽,饾憽+1 饾惙饾憽+1 ] ≤ 饾惙饾憽 + 饾憡饾憽 饾憗饾憽 + 饾憞饾憽 , (2) 饾憼饾憲 where φ, φ> 1, is the inverse of the wage elasticity of the labor supply 饾憗饾憽 and σ, σ > 0, is the 饾憲 inverse of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution of consumption 饾惗饾憽 , 饾惙饾憽+1 – nominal payments for a securities portfolio at the end of period t, 饾憚饾憽,饾憽+1 − a stochastic discount factor for nominal payments for a period ahead to a household in the country. Coefficient β is an intertemporal discount factor, 0 < β < 1, 饾憡饾憽 饾憲 - wages, and term 饾渹饾惗饾憽−1 is an external habit formation. A solution to the optimization problem of the household gives the first order condition in the aggregated form: 饾憙饾憽 (饾惗饾憽 − 饾渹饾惗饾憽−1 )−饾湈 = 饾浗 (饾憙 饾憽+1 ) (饾惗饾憽+1 − 饾渹饾惗饾憽 )−饾湈 , 饾渹 饾憗饾憽 (饾惗饾憽 − 饾渹饾惗饾憽−1 )−饾湈 = 饾憡饾憽 饾憙饾憽 (3) . (4) The following notation will clarify the remaining variables. The composite index of consumption 1 饾憲 1−饾浛 1 饾憲 1 饾浛 饾憲 1−饾浛 ]饾浛−1 1 饾惗饾憽 = [(1 − 饾浖)饾浛 饾惗饾惢,饾憽 + 饾浖 饾浛 饾惗饾惞,饾憽 is determined on the basis of the consumption index 1 饾憲 1 饾渶 饾憶 1 1− 饾渶 饾憲 饾惗饾惢,饾憽 = [(饾憶) ∫0 饾惗饾惢,饾憽 (饾憱) 1 饾憲 1 饾渶 饾憶 饾渶 饾渶−1 饾憫饾憱] 1 1− 饾渶 饾憲 饾惗饾惞,饾憽 = [(1−饾憶) ∫0 饾惗饾惞,饾憽 (饾憱) , (5) 饾渶 饾渶−1 饾憫饾憱] (6) 饾憲 饾憲 of domestic and foreign goods, respectively and the values 饾惗饾惢,饾憽 (饾憱) for 饾憱 ∈ [0, 饾憶) and 饾惗饾惞,饾憽 (饾憱) for 饾憱 ∈ [饾憶, 1] as well represent consumption levels of domestic and foreign goods, respectively. Here ε is the elasticity of intratemporal substitution among goods produced in a same country, ε> 0. And δ is the elasticity of intratemporal substitution between a bundle of Home goods and a bundle of Foreign goods. The value α determines the share of imported goods in the domestic consumption of the household. Similar formulas hold for the country F. The solution to the optimization problem of minimization 饾憶 饾憲 ∫ 饾憙饾惢,饾憽 (饾憱)饾惗饾惢,饾憽 (饾憱)饾憫饾憱 0 饾憲 for 饾惗饾惢,饾憽 (饾憱) under the constraint (5) and the minimization problem 饾憶 饾憲 ∫ 饾憙饾惢,饾憽 (饾憱)饾惗饾惢,饾憽 (饾憱)饾憫饾憱 0 under the constraint (6), where 1 饾憙饾惢,饾憽 = 饾憶 1−饾渶 (饾憶 ∫0 饾憙饾惢,饾憽 (饾憱)1−饾渶 饾憫饾憱 ) 1 1 , 饾憙饾惞,饾憽 = 1 1−饾渶 (1−饾憶 ∫饾憶 饾憙饾惞,饾憽 (饾憱)1−饾渶 饾憫饾憱 ) 1 , provides the optimal allocation of consumption between domestic and foreign goods: 饾憙饾惢,饾憽 −饾浛 饾憲 小饾惢,饾憽 = (1 − 饾浖) ( 饾憙饾憽 ) 饾憲 饾憙饾惞,饾憽 −饾浛 饾憲 饾惗饾憽 , 小饾惞,饾憽 = 饾浖 ( ) 饾憙饾憽 饾憲 饾惗饾憽 . Here 饾憙饾憽 is an index of consumer prices in the country H: 1 1−饾浛 1−饾浛 1−饾浛 饾憙饾憽 = [(1 − 饾浖)饾惗饾惢,饾憽 + 饾浖饾惗饾惞,饾憽 ] . Also, we have the formulas for the consumer price indices of domestic and foreign goods: 饾憙饾惢,饾憽 −饾浛 小饾惢,饾憽 (1 − 饾浖) ( 饾憙饾憽 ) 饾惗饾憽 , 小饾惞,饾憽 饾浖 ( 饾憙饾惞,饾憽 −饾浛 饾憙饾憽 ) 饾惗饾憽 . All similar formulas hold for the country F. For it all variables are marked with a superscript (*). Given the existence of a representative agent in each economy and the condition (4), we can present the function of aggregate labor supply for both countries: 饾憗饾憽饾憼 饾憗饾憽∗饾憼 = = 饾憶 饾憼饾憲 ∫0 饾憗饾憽 饾憫饾憲 饾憶 ∗饾憼饾憲 ∫0 饾憗饾憽 饾憫饾憲 1+ = 饾憶 饾湈 饾湋 1 饾憡 饾湋 ( 饾憽) 饾憙饾憽 1+ = (1 − 饾憶) 饾湈 饾湋 − 饾惗饾憽 饾湈 饾湋 , 1 饾憡饾憽∗ 饾湋 ( 饾憙∗ ) 饾惗饾憽∗ − (7) 饾湈 饾湋 . (8) 饾憽 Firms There is a continuum of firms i ∈ [0, n) producing a variety of final goods, using labor 饾憗饾憽饾憱 and oil 饾憘饾憽饾憱 . They apply identical technologies 饾憣饾惢,饾憽 (饾憱) = 饾惔饾憽 min{饾憗饾憽饾憱 , 1 饾渷 饾憘饾憽饾憱 }, (9) i.e. expend labor and oil in fixed proportions. Parameter 饾惔饾憽 stands for the total factor productivity. Its dynamics is described by first-order autoregressive process AR (1): 饾憴饾憶饾惔饾憽 = 饾湆饾惔 饾憴饾憶饾惔饾憽−1 + 饾渶饾惔,饾憽 , where 饾湆饾惔 ∈ [0,1), and the random variable 饾渶饾惔,饾憽 is independently and identically distributed with a zero mean and a final standard deviation 饾湈饾惔 . Since in reality a firm will not spend excessive amounts of resources, we can assume that the condition of conformity of oil used by the quantity of labor: 饾憘饾憽 = ζ饾憗饾憽 . Oil Sector In the Home country there is a firm producing oil. Part of the oil 饾憘饾憽 is consumed by domestic firms for the production of final goods, and the rest 饾憘饾憽∗ goes abroad to foreign producers. Oil producing firm takes the price of oil 饾憙饾憽饾憘 and wage rate 饾憡饾憽 as given. The volume of oil 饾憘饾憽饾憜 is determined by the amount of labor used 饾憗饾憽饾憘 . The firm maximizes its profits in each period: 饾憵饾憥饾懃[饾憙饾憽饾憘 饾憘饾憽饾憜 − 饾憡饾憽 饾憗饾憽饾憘 ] 饾湀 under constraint 饾憘饾憽饾憜 = 饾憤饾憽 饾憗饾憽饾憘 , (12) where the parameter 0 <ν <1, which reflects the diminishing returns to labor in the production technology of oil. A factor 饾憤饾憽 determines the performance, and changes in accordance with the process of autoregression 饾憴饾憶饾憤饾憽 = 饾湆饾憤 饾憴饾憶饾憤饾憽−1 + 饾渶饾憤,饾憽 , where 饾湆饾憤 ∈ [0,1), and the random variable 饾渶饾憤,饾憽 are independently and identically distributed with a zero mean and a final standard deviation 饾湈饾憤 . By substituting 饾憘饾憽饾憜 from condition (12) into the profit function and by differentiating it by 饾憗饾憽饾憘 we obtain the first order condition for the oil producing firm’s problem ν饾憤饾憽 饾憙饾憽饾憘 饾憗饾憽饾憘 饾湀−1 = 饾憡饾憽 . (13) Equilibrium In the model of markets of final goods, labor and oil are presented. In equilibrium at each of them clearing should take place, i.e. the supply must be equal to the demand: ∗ 饾憣饾惢,饾憽 = 饾惗饾惢,饾憽 + 饾惗饾惢,饾憽 , (14) 饾憗饾憽饾憼 = 饾憗饾憽饾憘 + 饾憗饾憽 , (15) 饾憘饾憽饾憜 = 饾憘饾憽 + 饾憘饾憽∗ . (16) Here, the demand for labor by firms producing final goods 饾憗饾憽 as well as the demand for oil 饾憘饾憽 is determined by summing over all firms. We also use the international risk sharing condition 饾惗饾憽 = 1⁄ 饾憶 1−饾憶 饾湕饾憚饾憽 饾湈 饾惗饾憽∗ (17) Log-linearization of this equation around the steady state at 饾湕 = 1 gives the equation: 饾憶 饾憪饾憽 = 饾憴饾憶 (1−饾憶) + 1 饾湈 饾憺饾憽 + 饾憪饾憽∗ . Here with small letters except n deviations of the logarithms of the corresponding variables in the logarithms of these variables in a stable condition are marked. So 饾懃 = 饾憴饾憶饾憢饾憽 − 饾憴饾憶饾憢 for any variable X, but for rate of inflation 饾湅饾憽 = 饾憴饾憶饾憙饾憽 − 饾憴饾憶饾憙 , where X, P are values of corresponding variables in steady state. According to the approach of Calvo (1983) it is considered that each firm producing final goods, sets a new price for the goods in period t with a probability 1-ξ and retains the same price with a probability ξ. The new price of the company is determined by solving the maximization problem: 饾憳 虆 ∑∞ 饾憳=0 饾湁 饾惛饾憽 [饾憚饾憽,饾憽+饾憳 饾憣饾惢,饾憽+饾憳 (饾憲)(饾憙饾惢,饾憽 (饾憲) − 饾憖饾惗饾憽+饾憳 )] (18) by 饾憙虆饾惢,饾憽 (饾憲) under the constraints 饾憣饾惢,饾憽+饾憳 (饾憲) = ( −饾浛 饾憙虆饾惢,饾憽+饾憳 (饾憲) 饾憙饾惢,饾憽+饾憳 ) ∗ (饾惗饾惢,饾憽+饾憳 + 饾惗饾惢,饾憽+饾憳 ) (19) For the model of optimal pricing in the article Gali & Monacelli (2005), the following formula was received 饾湅饾惢,饾憽 = 饾浗饾惛饾憽 [饾湅饾惢,饾憽+1 ] + 饾渾饾憵饾憪 虃饾憽 , where 饾憵饾憪 虃 饾憽 is the deviation of real marginal cost from its steady state, and the parameter 饾渾 = 1−饾浛 饾浛 (1 − 饾浗饾浛). Without oil production costs marginal costs of firms producing final goods are the following: 饾憖饾惗饾憽 = 饾憡饾憽 (20) 饾惔饾憽 饾憙饾憽 After log-linearization around the steady state 饾憵饾憪 虃 饾憽 can be written as 饾憵饾憪 虃 饾憽 = (饾湋 + 饾湈)饾懄饾憽 − (饾湐 − 1)饾憼饾憽 . (21) Taking into account the production costs for the use of oil by firms producing final goods, then (20) is changed to the following: 饾憖饾惗饾憽 = 饾憡饾憽 + 饾渷饾憙饾憽饾憘 (22) 饾惔饾憽 饾憙饾憽 Accordingly, the process of log linearization around a steady state instead of (22) leads to the relationship 饾憵饾憪 虃 饾憽 = (饾湋 + 饾湈)饾懄饾憽 − (饾湐 − 1)饾憼饾憽 + 饾渷(饾憹饾憽饾憘 − 饾憹饾憽 ). (23) With this clarification, associated with the use of oil revenues, New Keynesian Phillips Curve is written as 饾湅饾惢,饾憽 = 饾浗饾惛饾憽 [饾湅饾惢,饾憽+1 ] + 饾渾(饾湋 + 饾湈)饾懄饾憽 + 饾渾(1 − 饾湐)饾憼饾憽 + 饾渾饾渷(饾憹饾憽饾憘 − 饾憹饾憽 ). Revenue from the sale of oil abroad is 饾憙饾憽饾憘 饾憘饾憽∗ , and in real terms is 饾憙饾憽饾憘 饾憘饾憽∗ 饾憙饾憽 (24) . However, not the entire oil revenues can be used for current consumption, but only part of it. The rest of revenues is accumulated in the National Fund (a sovereign wealth fund). Let κ be the share of oil revenues used for current consumption. This is equivalent to the current real income of the country with the use of oil revenues on consumption is equal to 饾憣饾憽 + κ 饾憙饾憽饾憘 饾憘饾憽∗ 饾憙饾憽 . (25) After log-linearization around the steady state (25) can be rewritten to 饾懄饾憽 + (饾憹饾憽饾憘 + 饾憸饾憽∗ − 饾憹饾憽 ) = 饾憪饾憽 + 饾湐−1 饾湈 饾憼饾憽 . (26) Taking into account equation (26) log-linearized equation of equilibrium on the market of goods is reduced to 饾憘 ∗ ] 饾懄饾憽 = 饾惛饾憽 [饾懄饾憽+1 ] + 饾惛饾憽 [饾洢(饾憹饾憽+1 − 饾憹饾憽+1 )] + 饾惛饾憽 [饾洢饾憸饾憽+1 − 饾湐−1 饾湈 饾惛饾憽 [饾憼饾憽+1 ] − 1 饾湈 (饾憻饾憽 − 饾惛饾憽 [饾湅饾憽+1 ] + + 饾憴饾憶饾浗) + (1 − 饾渽)(饾憹饾憽饾憘 + 饾憸饾憽∗ − 饾憹饾憽 ). (27) It is assumed that the monetary policy of central banks in the country and abroad follows the Taylor rules: 饾憻饾憽 = 饾浛饾湅 饾湅饾憽 + 饾浛饾懄 饾懄饾憽 + 饾渶饾憖,饾憽 , (28) ∗ 饾憻饾憽∗ = 饾浛饾湅∗ 饾湅饾憽∗ + 饾浛饾懄∗ 饾懄饾憽∗ + 饾渶饾憖,饾憽 , (29) ∗ where each of the stochastic processes 饾渶饾憖,饾憽 and 饾渶饾憖,饾憽 represents a white noise. Log-liner system 饾懁饾憽 − 饾憹饾憽 = 饾湋饾憶饾憽饾憜 + 饾湈 饾憪 1−饾渹 饾憽 − 饾渹饾湈 饾憪 1−饾渹 饾憽−1 , 饾憸饾憽饾憜 = 饾懅饾憽 + 饾湀饾憶饾憽饾憘 , 饾懄饾憽 + (饾憹饾憽饾憘 + 饾憸饾憽∗ − 饾憹饾憽 ) = 饾憪饾憽 + 饾湐−1 饾湈 饾憼饾憽 , 饾湅饾惢,饾憽 = 饾浗饾惛饾憽 [饾湅饾惢,饾憽+1 ] + 饾渾(饾湋 + 饾湈)饾懄饾憽 + 饾渾(1 − 饾湐)饾憼饾憽 , 饾憘 ∗ ] 饾懄饾憽 = 饾惛饾憽 [饾懄饾憽+1 ] + 饾惛饾憽 [饾洢(饾憹饾憽+1 − 饾憹饾憽+1 )] + 饾惛饾憽 [饾洢饾憸饾憽+1 − 饾湐−1 饾湈 + 饾憴饾憶饾浗) + (1 − 饾渽)(饾憹饾憽饾憘 + 饾憸饾憽∗ − 饾憹饾憽 ) , 饾憻饾憽饾憭 = (1 − 饾渻) 饾湈(1+饾湋)(饾湆−1) 饾湋+饾湈 饾憥饾憽 + 饾渻 饾湈(1+饾湋)(饾湆∗ −1) 饾湋+饾湈 饾憻饾憽 = 饾浛饾湅 饾湅饾憽 + 饾浛饾懄 饾懄饾憽 + 饾渶饾憖,饾憽 , ∗ ] 饾湅饾憽∗ = 饾浗饾惛饾憽 [饾湅饾憽+1 + 饾渾(饾湋 + 饾湈)饾懄饾憽∗ , ∗ ] 饾懄饾憽∗ = 饾惛饾憽 [饾懄饾憽+1 − 饾憻饾憽∗饾憭 = 1 饾湈 ∗ ] (饾憻饾憽∗ − 饾惛饾憽 [饾湅饾憽+1 − 饾憻饾憽∗饾憭 ) , 饾湈(1+饾湋)(饾湆∗ −1) 饾湋+饾湈 饾憥饾憽∗ − 饾憴饾憶饾浗 , ∗ 饾憻饾憽∗ = 饾浛饾湅∗ 饾湅饾憽∗ + 饾浛饾懄∗ 饾懄饾憽∗ + 饾渶饾憖,饾憽 , 饾憼饾憽 = 饾湈 饾湐 (饾懄饾憽 − 饾懄饾憽∗ ) , 饾懁饾憽 − 饾憹饾憽 = 饾懅饾憽 + 饾憹饾憽饾憘 − 饾憹饾憽 + (饾湀 − 1)饾憶饾憽饾憘 , 饾憸饾憽 = 饾懄饾憽 − 饾憥饾憽 , 饾憶饾憽 = 饾憘 饾憸 饾渷饾憗 饾憽 饾憶饾憽饾憜 = 饾憗饾憜 饾憗 , 饾憗 饾憶饾憽 + (1 − 饾憗饾憜 )饾憶饾憽饾憘 , 饾憥饾憽∗ − 饾憴饾憶饾浗 , 饾惛饾憽 [饾憼饾憽+1 ] − 1 饾湈 (饾憻饾憽 − 饾惛饾憽 [饾湅饾憽+1 ] + 饾憘 饾憸饾憽饾憜 = 饾憘饾憜 饾憘 饾憸饾憽 + (1 − 饾憘饾憜 )饾憸饾憽∗ , 饾憘 饾憹饾憽饾憘 − 饾憹饾憽 = 饾湆饾憹饾憸 (饾憹饾憽−1 − 饾憹饾憽−1 ) + 饾渶饾憹饾憸,饾憽 , ∗ 饾憸饾憽∗ = 饾湆饾憸∗ 饾憸饾憽−1 + 饾渶饾憸∗,饾憽 , ∗ 饾憥饾憽∗ = 饾湆饾憥∗ 饾憥饾憽−1 + 饾渶饾憥∗,饾憽 , 饾憥饾憽 = 饾湆饾憥 饾憥饾憽−1 + 饾渶饾憥,饾憽 , 饾懅饾憽 = 饾湆饾懅 饾懅饾憽−1 + 饾渶饾懅,饾憽 . Here we use the following notations 饾渾= 1−饾浛 饾浛 (1 − 饾浗饾浛), 饾湐 = 1 + 饾浖虆(2 − 饾浖)(饾湈饾浛 − 1), 饾渻 = 饾湋(饾湐−1) 饾湋饾湐+饾湈 . Calibration and parameters estimation The model parameters can be divided into three groups. For the first group values of parameters were taken as generally used in the literature. For the second group values of parameters were taken by their rough estimate based on statistical data of the economy of Kazakhstan. So in the calculations, the value of 饾浖虆 = 0.33 was used as an average ratio of import to GDP. And for the third group estimation was taken by Bayesian estimation method using the Metropolis-Hastings algorithm. The following table shows the values of parameters used in the model. Parameter Value 饾浖 0.33 饾湋 2.5 饾湈 0,95 饾渹 0.8006 饾湀 0.6996 饾浗 0.98 饾渽 0.12, 0.5 饾渷 0.5003 饾浛 1.5 饾浛饾湅 1.5 饾浛饾懄 0.5217 饾浛饾湅∗ 1.5 饾浛饾懄 0.5 ON 1.0 NNS 0.4 OOS 0.4 OZOS 0.6 饾湆饾憹饾憸 0.7813 饾湆饾憸∗ 0.9 饾湆饾憥 0.9524 饾湆饾憥∗ 0.9975 饾湆饾懅 0.9 Numerical Analysis Productivity shocks Productivity shock reduces the marginal costs of firms, allowing them to reduce the price of domestically produced goods (Fig.A.1). In terms of price rigidity a decline in real interest rates happens, which in its turn moves the output and trade terms down before the rates go back to the steady state values. The trade terms are reduced. As a consequence, there is a downward slump in prices for goods produced in the country, as well as inflation (CPI). The real wage increases dramatically, resulting in a decline in oil production, as well as in domestic use of oil by producers. Accordingly, there is a decline in domestic consumption. Productivity shock abroad has a similar effect on domestic economic performance of the country, except for the terms of trade (Fig.A.2). Reduction in the marginal cost of foreign producers leads to a slump in prices both abroad and in the Home country. There is a temporary reduction in the interest rate, the output of final goods at home and abroad. Monetary shocks Impulse response functions for the Home country variables are shown in Fig. B.1. Due to the monetary shock, leading to an increase of a short-term interest rate, there is a short-term decline in inflation for goods produced in the country, and in the general level of inflation. Negative shocks of output, the trade terms, oil production and employment in the oil sector and consumption in the country Home are created. But there is an upswing in real wages, which may explain the jumps up and then down of employment in the production sector of final goods, total employment. Need to note that the effects of a short-term monetary shock disappear relatively faster than in the case of an output shock. The impact of an overseas monetary shock on economic indicators of Home country are reflected in Fig. B.2. Monetary shock abroad boosts interest rates there, which leads to a decline in production there and inflation. Positive jump in inflation of final-products reduces the real wages in the country. This increases the demand for labor to firms and leads to an increase in employment and output. Oil Price Shocks A short-term increase in oil prices, above all, leads to an increase in oil production and employment growth in the oil sector of the Home country (Figure C.1). There is an outflow of labor from the production of final goods. Interest rate and terms of trade increase. Real wage is rising, stimulating domestic consumer demand and production of final goods. There is a positive jump in inflation as on goods produced in the country, and on the CPI. Differences between Fig. C.1 and C.2 are connected so that the first depicts impulse response functions, when 12 percent oil revenues are used for current consumption, and the second case - 50 percent. As can be seen, with a higher level of oil revenue use, changes of indicators occur in the same directions as for using less of oil revenues, but their reaction to the positive jump in oil prices are weaker. Oil Demand Shocks The sharp increase in oil consumption abroad causes a corresponding increase in its production in the Home country (Figure D.1). An inflow of manpower to the oil sector is accompanied by its outflow from industries producing final goods and, therefore, the decline of production in them. The inflow of oil revenues causes the growth of inflation rate as CPI inflation, and on goods produced in the country. The real interest rate increases. Here, the share of oil revenues, which is used for current consumption, is equal to 12 percent. The implication of this is the decline in real wages. The increase in oil revenues also explains the increase in consumption in the country. On Fig.D.2 a situation for which the share of oil revenues, which is used in the country for the current consumption, is set at 50 percent is depicted. As you can see, all the deviations of economic variables occur in the same directions as for the standard deduction of oil revenues of 12 percent, but weaker. Oil Production Productivity Shocks A positive productivity shock in the oil sector reduces the need in labor (Fig.E). The outflow of labor from the oil sector leads to their inflow into the sector of final goods. Throughout the country real wages are increasing. A change in the share of oil revenue payments for current consumption does not have any effect on the consequence of the shock in oil production. In this paper, we consider a model of dynamic stochastic general equilibrium for the economy of Kazakhstan. The model is based on the standard model of an open economy and its development till the model of two countries and takes into account the specific characteristics of the economy of Kazakhstan. For firms producing final goods, a certain stiffness of technologies is assumed, and for their descriptions production functions with fixed proportions of resources are used. Essential to the economic development of Kazakhstan is the flow of revenues from oil exports. In order to prevent the growth of Dutch disease and inflation, the government does not use its all oil revenues for current consumption, but only a small part of them. The rest of the oil revenues is accumulated in the National Fund of Welfare. In this paper the effects of production shocks, monetary shocks in the country and abroad, oil price and demand for oil shocks abroad, performance shock in the oil production sector for main economic indicators of the country are analyzed. It turns out that the increase in the share of oil revenues allocated to current consumption has a debilitating effect on the consequences from rising oil prices and global oil demand shocks. References Calvo, G. A. (1983). Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework, Journal of Monetary Economics, 12:383-398. Gali, J. & Monacelli, T. (2005). Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy. Review of Economic Studies, 72:707-734 Gunter, Ulrich (2009). Macroeconomic Interdependence in a Two-Country DSGE Model under Diverging Interest-Rate Rules. Department of Economics, University of Vienna Hohenstaufengasse 9, A-1010 Vienna, Austria. Medina, Juan Pablo & Claudio Soto (2005). Oil Shocks and Monetary Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model for a Small Open Economy. WP N.° 353 – Diciembre 2005, CENTRAL BANK OF CHILE Obstfeld, M. and K. Rogff (2001): Risk and Exchange Rates. Conference paper in honor of Assaf Razin, Tel-Aviv University. Silveira, Marcos Antonio (2006). Two-country new keynesian DSGE model: a small open economy as a limit case. Rio de Janeiro, fevereiro de 2006 Appendices A1. IR Functions for Home Variables to a Home Productivity, 饾渽 =0.12, 0.5 pih y s 0 0 0 -0.02 -0.005 -0.005 -0.04 10 20 30 40 -0.01 10 r 20 30 40 -0.01 re 0 2 -0.05 -0.02 1 10 20 30 40 -0.04 10 pi 20 30 40 0 0 -0.02 0.1 -0.5 20 30 0 40 10 20 30 40 20 30 40 30 40 no 0.2 10 10 wp 0 -0.04 20 a 0 -0.1 10 30 40 os -1 10 20 o 0 0 -0.2 -1 -0.4 10 20 30 40 -2 10 ns 2 0.05 1 10 20 30 40 30 40 c 0 -0.005 -0.01 10 20 30 40 30 40 n 0.1 0 20 0 10 20 Fig. A.2: IR Functions for Home Variables to a Foreign Productivity Shock , pih y 0 -0.02 饾渽 =0.12, 0.5 s 0 0.01 -0.01 0.005 -0.04 10 20 30 40 -0.02 10 r 20 30 40 0 re 0 0 -0.05 -0.02 -0.02 10 20 30 40 -0.04 10 piz 20 30 40 -0.04 0 -0.05 -0.01 -0.1 20 30 40 -0.02 10 rez 20 30 40 -0.2 az 0 -0.02 30 40 20 30 40 30 40 30 40 30 40 30 40 rz 0 10 10 yz 0 -0.1 20 pi 0 -0.1 10 2 2 1 1 10 20 -3 wp 10 20 x 10 -0.04 10 20 30 40 0 no 0 0 10 20 -3 os x 10 30 40 o 0 -2 -0.005 0 -0.01 -4 -0.01 10 20 30 40 10 ns 20 30 40 -0.02 n 0.1 0 0.02 0.05 -0.01 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 20 c 0.04 0 10 30 40 -0.02 10 20 Fig. B.1: IR Functions for Home Variables to a Home Monetary Policy Shock , pih y s 0 0 0 -0.1 -0.5 -0.2 -0.2 10 20 30 40 -1 10 r 20 30 40 -0.4 0.1 0.2 0 0.05 20 30 40 -0.5 10 no 20 30 40 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 -0.5 20 30 40 -0.4 10 20 30 40 20 30 40 30 40 o 0 10 10 os 0 -0.4 20 wp 0.5 10 10 pi 0.4 0 饾渽 =0.12, 0.5 30 40 -1 10 20 ns 1 0 -1 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 25 30 35 40 25 30 35 40 n 5 0 -5 5 10 15 20 c 0 -0.2 -0.4 5 10 15 20 Fig. B.2: IR Functions for Home Variables to a Foreign Monetary Policy Shock , pih y s 0.04 0.1 0.4 0.02 0 0.2 0 10 20 30 40 -0.1 10 r 20 30 0 40 0.2 0 0 0 20 30 40 -0.2 10 yz 20 30 40 -0.2 0.5 10 20 30 0 40 10 20 30 30 40 40 -0.02 0 0 10 20 30 40 -0.05 10 o 0.5 0 0 20 30 40 -0.5 10 n 30 40 0.2 0 0 20 20 30 40 20 30 40 30 40 c 1 10 20 ns 0.1 10 10 os 0.05 -1 20 0 no -0.1 40 0.02 0.1 -0.1 30 wp -0.5 -1 10 rz 0 20 piz 0.2 10 10 pi 0.5 -0.5 饾渽 =0.12 30 40 -0.2 10 20 Fig. 小.1: IR Functions for Home Variables to a Oil Price Shock, 饾渽 pih y 1 s 0.5 0.4 0.5 0 0.2 10 20 30 40 0 10 r 20 30 0 40 2 1 0.5 1 20 30 40 0 10 wp 20 30 0 40 0.2 0.5 0.2 0.1 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 o 1 0.6 0 0.4 -1 0.2 -2 10 20 40 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 ns 0.8 0 30 os 0.4 10 10 no 1 0 20 pop 1 10 10 pi 2 0 = 0.12 30 40 -3 10 n 20 30 40 30 40 c 2 1.5 0 1 -2 0.5 -4 -6 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 Fig. 小.2: IR Functions for Home Variables to a Oil Price Shock, 饾渽 pih y s 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 r 20 30 0 40 20 30 40 30 40 30 40 pop 0.5 2 0.5 1 10 20 30 40 0 10 wp 20 30 0 40 0.1 0.5 0.1 0.05 20 30 40 0 10 20 20 os 0.2 10 10 no 1 0 10 pi 1 0 = 0.5 30 40 o 0 10 20 ns 0.4 1 0.3 0 0.2 -1 0.1 0 10 20 30 40 -2 10 n 20 30 40 30 40 c 2 1.5 0 1 -2 0.5 -4 -6 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 Fig. D.1: IR Functions for Home Variables to a Oil Demand Shock, pih y s 1 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.2 0.2 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 r 20 30 0 40 0 1 1 -0.2 20 30 40 0 10 oz 20 30 40 -0.4 1 1 1 0.5 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 20 30 40 30 40 os 2 10 10 no 2 0 20 wp 2 10 10 pi 2 0 饾渽 =0.12 30 40 o 0 10 20 ns 0.4 0 0.3 -1 0.2 -2 0.1 0 10 20 30 40 -3 10 n 20 30 40 30 40 c 0 1.5 -2 1 -4 0.5 -6 -8 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 Fig. D.2: IR Functions for Home Variables to an Oil Demand, pih 饾渽 =0.5 y s 1 0.4 0.2 0.5 0.2 0.1 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 r 20 30 0 40 pi 1 0 1 0.5 -0.2 10 20 30 40 0 10 oz 20 30 40 -0.4 1 1 0.5 0.5 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 20 30 40 30 40 os 1 10 10 no 2 0 20 wp 2 0 10 30 40 o 0 10 20 ns 0.4 0 0.3 -1 0.2 -2 0.1 0 10 20 30 40 -3 10 n 20 30 40 30 40 c 0 1.5 -2 1 -4 0.5 -6 -8 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 Fig. E: IR Functions for Home Variables to an Oil Production Productivity, wp z 2 2 1 1 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 no 1 -1 0.5 10 20 30 40 30 40 n 4 2 0 10 20 20 30 40 30 40 ns 0 -2 饾渽 =0.12, 0.5 0 10 20