We the People’s Republic China’s Democratic Village Elections & the Legitimacy of the One-Party State Jace T. White ---------Rollins College We the People’s Republic Spring 2013 Table of Contents I. Introduction………………………………………….. 2 II. The Analytical Context Of Democracy in China…………………………..... 7 III. The Dynamics of Village Self-Government……..……………….......10 i. Elections and Local Governance……....................... 11 ii. Elections and Rural Villagers……………………….. 19 IV. Village Elections & Political Legitimacy………..……….…….......... 24 V. Conclusion…………………………………………..... 28 VI. Bibliography…………………………………………... # — 1 — Jace T. White Abstract: The implementation of democratic elections in villages across China has been one of the most widely discussed topics of the reform era. In particular, analysis has attempted to determine the potential significance and consequences of village elections for the much broader issues of political reform in China. Analyzing the issue at the local level, this paper contends that the institutionalization of village elections and certain elements of electoral democracy in village governance allow opportunities for the party-state to reconsolidate its rural political legitimacy. This paper will provide evidence to its main contention by drawing evidence from scholarly review, village-level case studies, and analysis of the implications of village elections for the rural political legitimacy of the party-state vis-à-vis the structures and dynamics of local-level governance and the rural voting populace. I. Introduction Revolutionary change in China has always, by and large, been a product of the rural countryside. In the decades following 1949, the will of the rural Chinese people was to lead the People’s Republic of China into a new age of revolutionary Maoist communism. Nearly sixty-four years later, the rural Chinese people are supposedly the vanguard of no less revolutionary a movement designed to bring China into modernity—democracy. Whether China is able to realize the “fifth modernization” is an issue of considerable contention, but recent developments in village self-government (Cunmin Zizhi 村民自治) provide a different light in which to analyze future political reform in China. Pro-market reforms and the gradual liberalization of the Chinese economy under the guidance of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) in the Post-Mao era has resulted in phenomenal developmental growth and rising standards of living, bringing China ever closer to international standards of modernity. China’s future success is unsurprisingly directly dependent on the economic system’s sustainability. However, economic development as it currently stands has not been without its demerits. Rampant systemic corruption, widening wealth inequality, increasingly common social unrest, and decreasing economic growth rates threaten the sustainability of economic development and therefore China’s modernization. The successful resolution of these issues and sustainability of economic growth hinges largely on the capacity of the Chinese political system to undergo reforms that would enable it to cope with the developmental issues of a continuously changing economic system. The central Chinese leadership has fully understood the necessity of political reform, especially from the — 2 — We the People’s Republic onset of the post-Mao era reforms. Deng Xiaoping, the author of the phenomenal and sweeping economic reforms of the past four decades, realized that the successful progression of economic reform and development would greatly depend on concurrent political reform. Deng was especially vocal in his support for the so-called dual track of development, notably claiming: “If we fail to do that [political reform], we shall be unable to preserve the gains we have made in the economic reform… Without political reform, economic reform cannot succeed… So in the final analysis, the success of all our other reforms depends on the success of the political reform.”1 Most analysts, therefore, agree that China’s future modernization depends almost entirely on significant reform of the Chinese political system, yet the predicted ramifications vary significantly. Political reform as it currently stands, while not completely static, has lagged far behind economic reforms and by most accounts is far from achieving democratization. There have been important steps, although slowpaced and incremental, towards political reform. China’s traditional authoritarian political system has evolved, for example, in terms of its developing norms of meritocratic leadership promotion and norms of stable leadership succession. Yet perhaps the most important and notable institutional development is the implementation of democratic elections for membership in rural village committees (Cunmin weiyuanhui 村民委员会), a village-level executive and administrative body equivalent to that of city councils in Western societies. Analysts frequently point to village elections and village self-government 2 as providing the foundation for eventual fullfledged political reform. China’s experiment with democratic village elections began in 1987 in direct response to the process of the de-collectivizing the people’s communes a few years prior in 1982. As part of Deng’s economic reforms, dismantling the basic administrative level of the Chinese communist system allowed for the “Household Responsibility” system of land privatization to take effect. While Deng Xiaoping, “Reform of the Leadership System of the Party and State”, Selections of Deng Xiaoping, Volume II (Beijing: People’s Press, 1983), pp. 320-343 2 The term Village Self-Government in this paper refers to the local structures, institutions and dynamics of “autonomous” governance derived from the implementation of village elections, mainly defined by the relationship between the village committee and the voting villagers. In theory, village self-government is designed to reflect villagers democratically electing their preferred village committee members to oversee village administrative affairs, independent of the higher strata of the party-state administrative bureaucracy. 1 — 3 — Jace T. White de-collectivization resulted in rising standards of living and greater economic opportunities for rural Chinese, the process thoroughly shook up local governance structures. The village-level political organizational units of the commune, namely the production brigades (danwei 单位), were disbanded along with the commune. The dissolution of these basic rural political organizations resulted in a political vacuum among the rural villages, causing concern for the party-state 3 due to it’s substantially decreased presence in the countryside. Furthermore, the lowest rung of government bureaucracy shifted up to the township level (Xiangzhen 乡镇) of governance, leaving villages not only economically but also, to an extent, politically autonomous. Interestingly, some villages elected their own leaders to an executive organizational body, a village committee, without the government’s express permission and through democratic means. This drew the attention and, interestingly, later approval of the Chinese central leadership interested in reasserting party-state control in the countryside, providing for effective governance in the villages, and protecting against the possibilities of rural economic and political instability. 4 The central Leadership’s response of support for village elections and democratic village self-governance reflected the oft-invoked policy-making method of “proceeding from point to surface” (youdian daomian 由点到面), or decentralized, locally-based experimental policy-making; democratic village elections and village self-governance were thus sanctioned as experimental local solutions to the breakdown of rural For the sake of clarity and expediency in writing this paper, the general term party-state will be used to refer to the monolithic, centralized, one-party authoritarian governing body of the Chinese political system—the combination of the administrative bureaucracy and the guiding Chinese Communist Party. The party-state is further divided into five categories of vertical strata: Central-level, provincial-level, prefectural-level, county-level, and township-level (or local-level). For more on the Chinese state structure, see: Kenneth J. Lieberthal, Managing the China Challenge: How to Achieve Corporate Success in the People’s Republic (Harrisonburg: The Brookings Institution, 2011), pp. 11-58; J. Bruce Jacobs, “Elections in China,” The Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs 25 (1991), pp. 172 4 For an overview of early rural reforms and the de-collectivization of the commune system, see: Qingshan Tan, Village Elections in China: Democratizing the Countryside (Lewiston: The Edwin Mellen Press, 2006), pp. 33-64; Kevin J. O’Brien and Lianjiang Li, “Accommodating ‘Democracy’ in a One-Party State: Introducing Village Elections in China,” The China Quarterly 162 (Jun. 2000), pp. 465-489; Tyrene White, “Reforming the Countryside,” Current History, 91 (Sep. 1992), pp. 273-277 3 — 4 — We the People’s Republic governance and a strategy to shore up the party-state’s local political authority and legitimacy.5 As a result, the Ministry of Civil Affairs enacted the Organic Law of Village Committees in 1987, requiring each of China’s nearly 930,000 villages to elect members of a village committee through democratic means. 6 The village committee, consisting of five to seven elected members, would act as the village’s executive administrative body and oversee local administrative affairs. The Organic Law further mandated that village committees be elected in three-year cycles. After the trial implementation beginning in 1987, the Organic Law was adopted into full law in 1998, signaling a permanent institutionalization of village-level electoral law in China.7 Unsurprisingly, this development has drawn considerable scholarly attention, and debate carries on regarding the implications of village elections and village self-government for China’s future political reform. The presence of democratic elections at the lowest level of Chinese society may appear to be a political breakthrough in one of the most notoriously authoritarian states, but the realities are much more nuanced. In many ways, the village has become a testing ground for whether or not democracy can work in China and the experimentation with democratic elections in China’s villages continues into the 21st century without offering a decisive answer. In addition, great variances in regional experiences with village selfgovernment further cloud the picture; one village’s experiences with elections may be starkly different from others’ and therefore no decisive consensus exists on the decisive implications of village elections for political reform. However, numerous case studies of village elections from across China serve to highlight the overarching trends in possible implications for future political reform from which conclusions can be drawn. For an overview on China’s process of utilizing local experimentation of national policies in determining their viability and maximizing their effectiveness, see: Sebastian Heilmann, “From Local Experiments to National Policy: The Origins of China’s Distinctive Policy Process,” The China Journal 59 (Jan. 2008), pp. 1-31; Sebastian Heilmann, “Policy Experimentation in China’s Economic Rise,” Studies in Comparative International Development 43 (2008), pp. 1-26 6 National People’s Congress, Organic Law of Villagers Committees of the People’s Republic of China (1998): <http://www.china.org.cn/english/government/207279.htm> 7 For a comprehensive overview of the history of the Organic Law and the debate in the central leadership regarding its passage and implementation, see: O’Brien and Li, “Accommodating ‘Democracy’ in a One-Party State,” pp. 465-489; Daniel Kelliher, “The Chinese Debate over Village Self-Government,” The China Journal 37 (1997), pp. 63-86 5 — 5 — Jace T. White The purpose of this paper will be to explore the consequences of village elections in context of the much broader issue of future political reform in China. Specifically, this paper will analyze the potential implications of village elections for the political legitimacy of the current party-state regime’s rural presence, authority, and leadership. Along these lines, this paper asserts that village elections, in institutionalizing electoral democracy as a basis of legitimate grassroots-level governance, also cogently signify the capacity of village elections to contribute to the reconsolidation and strengthening of the authoritarian, one-party state’s political legitimacy throughout rural China. The implications of village elections and village selfgovernment, analyzed in context of both local dynamics and structures of local governance as well as rural Chinese villagers particularly evidences the capacity of village elections to reinforce the party-state’s internal and external legitimacy. Going forward, this paper will begin with an examination of the appropriate criteria with which to define the concept of democracy, especially as it pertains to village elections and China’s current political circumstances. Subsequently, the paper will provide an ample selection of the current body of scholarly literature concerning village elections and political reform in China, in many cases including scholarly case studies of several issues pertinent to village elections as well. For lack of official and reliable national data or surveys of village elections, analysis as a result must rely for the most part on scholarly case studies of village elections conducted across China. These case studies provide a comprehensive overview of the key trends and themes of village self-government and elections across the vast breadth of the largely anecdotal “mountain of evidence” from which arguably any conclusion concerning village elections can be haphazardly drawn.8 With this in mind, this paper will avoid the use of anecdotal evidence to draw conclusions and avoid getting bogged down in finite details of specific incidences of village self-government and village elections. The rationale behind the analysis of case studies is to reveal how a village’s specific electoral experiments may be significant of the much broader underlying themes and trends existing in rural Chinese villages and how these may signify similar trends in Chinese politics at large. That is to say, this paper will not determine the significance of village elections for China’s political system by pointing to specifics, as one village’s experiences most decidedly do Melanie Manion, “How to Assess Village Elections in China,” Journal of Contemporary China 18 (Jun. 2009), p. 379 8 — 6 — We the People’s Republic not represent the whole of China in the slightest; this paper will not, for instance, point to the specific failure of elections in Village A to oust a corrupt cadre or the specific dynamic of Village B’s village committee-party relationship to conclude the future of political reform in China. Rather, as village elections are still a relatively new political development across China, this paper will relate the experiences of specific villages carefully researched in case studies as evidence of potential trends in the broader context of political reform in China as a whole. In order to determine the potential implications of village elections for the party-state’s rural legitimacy, this paper will examine the effects of institutionalized village electoral democracy for the structures and dynamics of local governance and the political role and involvement of rural villagers. In particular, this paper’s conclusions will focus its analysis on the potential consequences of village elections for both the external and internal legitimacy of the party-state. That is, analysis of the structures and dynamics of local governance will demonstrate the capacity of village elections to aid in the relegitimation of the party-state’s own internal structures of governance. Similarly, the analysis of village elections as they impact rural villagers will highlight the potential of village elections to re-legitimate its external relations with the villagers themselves. II. The Analytical Context of Democracy in China Any discussion of political reform in China must also provide a sufficient analytical context of the theory of democracy. Including a working definition of the components of democracy allows for the appropriate analysis of the democratic nature of village elections as well as the analysis of their potential democratizing power. Yet certain questions remain: what is democracy and how do we judge a political system to be democratic? Is it appropriate to hold developing political systems to Western standards of democracy? Although this paper will primarily examine how village elections provide for the reconsolidation of the party-state’s legitimacy, analysis of the democratic village self-government operating in China offers a more complete picture of the nature of democratic village elections and democratic village self-government. Therefore, this section will expound on certain criteria through which to define democracy in China. In order to synthesize this functioning definition of democracy, this paper will draw on select scholarly interpretations. For one, Larry Diamond’s account of electoral democracy is, in his words, “a civilian, constitutional — 7 — Jace T. White system in which the legislative and chief executive offices are filled through regular, competitive, multiparty elections with universal suffrage.” Furthermore, Diamond asserts that elections themselves must be free and fair to be considered democratic in their own right or conducive to democratic governance. Firstly, elections must be free in the sense that legal barriers to entry and participation in the election are minimal, that competition and partisanship are both permitted and protected, and that voters must be free from coercive or fraudulent electoral processes. Secondly, elections must be fair in the sense that they are equitable, transparent, and impartial, free of control by the vested interests present in the ruling party, and accessible by all adult citizens granted the right to vote in universal suffrage.9 The appropriate context in which to examine China’s potential paths of political reform is thus reliant on a practical selection of criteria for what shall constitute democracy. It would be counterintuitive to select these criteria according to lofty Western standards, as the West’s political development experience, political culture, and historical-political context all differ greatly from those of China. In analyzing democratic characteristics through a developmental perspective, the definition of democracy operates more so along a continuum rather than on an either/or basis. 10 That is, because it would be inappropriate to judge the nascent inklings of democracy in China according to the standards of the more advanced and institutionalized liberal democracies of Western states, the developing notions of democracy in China must begin at the basic level on this continuum. For example, the staple characteristics of liberal democracies, such as multiple political parties, systems of government checks-andbalances, and most cogently the direct election of national legislative and executive offices do not appropriately reflect criteria of a developing democratic system, but criteria of advanced, institutionalized democratic societies. And so, accounting for China’s status as a developing nation, the criteria of democracy—pertaining to village elections and their broader implications for political reform—will borrow from Diamond’s rudimentary interpretation of electoral democracy. As a result, democracy for the purposes of this paper will be defined with the following five basic yet significant criteria: Larry Diamond, “Introduction: Elections and Democracy in Greater China,” The China Quarterly 162, pp. 366 10 Ibid. pp. 367 9 — 8 — We the People’s Republic 1) The enfranchised citizenry determine chief legislative and executive offices through free and fair direct elections 2) Electoral procedures are governed by the rule of law. 3) The political system must allow and respect pluralism, namely dissent of opinion and organization of opposition 4) Universal suffrage is extended to the adult citizenry as an inalienable constitutional and legal right. 5) Norms and/or institutions of accountability, responsiveness, competence in governance exist that reinforce the connection between government and voters, allowing the interests of the voting citizenry potential indirect influence over the policy-making process, to a degree. These five criteria allow for the appropriate and realistic judgment of whether or not China’s experiment with village self-government represents developments in democracy. However, despite frequent claims on part of central leaders that the foundations of the Chinese political system lie with “socialist democracy” or the equally enigmatic “democracy with Chinese characteristics,” the obvious conclusion based on the aforementioned criteria is that although certain elements of democracy may be developing in China, Chinese democracy as it currently stands remains far removed from meaningful notions of democracy in the macro perspective. The political system’s democratic shortcomings are notably evident, for instance, in the lack of elections for central executive and legislative leadership, the frequency with which rule by law constitutes the guiding legal system, and the outright prohibition of opposition parties or organizations, just to name a few. However, whereas democracy is obviously non-existent at the national perspective, at the local perspective village self-government has made some arguably significant strides towards realizing a combination of the above criteria. As the purpose of this paper is to determine whether the institutions and norms of village electoral democracy will benefit or detract from the party-state regime’s rural legitimacy, the above criteria are critical to contextually defining democracy in China. Going forward, the use of the term democracy in this paper will reflect the above criteria. Similarly, the term democratization will refer to the spread of these criteria to other sectors of governance (e.g. the ‘bottom-up’ spread of democratic institutions and norms to higher government strata) or, similarly, will refer to the increasing development of these criteria within certain levels of governance. — 9 — Jace T. White III. The Dynamics of Village Self-Government This paper draws on a broad review of the current body of scholarly literature regarding village elections. The available body of literature provides an exhaustive overview on the potential capacity for village elections to lead to lasting and significant political reforms. Being such a controversial topic, the future political reform has unsurprisingly drawn considerable debate and various predictions of its nature. In focusing this paper’s topic on village elections and village self-government, this paper will refer to the portion of the central scholarly debate concerned primarily with the significance of village elections for both the future of the party-state’s political legitimacy in rural China. Within this section of the available literature, this paper will specifically review scholarly research of villagelevel governance structures, developing electoral procedures, the wide array of predictions for future political reform, and the dynamics of the political involvement of rural villagers and the particulars of villager involvement in local-level governance and politics. As theories of the significance and consequences of village elections for the above topics as well as for the current political system of centralized oneparty authoritarian rule, it is necessary order the review of the literature. Therefore, In order to make sense of the breadth of available literature on village elections and provide the best context in providing this paper’s central thesis, it is necessary to further categorize the literature according to two broad yet integral points of examination. The first point of examination will analyze the link between village elections and village-level governance, particularly in relation to the roles and involvement of village party branches, township governments, and local-level cadres. The second point of examination will analyze the effect village elections have on the villagers themselves with regards to rights consciousness, participation, and political efficacy. The various arguments and assertions derived from these central issues will serve to create the contextual framework in which this paper will synthesize its central thesis. Village Elections and Local Governance Forefront among the most significant issues in determining the implications of village elections for political reform—and party-state — 10 — We the People’s Republic legitimacy in particular—is examining how village elections affect the structures and dynamics of rural governance and local political power. Unsurprisingly, implementing village elections throughout China’s myriad rural villages has been a complex process, confusing these traditional structures and dynamics of local-level governance. Electoral democracy’s introduction of both bottom-up and top-down dynamics of vertical accountability—from rural villagers and the central party-state, respectively—have thoroughly complicated the relationships between the principal actors within the Chinese political system. That is to say, the nature of interactions, division of responsibility, and definitions of political hierarchy among the various levels of the administrative bureaucracy, the branches of the Chinese Communist Party, and the elements of village selfgovernment are left undefined by the vagueness of the Organic Law; there is a lack of standardization as to the definitive roles of village committees, village party branches, and township governments in village self-government. Prior to the assessment of the significance of village elections, it is first necessary to note that while village elections in several cases are procedurally democratic, this does not necessarily equate to democratic governance of villages. For a more comprehensive understanding of the significance of village elections and village self-government, it will be important to recognize this key distinction. As Kevin J. O’Brien and Rongbin Han explain, analyzing the implications of village elections through an exclusively procedural view of democracy does not explain the exercise of political power following an election.11 Specifically O’Brien and Han caution that evaluation of village self-government should effectively differentiate between access to power and exercise of power.12 By access to power, O’Brien and Han are referring to the institutions and norms of electoral democracy that allow villagers to participate in the political system, namely to vote for preferred candidates, to run for village committee membership, and so forth. The exercise of power, by contrast, refers to the specifics functions and operations of local governance following the election. More specifically, this refers to how power and authority is distributed between village committees, In reference to this paper’s criteria for democracy defined in Section II, for village self-government to be considered democratic, elections must not only be carried out in a manner considered to be free and fair, but post-election politics must also be governed by rule of law and democratic norms and institutions must be in place to continue to hold government accountable to the voting populace. 12 Kevin J. O’Brien and Rongbin Han, “Path to Democracy? Assessing Village Elections in China,” Journal of Contemporary China (2009), 18(60), p. 359-378 11 — 11 — Jace T. White township governments and local party branches following an election and whether the different local-level actors in the political system are able to effectively determine and adhere to a hierarchy of power and responsibility, avoid overlapping claims to authority, and so forth. The distinction between access to power and exercise of power is therefore a significant one. Many scholars as a result, call for future research to reflect this distinction. Melanie Manion, for instance, claims that discussion of the potential democratization of China must take this distinction into account, as most democratization optimists rely too much on the analysis of procedural democracy in making their claims.13 Therefore, in going forth, this paper will take into account the distinction between exercise of power and access to power in its analysis of village elections. 14 With this distinction in mind, Lisheng Dong helpfully categorizes the key issues concerning the implications of village elections for local governance into terms of four key local-level governmental and political bodies. 15 The first of these is the local party branch. Do these elections strengthen or weaken the political authority of the party in the village? The second concerns village-level cadres, or the party-state’s basic-level administrative and bureaucratic officials. Do village elections result in the responsiveness and accountability of local cadres? The third is the effect on the political superiority of township governments over village affairs. Do village elections upset the hierarchy of political power? Are village committee members accountable to the interests of the voters that elected them or to the directives of higher-ups in the township government? The fourth concerns the implementation of state policy. Does village self-government present difficulties to the central party-state’s capability to enact its policies in villages across China? Examination of these four components of governance in terms of how they are affected by village elections are helpful in providing Melanie Manion, “How to Assess Village Elections in China,” Journal of Contemporary China, p. 382 14 For an overview of access to power and exercise of power in Chinese villages, please see: Lianjiang Li, “The Empowering Effect of Village Elections in China,” Asian Survey 43 (2003), pp. 648-662; Melanie Manion, “Democracy, Community, Trust: The Impact of Elections in Rural China,” Comparative Political Studies (39)3, (2006), pp. 301-324; John James Kennedy, “Legitimacy with Chinese Characteristics: ‘Two increases, one reduction’”, Journal of Contemporary China 18, (2009) 15 Lisheng Dong, “Searching for a Direction After Two Decades of Local Democratic Experiments in China” China Elections and Governance Review 2 (May 2009), pp. 6 13 — 12 — We the People’s Republic the best context in which to analyze the consequences of villager selfgovernment for the party-state’s rural legitimacy. The question of how village elections affect the local party branch is of particular importance. The local party branch is the farthest extension of the central party state’s authority and as a result often assumes the most influential and active role in local political affairs. In many respects the relationship between the village party branch and the elected village committee is the most significant official relationship in village-level politics and defines the dynamics of village self-governance. Such as it is, the nature of this relationship can make or break effective village-level governance. As per the 3rd article of the Organic Law, the local party branch ought to assume a role of “leadership” (lingdao 领 导 ) in village governance, representing the party-state’s political authority in local affairs. However, the language of Organic Law (like much of the law) is vague on the exact relationship between the village committee and the local party branch, leading to frequent jurisdictional conflicts between the two administrative bodies. Qingshan Tan elaborates on this frequently dysfunctional relationship, citing institutional deficiencies as the cause. 16 That is, the absence of a legal institutional framework of governance is further confused by the vagueness of the Organic Law; while designed to allow various localities to experiment with the most effective electoral procedures appropriate to the respective locality, actively contributes to ineffective postelection governance in villages. The lack of definitive legal language on the sharing of administrative authority and responsibilities essentially renders the village committees unable to compete with the party-state-backed political superiority of the village party branch. The party branch has, in many cases, remained the dominant political authority in the villages as a result, thus precluding the institutionalization of efficient, democratic village self-government. Similarly, Jean Oi and Scott Rozelle note from their study of elections in thirty-two villages that the dynamic of power and authority in the villages remained largely unchanged due to the frequent reassertion of the village party branch’s political dominance. As a result, the village party secretary typically remains the most powerful player in village politics. By Oi Qingshan Tan, “Why Village Election Has Not Much Improved Village Governance,” Journal of Chinese Political Science (2010) 16 — 13 — Jace T. White and Rozelle’s analysis, the electoral procedures in many villages remain largely insignificant in their effects for local structures of governance. 17 Other scholars, by contrast, are more optimistic regarding the capacity for a harmonious relationship to exist between the village committee and the local party branch. Bjorn Alpermann, for one, suggests that the institutionalization of post-election procedures has simultaneously resulted in improving opportunities for effective villager self-governance and reinforced the local party branch’s role in village affairs as well. Specifically, Alpermann refers to the institutional reconfiguration of certain dynamics of village governance, particularly “democratic decision-making, management, and supervision.”18 He further posits that even though the vagueness of the Organic Law can, in some cases, lead to a problematic relationship between the village committee and the party branch, provincial and township governments will further refine the Organic Law as it passed down to lower government levels so as to mold village governance to more aptly suit the necessitating conditions of each locality. Furthermore, Alpermann views the “leadership” role of township governments as beneficial to both local governance and party-state control in rural localities. While the more experienced township officials train village committee members in the administration of village affairs, this also allows for opportunities to co-opt village committee members to work for the party-state’s ends. Regional experimentation with village self-governance has a resulted in interesting and significant developments in the particular role of the village party branch in some localities. Among the most notable of such developments is the “Two-Ballot System” (Liangpiaozhi 两 票 制 ). Some villages have allowed for the candidates for membership in the local party branch to undergo a series of two elections in deciding their entry into party membership. In the two-ballot system, the villagers choose their favored candidate for membership from the available pool of candidates by simply casting votes to note their preferences. However, this does not elect the potential party members, instead this “election” more so reflects the villagers’ vote of confidence in a potential party member. Subsequently, local party members take this vote into account when electing a new party member most Jean Oi and Scott Rozelle, “Elections and Power: The Locus of Decision Making in Chinese Villages,” The China Quarterly 162 (2000): pp. 513-539 18 Bjorn Alpermann, “Institutionalizing Village Governance in China,” Journal of Contemporary China (2009), pp. 397-409 17 — 14 — We the People’s Republic likely to strengthen accountability and responsiveness between the local party branch and the village people. 19 Much like the experiments with township elections, the experiments with these indirect elections for village party membership were locally invented and designed to remedy both poorly implemented village governance and party members’ corruption and abuse of power. Because village party secretaries in many cases manage the village committee’s affairs, village selfgovernment wouldn’t be meaningfully democratic without holding this principal executive office accountable to norms of responsiveness, accountability and transparency common to other areas of village selfgovernance. As a result, many township party branches incorporated the twoballot system as a staple institution of village self-government.20 Accordingly, with the institutionalization of the two-ballot system in increasingly more rural villages, legitimacy from the bottom up (i.e. from voters) rather than from the top-down is increasingly becoming a norm contending to define the legitimate role of the party branch in local governance. In some cases, there exist clear-cut, spelled out divisions of administrative responsibility and authority between the village committee and the village party branch. However, when the divisions are not so distinct, this reveals certain implications for villager-self government. In many cases, proponents of villager self-government welcome the concurrent holding of the two offices (yijiantiao 一肩挑) of village committee chair and village party secretary as a potentially conducive development to the democratization of local-level governance. According to Daniel Kelliher, these proponents believe “that concurrent office-holding may lead to popular control over the local party. Today, if a party secretary wants to exercise the presumptive right to head the villagers’ committee, then he or she must submit to an election.”21 That is to say, a village party secretary must win the support of the voters to act as the village committee chair and remain responsive and accountable to the voting public while acting in such a role. In this way, the local party branch becomes an arm of democratic village governance as a result, perhaps signifying the potential of this development to advance a process of bottom-up democratization. However, the particular sequence through which this Lisheng Dong, “Searching for a Direction After Two Decades of Local Democratic Experiments in China,” China Elections and Governance Review 2 (May 2009), pp. 3 20 Lianjiang Li, “The Two-Ballot System in Shanxi Province: Subjecting Village Party Secretaries to a Popular Vote,” The China Journal, No. 42 (1999), pp. 103-118 21 Daniel Kelliher, “The Chinese Debate over Village Self-Government,” The China Journal No. 37 (Jan. 1997), pp. 63-86 19 — 15 — Jace T. White official comes to hold both offices significantly determines whether this dynamic is indicative of democratization or, to the contrary, the strengthening of the party-state’s political reach. The concurrent holding of offices isn’t so indicative of democratization when switching the dynamic of coming into possession of both roles, as is explained above. If the village committee chair is appointed to act as local party secretary, this represents the cooptation of the village committee and is instead more indicative of the party-state’s reassertion of control over village-level political affairs. In such a way, both the village committee chair and the local party secretary would act according to the interests of the party-state rather than the voting public.22 Beyond the significant role of village party branch, some scholars instead focus on the role that the township governments play in village governance. Township governments, replacing the disbanded commune governments as the lowest level of party-state’s administrative bureaucracy, operate at the political stratum just above village-level government. Acting as the immediate superior political body to village self-government, the role of the township in village governance is thus of special significance, with the nature of involvement ranging from intervention to indifference. More specifically, John J. Kennedy categorizes three distinct “attitudes” that influence township governments to intervene in village-level affairs: support, partial support, and opposition.23 These attitudes in turn frame much of the relationship between village self-government and the townships, and to a degree explain the successes or failures of certain cases of village selfgovernment. Many analysts, focusing on the interventional role that township governments play in village politics, regard the township-village relationship as especially significant for village self-government. For example, Hang Lin claims that due to the township’s central role in organizing village level administrative activities, the success of village elections in producing meaningful, effective governance depends almost entirely on the township’s attitude towards village self-government. 24 The township, assuming the dominant political role in supervising the division of labor between the Suzanne Ogden, Inklings of Democracy in China (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2002), pp. 203-204 23 John James Kennedy, “Legitimacy with Chinese Characteristics: ‘Two Increases, Once Reduction,” Journal of Contemporary China 18(60), (2009), pp. 391-395 24 Hang Lin, “A Mixed Bag of Results: Village Elections in Contemporary China,” Asian Culture and History, 3(1), (Jan. 2011), pp. 14-22 22 — 16 — We the People’s Republic village committee and village party branch in village governance, is capable of manipulating or aiding in effective democratic village self-governance. Administrative dysfunction in village government also may force the township’s intervention. As Guo Zhenglin and Thomas Bernstein assert, in cases of political gridlock resulting from jurisdictional conflicts between the village committee and the local party branch, the township government will intervene and will more likely adjudicate in favor of the party branch.25 Due to both the distrust of villager self-rule coupled with the belief that the party branch is more likely than the village committee to be more responsive to the orders of superiors, the township will unsurprisingly support the party branch’s authority. Alpermann offers the dynamic of vertical accountability that exists between township and village governments as another cause for township intervention in village affairs, although in this case demonstrating support for village self-government.26 Cadres operating at levels below the township are typically unelected and therefore responsible for carrying out orders from above; unelected cadres answer directly to the township governments and are in most respects held accountable only to the township. The political legitimacy of these cadres as well as their ability to retain their posts therefore relies largely on their performance in effectively carrying out the directives handed down from the township government and other levels of government higher up. This dynamic of administrative responsibility granted from above causes cadres to be more susceptible to falsifying performance related data in order to meet requirements of their office from above. In acknowledgement of this possible hindrance to the effective governance of village affairs, townships as a result extend their political reach to villages to prevent this from occurring. In some cases, this extension of political control downward may take the form of the township supporting village elections, particularly if these elections may result in strong dynamics of accountability, transparency, and competency of cadres. With village elections sanctioned by township governments, cadres would theoretically be held accountable to the standards of performance necessitated by the interests of the villagers directly affected by cadres’ active role in village government. This change up of the dynamics of accountability would Guo Zhenglin and Thomas F. Bernstein, “The Impact of Elections on the Village Structure of Power: The Relations Between the Village Committee and the Party Branches,” Journal of Contemporary China (2004), pp. 267-271 26 Bjorn Alpermann, “The Post-Election Administration of Chinese Villages,” The China Journal 48 (Jul. 2001), pp. 45-67 25 — 17 — Jace T. White theoretically remove the immediate inclination of cadres to falsify information, in turn most likely improving the quality of village-level governance. As Oi and Rozelle aptly put it, “whether cadres have power depends not on their office but on their own ability to mobilize resources.” 27 In this way, the township’s intervention actively contributes to effective village self-governance. The 1998 experimentation with directly electing township level officials has unsurprisingly also drawn a considerable amount of scholarly review and attention. Reform-minded local party leaders initiated elections for magistrate positions in Buyun Township in Sichuan province without the expressed consent of the central party-state. While the Organic Law does leave much of the specifics of policy implementation to each respective locality, the election of posts higher than those prescribed in the Organic Law was a notably unauthorized interpretation of electoral democracy. Unsurprisingly, the central government declared the experiment to be unconstitutional and, interestingly, evoked China’s undertaking of the rule of law as the rationale behind shutting down the experiment. However sincere the central leadership might have been regarding the significance of constitutionality and the rule of law, scholars instead point to the fact that the township election experiment was a local invention as evidence of the democratizing influence growing out of the implementation of village-level electoral democracy. Furthermore, as townships comprise the lowest rung of the party-state political hierarchy, scholars accordingly place great importance with the potential of similar electoral experiments being held in the future. 28 The implications of village elections for village-level cadres are also an especially important aspect of village self-governance. As the basic administrative and managerial post of party-state, cadres play an important role in village-level governance and are arguably the most affected by village elections. Especially since the beginning of the reform era, relations between local level cadres and villagers have been particularly strained by the Jean Oi and Scott Rozelle, “Elections and Power: The Locus of Decision Making in Chinese Villages,” The China Quarterly 162 (2000): pp. 513 28 For an overview of the Buyun Township magistrate election of 1998, please see: Melanie Manion, “Chinese Democratization in Perspective: Electorates and Selectorates at the Township Level,” The China Quarterly, No. 163 (2000); Lisheng Dong, “Direct Township Elections: Latest Developments and Prospects,” Journal of Contemporary China (2006), pp. 503-515; Simon Shen, “Disharmony at the Grassroots Level: Possible Alienation Caused by Town-Level Direct Elections in China,” Journal of Chinese Political Science, (2010), pp. 191-203 27 — 18 — We the People’s Republic persistence of cadre corruption. Much of the available literature considers the effects that village elections have on keeping village cadre malfeasance in check and seeks to determine the capabilities of electoral institutions in improving the cadre-villager relationship. David Zweig and Chung Siu Fung, for instance, point out that village elections in several cases have resulted in high turnover rates of local cadres. This is a result villager actively ousting corrupt, imperious, or inefficient cadres with the ballot. Incumbent village cadres, in the theoretical realization of this development, are thus held to a political dynamic of accountability and responsiveness to villagers’ needs and wants, lest they end up ousted as well during the next election cycle.29 On a similar note, Manion asserts that there is a strong positive correlation with the quality of electoral procedures and cadre responsiveness and accountability. As a result, village elections strengthen the “congruence” between villagers’ interests and village cadres’ administration; village elections align cadre behavior more closely with villager needs and wants.30 However, other scholars offer evidence of continued disconnection between cadre behavior and villager interests, even when cadre posts are held accountable to regular elections. Cadres might, for example, willingly choose to carry out unpopular policies while ignoring policies that align best with villager interests. The likelihood of this so-called “selective policy implementation”—or the propensity of cadres to ignore or even actively go against the wishes of the villagers and their interests—increases the more removed the role of the central party-state in village affairs. The sense of autonomy and lack of top-down consequences to a degree ‘empowers’ cadres to abuse the powers of their office, obviously resulting in frequently poor local governance.31 Village Elections and Rural Villagers In context of the macro view of the state’s strict control of political power, the implications of the role of rural Chinese villagers in the political system is frequently understated. However, with the advent of the Organic David Zweig and Chung Siu Fung, “Elections, Democratic Values, and Economic Development in Rural China,” Journal of Contemporary China 16(50), pp. 25-45 30 Melanie Manion, “The Electoral Connection in the Chinese Countryside,” American Political Science Review Vol. 90 No. 4, (1996), pp. 736-748 31 Kevin J. O’Brien and Lianjiang Li, “Selective Policy Implementation in Rural China,” Comparative Politics, 31(2), pp. 167-186 29 — 19 — Jace T. White Law and village self-government, Chinese villagers became key players in rural China’s electoral experiment as a result. After all, village elections and village self-government first grew out grassroots responses by the villagers themselves to fill the political vacuum left in the wake of rural decommunization and provide for rural governance and stability. It was only later that the party-state endorsed village self-government and began the process of institutionalizing the political role of the rural villager through village electoral democracy. In light of the political developments throughout the countryside, the significance of role of the villager in rural politics, therefore, cannot continue to be understated. The economic reforms of the past four decades have resulted in the significant transformation of not only the rural Chinese economic system but also the people of rural China. Sweeping liberalization of the rural Chinese economy since the introduction of the household responsibility system has empowered rural Chinese with broadened economic freedoms. As a result, demands for proper political channels to defend their economic rights and interests are notably increasing and political reform is becoming a necessity. The institutionalization of village self-government and village elections has resulted in foundational institutions of democratic village self-governance, in turn exposing rural Chinese to democratic processes and values. The rural countryside is therefore also actively engaged in civic development as well. That is to say, village self-government is driving the transformation of the rural Chinese peasantry into the rural Chinese citizenry. Most scholars agree that village elections have initiated an incremental process of broadening villager involvement in the Chinese political system. 32 As the principal agents in village self-government, villagers are notably impacted through the implementation of village elections. In particular, village elections hold certain implications vis-à-vis the empowerment of the voting rural population, namely evolving dynamics of political efficacy, participation and voting behavior, and attitudes toward democracy. The trends of political efficacy of voting villagers reveal much about not only the quality of elections but also the general prospects for democracy to take root in China as well. Political efficacy, in the case of democratic elections, refers to the general notion that voters feel their participation See: Kevin J. O’Brien, “Villagers, Elections, and Citizenship in Contemporary China,” Modern China 27(4): Tianjin Shi, “Village Committee Elections in China: Institutionalist Tactics for Democracy,” World Politics 51(3): Robert Pastor and Qingshan Tan, “The Meaning of Chinese Village Elections,” The China Quarterly 162 32 — 20 — We the People’s Republic matters and that similarly their votes are significant for the policy-making process. More specifically, efficacy is further categorized into internal and external efficacy—Internal efficacy referring to the belief that one understands and therefore participates in politics and external referring to the belief that one’s participation is effective and that the government responds to the participation. Some scholars assert that a positive correlation exists between the quality and degree of efficient village-level electoral democracy and villager political efficacy. Furthermore, these scholars also assert that building political efficacy is especially significant for local dynamics of governance. Lianjiang Li, for one, concludes that the enhanced political efficacy felt by voting villagers may lead to increased political participation, thereby also affecting the nature and dynamics of village-level governance. He goes on to note that this enhanced villager political efficacy, when coupled with unresponsive cadres, unsurprisingly creates tensions in local governance. This tension may continue further up the political chain if cadres become responsive but party secretaries do not, for example. Therefore, Li also posits that increasing political efficacy may be evidence that the idea of political power stems from the people is taking root among villagers, thereby also changing villagers’ understanding of what constitutes political legitimacy.33 Similarly, some scholars also claim that the real significance of political efficacy lies in villagers perceiving village elections as meaningful. When villagers care about village elections and the quality of post-election governance, they are more likely to continue to participate politically and thereby influence cadres to similarly care about elections, as their offices are at stake as a result. Villager political efficacy as a result theoretically reinforces the congruence of villager and cadre views and opinions.34 However, some analysts present contrary evidence that enhanced political efficacy may in some cases dissuade some voters from participation in village elections. For example, Jie Chen and Yang Zhong contend that more educated, internally efficacious voters are less inclined to vote in elections if electoral procedures are viewed as poorly implemented, fraudulent or only nominally democratic and of little significance to postLianjiang Li, “The Empowering Effect of Village Elections in China,” Asian Survey Vol. 43, No. 4 (2003), pp. 648-662 34 Qingshan Tan and Xin Qiushui, “Village Elections and Governance: Do Villagers Care?” Journal of Contemporary China (2007), pp. 581-599; Zhong Zishu and Wang Yugang, “The Relationship Between Political Participation and Rural Grassroots Unites in China,” Management Science and Engineering, Vol. 5, Issue 2, pp. 108-113 33 — 21 — Jace T. White election governance. More specifically they cite semi-competitive elections and the local-government’s preclusion of fully inclusive, competitive elections as a cause for politically efficacious, democratically oriented villagers to abstain from voting in said elections. 35 Similarly, there is evidence that poorly managed or unfair elections have a negative effect on villager support for democratic self-government. Jens Kolhammar, for instance, posits that poorly carried out elections may produce the exact opposite effect on voter political efficacy, instead producing feelings of disaffection and apathy with democratic processes. Kolhammar argues that so long as no concrete values of democratic elections are demonstrated to villagers, democratic selfgovernance will fail to take root. This may, in other words, result in the political alienation of villagers or resulting complacency of the villagers with the political status quo.36 Accordingly, some scholars also take issue with the assumption that village elections positively impact villager political efficacy. Some scholars evidence a ‘disconnect’ between village electoral democracy and democratic rights consciousness. As Zhaohui Hong contends, democratic electoral procedures are thoroughly institutionalized throughout much of the countryside, but villagers continue to understand very little of democracy and that this results in the institutionalization of village elections as just a meaningless formality.37 On a similar note, other analysts contend that the institutionalization of village electoral democracy does not necessarily equate to villagers becoming more conscious of democracy, but that the significance of villager participation manifests itself in other ways. Tianjin Shi, for instance, claims that while village elections improve a villager’s external efficacy, they have little to no effect on internal efficacy. By this, Shi means that the elections themselves do not result in the increase of a villager’s understanding of politics, but increases their understanding that their participation has an effect on the responsiveness of cadres.38 A sizable section of research also seeks to determine if a connection exists between political efficacy and participation and villager attitudes Jie Chen and Yang Zhong, “Why Do People Vote in Semicompetitive Elections in China,” The Journal of Politics 60(1), (Feb. 2002), pp. 178-197 36 Jens Kolhammar, “Democracy Outmaneuvered: Village Self-Governance in Yunnan Province,” China Elections and Governance Review, Issue 1 (2009), pp. 5-6 37 Zhaohui Hong, “’Three Disconnects’ and China’s Rural Election: A Case Study of Hailan Village,” Communist and Post-Communist Studies 39 (2006), pp. 29-32 38 Tianjin Shi, “Cultural Values and Democracy in Mainland China,” China Quarterly 162 (Jun. 2000), pp. 540-549 35 — 22 — We the People’s Republic towards democracy, particularly in terms of popular demand for democracy. That is, many scholars seek to determine whether regularly held village elections influence popular demand for more democratic rights. A host of analysts believe that villagers’ particular attitudes of support or nonsupport for democracy are reliant on their “subjective orientations,” or in other words, how external efficacy determines the assessment of whether democratic electoral institutions have resulted in positive or negative effects for cadre performance and local governance.39 David Zweig and Chung Siu Fung, for example, find in their research of 120 village elections in Anhui and Heilongjiang provinces that villagers generally demand more democratic rights as a result of the economy performing well and the role of village selfgovernance in providing for economic growth.40 O’Brien suggests that elections have resulted in the increased villager demand for more citizenship rights that they had not previously enjoyed. 41 Similarly, Gunter Schubert, in describing village elections as a “Trojan horse of democracy,” claims that the right to vote has empowered villagers politically and will in turn influence them to demand additional channels of political participation. 42 Many place this increased demand for democratic rights with the realization of villagers that electoral rights can also be used in order to vote out unpopular, untrustworthy and heretofore-untouchable cadres from office.43 Similarly, the general consensus among this school of thought is that these rights, norms, and institutions, once granted and shared with the peasantry, would become difficult for the party-state to retract without considerable adversity. Hang Lin, for example, asserts that even if village elections produce ineffective local governance, the democratic rights of Jie Chen, “Popular Support for Village Self-Government in China,” Asian Survey, (45)6, (2005), pp. 865-885 40 David Zweig and Chung Siu Fung, “Elections, Democratic Values, and Economic Development in Rural China,” Journal of Contemporary China 16(50), pp. 25-45 41 Kevin J. O’Brien, “Implementing Political Reform,” The Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, No. 32 (1994), pp. 33-59; Kevin J. O’Brien, “Villagers, Elections, and Citizenship in Contemporary China,” Modern China, 27:4 (Oct. 2001), pp. 425-429 42 Gunter Schubert, “Village Elections in the PRC: Trojan Horse of Democracy?” Project discussion paper No. 19, Institute of East Asian Studies (2002) 43 Kevin J. O’Brien and Lianjiang Li, “The Politics of Lodging Complaints in Chinese Villages,” China Quarterly 143 (Sep. 1995), pp. 756-783; Lianjiang Li and Kevin J. O’Brien, “Villagers and Popular Resistance in Contemporary China,” Modern China 22:1 (January 1996), pp. 28-61; Lianjiang Li, “Distrust in Government Leaders, Demand for Leadership Change, and Preference for Popular Elections in Rural China,” Political Behavior (2011) 33, pp. 291-311 39 — 23 — Jace T. White participation and voting become so institutionalized and entrenched among the people that it would be counterintuitive for the party-state to retract these rights.44Suzanne Ogden similarly argues that the institutionalization of democratic procedures coupled with villagers’ active exercise of their rights of participation in selecting village leadership will politicize and empower China’s peasantry, who in turn will assume less passive roles in continuing political reform. This sense of political efficacy and autonomy will theoretically undergo increasing institutionalization throughout subsequent election cycles and develop villager attitudes toward democracy.45 IV. Village Elections and Political Legitimacy Having taken into account the principal implications of village elections for the structures and dynamics of local governance as well as for the rural voting population as well, this paper will similarly examine the implications for the ruling party-state regime’s political legitimacy. In short, legitimacy in terms of Chinese politics will refer to the general perception that the ruling regime is lawful and should be obeyed. The issue of the partystate’s legitimacy is of particular significance to the future of political reform. Whether the party-state can shore up and preserve its rural legitimacy in many respects will determine if it can survive as the predominant political authority in China. Notions of political legitimacy in China have appropriately undergone significant transformation since the onset of economic reforms. Specifically, the fading specter of Maoist and socialist ideology as the raison d‘être of the CCP had been replaced with the guiding paramount importance of ensuring the progression of economic development. As a result, the foundation of the party-state’s legitimacy shifted from ideologically-based to performancebased. In particular, the party-state’s legitimacy is largely reliant on its performance in three key areas: promoting economic development, Hang Lin, “A Mixed Bag of Results: Village Elections in Contemporary China,” Asian Culture and History, Vol. 3, No. 1 (Jan. 2011), pp. 14-22 45 Suzanne Ogden, Inklings of Democracy in China (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2002), pp. 183-220 44 — 24 — We the People’s Republic maintaining social order, and defending China’s national unity and international status. 46 In providing the context for examining the Party-state’s rural legitimacy, Thorenson suggests that analysis of legitimacy should be further divided into two categories of internal and external. In this sense, internal legitimacy refers to the efficacy of basic-level cadres in working loyally and effectively towards the party-state’s agenda and avoiding corrupt behavior. And in the external sense, legitimacy is determined by the support for and acceptance of party-state rule by “the masses,” or simply the villagers.47 In many respects, the quality of local-level governance is an effective indicator of whether village elections contribute to the legitimacy of the party-state regime’s legitimacy. For instance, Schubert and Chen reference their case studies of village elections in Lishu County, Jilin Province that village-level democratic electoral practices contributes significantly to the quality of local governance and increased social order and stability.48 That is to say, whether or not village elections and the derivative norms and institutions result in effective governance signifies the legitimacy of the rural party-state political system. In terms of legitimacy, efficacious village selfgovernment reflects the party-state’s internal legitimacy and the involvement of villagers in efficacious village self-government reflects the party-state’s external legitimacy. Forefront in developments to the party-state’s internal legitimacy is also the gradual institutionalization of the party-state. This transformation of the Chinese party-state from an ideologically based political authority to a meritocratic, complex, and specialized “state-party” represents its “sophistication” as the governing political body, so to speak. 49 The institutionalization of the party-state particularly reflects the increasing importance of meritocracy and efficacy in governance throughout the Chinese political system. In this regard, party-state institutionalization reflects the increasing importance of public participation institutions, namely those of Stig Thorenson, “Parasites or Civilisers: The Legitimacy of the Chinese Communist Party in Rural Areas,” China: An International Journal, 1(2) (Sep. 2003), pp. 200-223 47 Ibid. pp. 203 48 Gunter Schubert and Xuelian Chen, “Village Elections in Contemporary China New Spaces for Generating Regime Legitimacy? Experiences from Lishu County,” China Perspectives 3 (2007), pp. 12-27 49 Bruce Buena de Mesquita and George W. Downs, “Development and Democracy,” Foreign Affairs 84(85), 2005; Yang Yao, “Chinese Way of Democratization,” China: An International Journal, Vol. 8 No. 2 (2010) 46 — 25 — Jace T. White village electoral democracy, in providing for the legitimacy of the Chinese political system at large.50 Along the lines of the legitimating aspects of party-state intervention, in many cases it was the reassertion of the local party secretary’s political authority in village-level affairs that has resulted in more effective local structures and dynamics of governance. In the case of Xinmi Township in Guangdong province in 1986 and 1994, the local party secretary, in advance of the Province’s approval, initiated the implementation of self-government structures in its villages. The party secretary organized representative local organizations that allowed villagers to vote on individual projects and voice their opinions and interests. This trend of party-led efforts to install these representative linkage institutions in most cases provided a stronger basis for more effective structures of village self-governance. This in turn allowed the party-state to shore up some lost legitimacy and to similarly create legitimate self-government institutions. However, the villager committees in these same villages in Guangdong are still strongly controlled by the party-state. This is evidenced by the high percentage of village committee members that were also members of the party. This demonstrates the cooptation of village selfgovernment posts to facilitate party control of local administration.51 Developments and innovation in village self-government represent significant strides in the party-state’s rural legitimation as well. For example, the party-state’s promotion of yijiantiao—or the concurrent holding of the two offices of village committee chair and village party secretary—in some villages reflects the de factor party-state acquisition of village administration and village self-government.52 On a similar note, the “Twoballot system” signifies the legitimation of the party-state’s rural political role as well, especially in regards to ensuring the institutionalization of accountability, responsiveness, and competence in rural governance. The institutionalization of village self-government may also be evidence of an evolving federalist dynamic within the Chinese political system. Specifically, this refers to the trends of decentralizing central partystate political power, or the increasing development of two distinct areas of Andrew J. Nathan, “Authoritarian Resilience,” Journal of Democracy 14 (2003), pp. 6-17 51 Richard Levy, “Village Elections, Transparency, and Anticorruption: Henan and Guangdong Provinces,” in Grassroots Reform in Contemporary China, ed. Elizabeth J. Perry et al. (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2007), pp. 22 52 Tan Qingshan, Village Elections in China, pp. 302 50 — 26 — We the People’s Republic the Chinese political system: the party-state on the macro level and village self-government on the micro-level. In recognizing that the institutionalization of democratic procedures, institutions and norms in local government has resulted in more effective governance, the trend of the withdrawal of certain party-state apparatuses, namely the township government, has resulted to boosts in legitimacy in some cases. While village-level governance may benefit from the continued political presence and operations of the party branch, the continued intervention of mid-level officials (i.e. townships) in many cases prevents effective local governance. As a result, party-state legitimacy is closely tied to the reduction of the role of township governments and higher government strata in local-level governance.53 Furthermore, the “lowering of the center’s political legitimacy” as phrased by Zheng Yongnian is evidence of a developing federalist system. That is to say, directly due to the institutionalization of village democratic elections, the lower a particular level of government is in the political hierarchy the more legitimacy it enjoys. Grassroots-level governments are, accordingly, empowered to take on their superiors because their legitimacy is theoretically derived from the voting citizenry of the village rather than political appointment from higher-ups. 54 This dynamic may be of special significance in conferring the village committee the possible capability to preclude township or party branch interference in effective, democratic village self-government. In this way, village elections contribute to the legitimate decentralization of the political system. The central party-state retains its legitimate rule, but in terms of local governance, local government officials in turn derive their political legitimacy from the voters through local electoral institutions, norms and procedures. Along the same lines, in consideration of the external legitimacy of the party-state, among the most important components is the support and approval of the villagers. Arguably, in village governance, it is the voting villagers who play the most significant role in determining the external legitimacy of local governance. Reinforcing norms and institutions of accountability and responsiveness are among the most significant implications of village elections for political legitimacy. The capacity of village elections to hold village level cadres accountable and responsive to local John James Kennedy, “Legitimacy with Chinese Characteristics: ‘Two Increases, One Reduction’,” Journal of Contemporary China 18(60) (2009), pp. 391-395 54 Zheng Yongnian, Will China Become Democratic? Elite, Class, and Regime Transition, Eastern Universities Press (2004), pp. 141 53 — 27 — Jace T. White voters’ interests is one of the most obvious indicators of its contributions to the party-state’s external legitimacy. The institutionalization of representative institutions is a similarly significant aspect of the legitimating effects of village self-government. As a particularly important component of village self-government, the institutionalization of representative channels in local governance allow for both the effective representation of villager interests and the strengthening of the party-state’s embeddedness in local governance. Very notable are the representative electoral institutions that have a hand in determining the local administration of economic and financial affairs. Most significantly, village elections represent the representative institutionalization of local economic affairs.55 As de-collectivization deprived the state of traditional sources of revenue and facilitated China’s transition from a rentier state to a tax-based state, the need for taxation by consent necessitated the institutionalization of channels for representation. The opening of these channels in turn contributes to the legitimation of the partystate’s local economic role. As an example, Yan Xiaojun references the particular experience of the villages of “Q County” with the legitimating role of representative economic institutions. Several village committees in Q County became “mini-parliaments” of sorts, in several cases deciding on important public issues and providing a check on party-state operations. These village committees similarly acted as linkage institutions, or public forums of sorts, allowing for the institutional channels necessary for effective local level governance of economic concerns and issues. 56 Overall, the development of “taxation with representation” reflects the legitimate institutionalization of grassroots governance organizations. Yan Xiaojun, “Democratizing power of Economic Reform,” Problems of PostCommunism, 58(3) (Jun. 2011), pp. 39-52 56 Ibid. pp. 43 55 — 28 —