1 Ethnic Homogeneity, Group Antagonism, and State Financial Support for Higher Education John M. Foster Southern Illinois University Edwardsville Jacob Fowles University of Kansas PLEASE DO NOT CITE WITHOUT THE AUTHORS’ PERMISSION 2 Ethnic Homogeneity, Group Antagonism, and State Financial Support for Higher Education John M. Foster Southern Illinois University Edwardsville Jacob Fowles University of Kansas Abstract A growing literature suggests that the presence of multiple ethnic groups could lead to lower public expenditures. This inverse relationship may be attributable to the diversity in policy preferences which tends to coincide with ethnic diversity. When policy preferences vary widely among constituents, the subjective benefits of collective action are smaller. The subjective benefits of public spending may also be lower when the beneficiaries tend to be ethnic outsiders. For these reasons, ethnic diversity may steer the political process toward a lower level of public spending. These negative effects of diversity may be offset by positive social contact between ethnic groups. The authors investigate the effects of ethnic diversity on state higher education spending with a model that allows the effect of ethnic diversity to be mediated by the degree of positive social contact between groups, which we measure with the intermarriage rate. We find that ethnic diversity only has a statistically-significant and negative impact on state appropriations to universities in states with low intermarriage rates. The magnitude of the negative effect diminishes with the rate of intermarriage JEL: I23 KEYWORDS: Politics of race, higher education finance, redistribution 3 Introduction An extensive literature has documented a large increase in income inequality in the United States in recent decades. With the shift of production away from manufacturing and toward the service and technology sectors, educational attainment has become a powerful determinant of one’s position in the income distribution. Since the 1970’s, real earnings of adults with only a high school diploma have declined significantly. Between 1972 and 2005, the average income of high school graduates fell from $42,000 (in constant year 2003 dollars) to $30,000, which is a decrease of about one-third. By contrast, real earnings for the collegeeducated have held steady; among women, they have risen (Dynarski 2008). Due to the growing divide between those with and without a college degree, subsidies for higher education are likely to be a prominent component of any policy platform geared toward reducing income inequality. The political efficacy of public spending, including higher education subsidies, is likely to be influenced by the ethnic demographic context (Alesina et al 2000). The presence of multiple ethnic groups could increase the political costs of higher education subsidization for two reasons. First, higher-income ethnic groups may be less inclined to support public spending when the primary beneficiaries tend to be members of other ethnic groups. Second, preferences for public spending vary among different ethnic groups. With a heterogeneous population, the political process may be less likely to produce a fiscal platform that is close to one’s preferred service package. Thus, ethnic heterogeneity may reduce the benefits that one expects to obtain from numerous categories of public spending, including higher education subsidization, which leads one to prefer a smaller public sector. On the other hand, tensions between ethnic groups 4 have subsided over the past thirty years. Consequently, biases against public spending driven by ethnic divisions may be eroding. We extend the literature by examining the effects of ethnic diversity and the amiability of ethnic group relations on three categories of state higher education spending: state appropriations to public universities, need-based student aid, and non-need-based aid. This study is the first positive analysis of state higher education financial support that examines the effects of both ethnic diversity and the amiability of ethnic group relations. We use data on the 50 states for 1980 to 2009. We measure ethnic diversity with the complement of a Herfindahl index of ethnic group concentration. We use the intermarriage rate as a proxy for the congeniality between groups. We utilize data on the fifty states for 1980 to 2009. We use the fixed effects specification to control for time invariant state characteristics. We find that a state’s ethnic demographic context influences state appropriations to public universities but does not affect need-based or non-need-based student aid. Ethnic diversity is inversely-related to state appropriations. The effect of ethnic diversity depends on the intermarriage rate. In states with relatively high rates of intermarriage, the effect of ethnic diversity on state appropriations is not significantly different from zero. The intermarriage rate has a positive effect on state appropriations which increases with the level of ethnic diversity. Neither category of student aid is significantly affected by the intermarriage rate, regardless of the level of ethnic diversity. In the following section, we discuss the motives that states might have to subsidize higher education along with the literature on the effects of ethnic heterogeneity and ethnic group antagonism on the demand for public services. We then present our analysis of the effects of state ethnic demographics on state financial support for higher education. 5 Motives for Subsidizing Higher Education and Voter Preferences in Multiethnic Environments In the United States, higher education is financed with a combination of user charges and tax-financed subsidies. Experts and policymakers have prescribed subsidies for higher education as a means for states to capture the positive spillovers associated with the activities carried out by colleges and universities, to promote access to higher education for middle- and lower-income households, and to retain high-quality students. States have subsidized higher education through three mechanisms: transfers to public universities, need-based direct aid to students to cover all or a portion of tuition, and tuition assistance based on criteria other than need such as academic achievement, military service, or entry into a particular field of study such as education or nursing. State appropriations to public universities constitute the vast majority of state subsidy dollars, averaging 91 percent of state higher education spending in 2009. However, the share of state higher education spending that is devoted to direct aid to students exceeds 15 percent in seven states (Georgia, Florida, Pennsylvania, South Carolina, Tennessee, Vermont, and West Virginia). State appropriations to public universities are used to reduce tuition and fees, support research, and finance various services. The positive spillovers attributed to higher education include research that confers broad economic benefits and the enrichment of civic life that stems from the presence of a highlyeducated population. The products of research tend to become part of the public domain. Thus, a pure market would not fully compensate researchers. As a result, individuals and firms acting non-cooperatively would most likely underinvest in research in a pure market economy. Governments can enhance efficiency by subsidizing research activities. The cost-benefit analyses 6 of academic research that have been conducted have found large net benefits. For example, Griliches (1957) estimates the social rate of return on hybrid corn seed to be 700 percent and that the rate of return of all agricultural research was between 35 and 75 percent.1 Economic theory suggests that positive spillovers can also be generated by instructional activities. Educated citizens are likely to be more informed voters and more effective civic leaders. Dee (2003) and Milligan et al (2004) find that educational attainment is positivelyrelated to voter participation. Dee (2003) also finds a direct relationship between educational attainment and newspaper readership and support for free speech. The effect of subsidies on the level of positive spillovers from higher education instruction depends on the effects of those subsidies on college enrollment and degree completion, or on the price elasticity of demand for higher education. Most studies find modest responses to changes in the tuition price. Researchers have obtained a range of estimates that suggests that a $1,000 reduction in tuition is likely to lead to increases of enrollment falling between 3 and 7 percent (Deming and Dynarski 2009). Dynarski (2003) and Zhang and Ness (2012) attribute large portions of these effects to reductions in the fraction of college-bound high school graduates attending universities out-of-state. Dynarski (2008) finds that the large-scale merit aid programs introduced in Georgia and Arkansas in the early 1990’s increased college degree attainment by 3 to 4 percentage points. The effects are about twice as large for Hispanic and nonwhite women, which suggests that disadvantaged groups are relatively sensitive to the costs of higher education. These estimates suggest that the generation of positive spillovers from instruction is probably not the most compelling motive for the subsidization of higher education. 1 See Rizzo (2004) for a review of the literature. 7 Even though subsidies for higher education do not have large impacts on enrollment and degree attainment, they are important forms of in-kind redistribution. State appropriations to public universities and direct student aid programs reduce the amount of debt that most students take on in order to finance their studies. These subsidies may also reduce the amount of time that they must spend working while studying which may enable them to complete their education faster. Views on the progressivity of state funding for higher education have not been unanimous. Hanson and Weisbrod (1969) find that the incidence of higher education financing in California is regressive. However, the authors did not take the progressivity of the tax system into account. Johnson (2006), analyzing data for all 50 states, examines the distribution of state appropriations across income groups net of state taxes and finds a mildly progressive incidence pattern since wealthy households pay relatively large shares of state taxes and are less likely to utilize public universities. Systematic studies of the incidence of direct aid programs have not been carried out. Because need-based aid is targeted to individuals from needy families, one would expect the incidence of those transfers, net of taxation, to be highly progressive. Why would state governments make these considerable in-kind transfers instead of offering more cash assistance? In-kind transfers in the form of higher education subsidies may be politically-desirable because they address what James Buchanan (1957) termed the “Samaritan’s Dilemma.” The Samaritan’s Dilemma stems from two problems: (1) the moral hazard created by transfers to those who are currently poor; and (2) the inability of the Samaritan, in this case the government, to commit to a policy of zero future assistance for current recipients who could have lifted themselves out of poverty but chose not to do so. Needy individuals who receive aid in the present may reasonably expect to receive aid in the future if they continue to be poor. Bruce and Waldman (1991) use the concept of the Samaritan’s Dilemma to show that providing at least a 8 portion of the transfer in the form of an illiquid investment, such as a subsidy for human capital investment, enhances efficiency by reducing the likelihood that current recipients will need assistance in the future. State subsidies for higher education potentially promote a number of public objectives. The optimal level of subsidization depends on the relative weight that the public attaches to those objectives relative to other public service needs and private consumption. The relative weight that states attach to higher education subsidization varies widely. In 2009, total state subsidies for higher education per full-time-equivalent public university student averaged $7,732, ranging from $3,743 in New Hampshire to $15,244 in Alaska. A scarcely-examined determinant of this variation across states is their ethnic demographic context. The presence of diverse ethnic groups could place downward pressure on the demand for government intervention. If the population is divided into multiple ethnic groups with different preferences for the level of public spending and the manner in which public programs are delivered (e.g. divided opinion over what should be the curriculum of public schools), then the subjective benefits of public provision are lower, entailing less public support (Alesina and Spaloare 1997). Alesina, Baqir, and Easterly (1999) look at U.S. urban areas and find that shares of spending on infrastructure and K-12 education are inversely-related to racial heterogeneity. The concentration of ethnic others in the low end of the income distribution may also weaken altruism among higher income ethnic groups. There is evidence that the ethnic congruence between the poor and non-poor is directly-related to redistribution on the both the expenditure and revenue sides. Orr (1976), Alesina et al (2000), and Luttmer (2001) find an inverse relationship between ethnic heterogeneity and welfare spending among the U.S. states. Alesina et al (2000) obtain similar results from a cross-country study and conclude that ethnic divisions are 9 a significant part of the explanation for why the United States never developed a European-style welfare state. Foster (2013) finds that tax progressivity is lower in American states in which the poor and non-poor tend to come from different ethnic groups, all else equal. The effect of ethnic diversity on the demand for public spending is likely to depend on the degree of antagonism between ethnic groups. Lind (2007) presents a theoretical model in which the negative effect of ethnic diversity on public spending increases with the degree of group antagonism. He examines the effects of group antagonism on support for welfare spending with an analysis of data from the General Social Survey. Lind finds that white respondents who had recently had African Americans as guests in their homes favored higher levels of welfare spending, ceteris paribus. Other studies have found a direct relationship between positive social contact between ethnic groups and support for policies that could generally be labeled progressive. Boisjoly et al (2006) find that white college students who were randomly assigned African- American roommates were more likely to be supportive of affirmative action policies. In their study of the racial attitudes and policy preferences of Texas adults, Stein et al (2000) find that white attitudes toward immigration were less favorable the more diverse the county if contact with Hispanics was low but not if the diverse context led to frequent contact with Hispanics, in which case there were more favorable attitudes to immigration. Roch and Rushton (2011) find that white voters in more segregated Alabama counties were less likely to support a state referendum that would have significantly increased the progressivity of the state tax system and used the additional revenue for K-12 education. Foster (2013) finds that the average level of residential segregation in a state is inversely related to state and local tax progressivity. Thus, the effect of diversity on support for public spending appears to be associated with the degree of social contact between ethnic groups. It is important to note that residential segregation could 10 also reflect the degree to which the most prosperous ethnic group is amiably-disposed toward other ethnic groups in the first place. Whether social contact between different ethnic groups causes or reflects congeniality between ethnic groups, we believe that measures of social contact can function as proxies for the amiability of ethnic group relations. Evidence provided by survey data and data on individual choices suggest that tensions between ethnic groups have subsided considerably over the past three decades. In 1972, 37 percent of respondents to the General Social Survey (GSS) claimed to be in favor of a law against interracial marriage. In 2002, only 10 percent of respondents expressed support for such a law. One can argue that these changes in survey responses reveal more about mores of political correctness than about actual preferences, but there have been accompanying changes in behavior as well. Between 1980 and 2009, the percentage of married individuals with a spouse from an ethnic group other than their own increased from around 5 percent to 8 percent, which is an increase of almost 60 percent. The percentage of white GSS respondents who claimed to be members of an integrated church rose from 34 percent in 1978 to 48 percent in 1994. It is possible that the growing social integration of non-white groups has weakened biases against public spending driven by ethnic divisions. This study extends the literature by examining the effects of both ethnic diversity and the amiability of ethnic group relations on state higher education spending. We estimate a model of state higher education spending as a function of the overall ethnic diversity of the population, the amiability of ethnic group relations, which we measure with the percentage of married individuals who are married to a person from a different ethnic group (i.e. the intermarriage rate), the population shares of the major minority groups, and the standard controls. We allow the 11 effect of ethnic diversity to depend on the intermarriage rate. The following section describes our research design in detail. Empirical Implementation The data cover state spending on higher education by the 50 states for 1980 to 2009. We model three types of state higher education spending (state appropriations to public universities, non-need-based aid, and need-based aid) as functions of state demographic, economic, and political characteristics from the previous year. The empirical model can be summarized by πππ‘ = π½0 + π½1 πΈππ‘−1 + π½2 πΌππ‘−1 + π½3 (πΈππ‘−1 ∗ πΌππ‘−1 ) + π½4 π»ππ‘−1 + π½5 π΄ππ‘−1 + π½6 πππ‘−1 + (1) π½7 πππ‘−1 + ππ + ππ‘ + vππ‘ The term Eit-1 denotes ethnic diversity while πΌππ‘−1 is the intermarriage rate. π»ππ‘−1 , π΄ππ‘−1 , πππ‘−1 , denote the Hispanic, African-American, and “Other” population shares, respectively. The standard control variables are given by πππ‘−1 . Lagging the determinants by one year allows for the possibility that policymakers cannot immediately adjust state policy in response to changes in economic, demographic, and political parameters. State and year fixed effects are given by ππ and ππ‘ , respectively. The parameter vππ‘ is a mean-zero, random error term. We measure ethnic diversity with the probability that two people randomly drawn from a state’s population are from k different ethnic groups. This probability is given by: Ethnic Diversity = 1- ∑∀π(πππ. πβππππ )2 We expect ethnic diversity to be inversely-related to all three forms of higher education spending. The intermarriage rate is the percentage of married individuals who married outside of their own ethnic group. We expect the intermarriage rate to be positively-related to state higher 12 education spending since it reflects the cessation of tension between ethnic groups and should reflect the erosion of differences in spending levels based solely on ethnic divisions. To derive the intermarriage rate and the ethnic diversity measure, we divided state populations into Hispanics, non-Hispanic whites, non-Hispanic African-Americans, and non-Hispanic, non-white “others,” with “others” including Native Americans, Asians, Pacific Islanders, and a residual category. We interact the ethnic diversity index with the intermarriage rate since the political costs of public spending that benefits ethnic outsiders may be lower (higher) in states that are characterized by low (high) degrees of ethnic tension. Lind’s (2007) theoretical analysis demonstrated that the effects of an increase (decrease) in the degree of antagonism between ethnic groups on public spending are directly related to the level of ethnic diversity. Thus, the effect of intermarriage on state higher education spending may increase with the level of ethnic diversity. The diversity index captures the extent to which the population is ethnically fragmented. However, it does not provide information on the relative size of each ethnic group. This information is likely to be pertinent since the policy preferences of certain nonwhite groups tend to differ not just from those of whites but also from those of other nonwhite groups. Analysis of survey data conducted by Alesina and La Ferrara (2003) indicates that African-Americans are more supportive of redistribution, even with income held constant. Brunner et al (2012) find that African-Americans, Hispanics, and respondents falling into a residual, non-white, non-Hispanic category favor progressive fiscal policies more strongly than whites. Preferences among the non-white groups are not uniform. African-Americans are more supportive of government intervention than Hispanics while Hispanics are more supportive of such policies than other non-white groups. Thus, the population shares of minority groups are likely to be directly-related to the political attractiveness of government intervention, with the 13 African-American population share having the strongest effect. For these reasons, the models include the African-American, Hispanic, and Other Non-Hispanic population shares. The vector πππ‘−1 consists of measures of state economic, demographic, and political characteristics. The natural log of state GDP per-capita (in $1,000s of year 2005 dollars) is included to control for a state’s resources. The model also includes the state Gini coefficient. The level of income inequality in a state is likely to affect its spending priorities. A high degree of inequality may increase demand for fiscal platforms that transfer income from the wealthy to middle and lower-income households. Thus, we expect the Gini coefficient to be positivelyrelated to both types of student aid. The effect of income inequality on state appropriations per FTE public university student is difficult to predict since there is considerable variation within many states in the socioeconomic groups served by public universities. An increase in income inequality could lead to a shift in state appropriations away from public universities that serve predominantly upper-income students and toward public universities that serve the less well-off. The relative weight that state policymakers place on the subsidization of higher education could depend on the distribution of state population across age groups. Thus, the models include the population shares of three age groups that compete for sizable shares of state expenditure: traditional elementary and secondary school-age youths (age 5-17), traditional college-age adults (age 18-24), and the elderly (age 65 or older). The percentage of college students who are Pell grant recipients is included since the receipt of Pell grants by students in a state may crowd out state assistance. The percentage of adults with a college degree is included since it may influence the demand for higher education. Alternatively, states with relatively large supplies of skilled labor may be less inclined to subsidize higher education. 14 The model also includes measures of a state’s ideological orientation. We use the measure of average voter liberalism developed by Berry et al (1998). We expect a greater degree of liberalism among voters to be positively-related to need-based student aid. The effects of average voter liberalism on non-need-based aid depend on the weight that liberal voters place on transfers to middle-class households relative to redistributive programs that provide more concentrated benefits to the poor and near-poor. The expected signs on average voter liberalism are ambiguous in the state appropriations equation since changes in those regressors could lead to shifts in the distribution of appropriations among institutions within states. The models include the private university share of college enrollments. The prominence of private universities is likely to be inversely-related to voter demand for state subsidies to public universities. We include year indicators to control for national economic and policy shocks. We carry out the fixed effects transformation to control for time-invariant state idiosyncrasies. We experimented with the random effects specification and carried out the Hausman test determine if the estimates differed significantly from those obtained with the fixed effects specification. The tests strongly rejected the null hypothesis of zero difference for all three equations. This suggests that at least one of the regressors is correlated with the state fixed effects. Consequently, the fixed effects transformation is necessary to obtain consistent estimates. The standard errors are clustered by state. Consequently, the inference statistics are robust to heteroskedasticity and within-state autocorrelation. Summary statistics are presented in Table 1. Results The ordinary least squares results are presented in Table 2. Ethnic diversity is significantly and negatively related to state appropriations to public universities per FTE public 15 university student but is insignificant in the other models. The marginal effect of ethnic diversity on any of the three state higher education spending equations depends on the interaction between diversity and the intermarriage rate. Thus, we obtain the formula for the marginal effect by differentiating the empirical model with respect to ethnic diversity, which yields: ππππ‘ = π½1 + π½3 πΌππ‘−1 ππΈππ‘−1 (2) where π½1 is the coefficient on ethnic fractionalization and π½3 is the coefficient on the interaction term.2 We evaluate equation (2) at all values of intermarriage for 1980 and 2009. We used the delta method to obtain the standard error of each marginal effect. We present the results for all 50 states and for each year in Tables 3 and 4, respectively. We see that the marginal effect of ethnic diversity on state appropriations to public universities is negative for almost all values of the intermarriage rate, the sole exception being Hawaii in 2009, which has such a high rate of intermarriage that an increase in ethnic diversity of one standard deviation has a small positive effect. The magnitude of the negative effect and its statistical significance decrease as the intermarriage rate increases. The highest intermarriage rate at which the marginal effect of ethnic diversity on state appropriations is statistically significant is around 4.5 percent in 1980 and in 2009. For states with intermarriage rates less than or equal to 4.5 percent, an increase in ethnic diversity of one standard deviation leads to reductions in state appropriations ranging from 12 to 15 percent. The number of states with intermarriage rates below the threshold of statistical 2 We conducted linear Wald tests of the joint significance of the interaction term and each of its constituent variables. Ethnic diversity and the interaction term are jointly significant at the 95 percent confidence level in the state appropriations equation but not in the student aid equations. We found the same significance pattern with tests of the joint significance of the interaction term and the intermarriage rate. 16 significance fell from 27 in 1980 to 17 in 2009.3 Thus, the results indicate that the growing amiability of ethnic group relations, which is captured so some extent by the intermarriage rate, has weakened the influence of ethnic diversity on state appropriations to public universities in many states. Controlling for other factors, ethnic diversity is not significantly related to either type of student aid for any of the values of the intermarriage rate in the 2009 portion of the sample. The intermarriage rate is positively-related to state appropriations to public universities per FTE public university student in all states except for those that are relatively homogeneous (see Table 5). The lowest value of the ethnic diversity index that coincides with a significant effect of the intermarriage rate on state appropriations is Ohio’s 2009 value of 0.31, which corresponds to the 31st percentile of the 2009 distribution of the ethnic diversity index. The effects of a one-standard-deviation increase in the intermarriage rate on state appropriations to public universities among states with levels of ethnic diversity equal to 0.31 or greater range from an increase of 2.5 percent for Ohio to 8.3 percent for California. Between 1980 and 2009, the intermarriage rate increased from about 5 percent to about 8 percent, on average. This shift, which presumably reflects an increase in the congeniality of ethnic group relations, increased state appropriations to public universities by around 3 percent in states with the 2009 average level of ethnic diversity. The estimated effects of the growth of intermarriage are considerably higher in 5 states that are relatively heterogeneous and experienced above-average increases in the intermarriage rate. In Arizona, California, New Jersey, Nevada, and Texas, the intermarriage rate increased by around 5 percentage points, on average. The estimates indicate that state appropriations to public universities were around 9 to 10 percent higher than they otherwise 3 Two of the 17 states—New Hampshire and West Virginia—are not interesting cases because their levels of ethnic diversity are more than one standard deviation below the national average. 17 would have been. These estimated increases translate into dollar amounts per FTE public university student ranging from $426 in Arizona to $817 in Nevada. The intermarriage rate is not significantly related to either form of student aid for any value of ethnic fractionalization found in the 2009 portion of our sample. Other results are worth mentioning briefly. The African-American share is significantly and positively related to state appropriations to public universities, but is insignificant in the equations for student aid. The Hispanic share of the population and the share of the population that consists of “Other” non-Hispanic individuals are not statistically significant in any of the state higher education spending equations. Holding all other relevant variables constant, an increase in the African-American population share of one standard deviation increases state appropriations by about 44 percent. Non-need-based aid is influenced primarily by the certain demographic characteristics. The Gini coefficient is inversely related to non-need-based aid. It is possible that an increase in income inequality prompts state governments to divert resources away from scholarships and toward programs that confer more immediate benefits to the poor and near-poor. The percentage of adults with a bachelor’s degree is inversely related to nonneed-based aid. If a state has a relatively large college-educated population, then the benefits from using scholarships to “stem the brain drain” may be smaller, all else equal. The population share of traditional college-age adults is inversely related to both state appropriations to public universities and non-need-based aid. The aggregate cost of a given per-student subsidy increases with the share of the population constituted by potential students. The political costs associated with this “price effect” of the population share of traditional college-age adults appear to outweigh the political benefits of subsidizing that group. Need-based-aid is determined primarily 18 by state resources. State GDP per-capita is positively related to state appropriations with an elasticity of 1.82. Conclusion Previous studies have identified two channels through which ethnic diversity can influence voter demand for and government supply of public services. The presence of multiple ethnic groups may put downward pressure on support for redistribution among all groups since the political process is less likely to produce a public services bundle that is close one’s preferred bundle. Additionally, altruism among higher income ethnic groups may decrease with the proportion of beneficiaries from public spending who are members of other groups. These negative effects of diversity may be offset by the rise of positive social interaction between ethnic groups that took place over the latter decades of the 20th century. This study extends the literature by using an empirical model that allows the effect of ethnic diversity on state higher education spending to be mediated by level of antagonism between ethnic groups. We gauge the degree of tension between ethnic groups with the intermarriage rate. Consistent with previous studies, we find that ethnic diversity is inversely related to state appropriations to public universities for states with low intermarriage rates. In the most recent year in our sample, in states with intermarriage rates above roughly the 33rd percentile of the distribution, the effect of ethnic diversity on state appropriations is not significantly different from zero. Our estimates indicate that the rise of intermarriage over the course of our 29 year sample has had a direct positive effect on state appropriations to public universities. This direct effect is only substantial in magnitude in states that are characterized by 19 above-average levels of ethnic diversity. Increases in the intermarriage rate have supported state higher education spending indirectly by reducing the number of states in which ethnic diversity consistently inhibits state higher education spending. The literature on the political economy of subnational budgets could be extended further by applying our empirical model to other important areas of state spending such as K-12 education, Temporary Aid to Needy Families (TANF), and state Medicaid programs. Positive social interaction between ethnic groups has increased but additional analysis is necessary to determine whether the United States is evolving into a society in which variation in fiscal policy among states is driven primarily by differences in economic circumstances and in voters’ conceptions of economic justice. 20 References Alesina, Alberto, Edward Glaeser, and Bruce Sacerdote. 2000. Why doesn’t the U.S. have a European-style welfare system? NBER Working Paper No. 8524. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved on August 11, 2013, at http://www.nber.org/papers/w8524 Alesina, Alberto, Reza Baqir, and William Easterly. 1999. Public goods and ethnic divisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (4): 1243-1284. Alesina, Alberto, and Eliana La Ferrara. 2005. Preferences for redistribution in the land of opportunities. Journal of Public Economics 89 (6): 897-931. Alesina, Alberto, and Enrico Spaloare. 1997. On the number and size of nations. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4): 1027-1056. Berry, W. D., R.C. Fording, R.L. Hanson, and Evan J. Ringquist. 1998. Measuring citizen and government ideology in the American states, 1960-1993. American Journal of Political Science, 42, 327-348. Boisjoly, Johanne, Greg J. Duncan, Michael Kramer, Don M. Levy, and Jacques Eccles. 2006. Empathy or apathy? The impact of diversity. The American Economic Review 96 (5): 1890-1905. Bruce, Neil and Michael Waldman. 1991. Transfers in kind: They can be efficient and nonpaternalistic. The American Economic Review 81 (5): 1345-1351. Brunner, Eric, Stephen L. Ross, and Ebonya Washington. 2011. Economics and policy preferences: Causal evidence of the impact of economic conditions on support for redistribution and other ballot proposals. The Review of Economics and Statistics 93 (3): 888-906. Buchanan, James M. 1957. The samaritan’s dilemma. In Edmund S. Phelps, ed., Altruism, Morality, and Economic Theory, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1975, 71-85. Dee, Thomas S. 2003. Are there civic returns to higher education? NBER Working Paper w9588. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Deming, David, and Susan M. Dynarski. 2009. Into college, out of poverty? Policies to increase the postsecondary attainment of the poor. NBER Working Paper w15387. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Dynarski, Susan M. 2003. Does aid matter? Measuring the effect of student aid on college attendance and completion. The American Economic Review 93 (1): 279-288. 21 Dynarski, Susan M. 2008. Building the stock of college-educated labor. Journal of Human Resources, 43(3): 576-608. Foster, John M. 2013. Voter ideology, economic factors, and state and local tax progressivity. Public Finance Review 41 (2): 177-202. Griliches, Zvi. 1957. Hybrid corn: An exploration in the economics of technological change. Econometrica 25 (4): 501-522. Hansen, W. Lee and Burton A. Weisbrod. 1969. The distribution of the costs and benefits of public higher education: The case of California. Journal of Human Resources 4 (2): 176-191. Johnson, W.R. 2006. Are public subsidies to higher education regressive? Education Finance and Policy, 1 (3), 288-315. Lind, Jo Thori. 2007. Fractionalization and the size of government. Journal of Public Economics 91 (1-2): 51-76. Luttmer, Erzo F.P. 2001. Group loyalty and the taste for redistribution. Journal of Political Economy 109 (4): 500-528. Milligan, Kevin, Enrico Moretti and Philip Orsopoulis. 2004. Does education improve citizenship? Evidence from the U.S. and the U.K. Journal of Public Economics 88 (9-10): 16671695. Orr, Larry L. 1976. Income transfers as a public good: An application to AFDC. The American Economic Review 66 (3): 359-371. Rizzo, M.J. 2004. The public interest in higher education. CHERI Working Paper #55. Retrieved on August 11, 2013, from http://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/student/10/ Roch, Christine H. and Michael Rushton. 2008. Racial context and voting over taxes: Evidence from a referendum in Alabama. Public Finance Review 36 (5): 614-634. Stein, Robert M. Stephanie Shirley Post, and Allison L. Rinden. 2000. Reconciling context and contact effects on racial attitudes. Political Research Quarterly 54 (3): 571-604. 22 Table 1: Summary Statistics Variable State Appropriations a Non-Need-Based Aidb Need-Based Aid b Intermarriage Rate c c Ethnic Diversity African American Hispanic c c Other Non-Hispanic c c Gini Coefficient Per-Capita GDP ($1,000 year 2005)d Age 18-24 Age 5-17 Age 65+ c c c Bachelor's Degree or Higher Pell Recipients e Private Enrollment e f c Mean STD Min Max $6,891.79 $2,164.13 $2,796.41 $26,772.59 $70.71 202.44 0 $1,708.32 $229.92 $289.62 0 $1,785.88 5.72 5.04 0.73 37.35 0.32 0.16 0.03 0.67 9.5 9.23 0.207 37.1 6.67 8.29 0.03 44.99 5.46 9.01 0.32 68.34 0.39 0.03 0.32 0.49 $33.37 $9.13 $17.34 $99.66 10.4 1.6 5.6 17.4 18.84 1.65 15.09 26.57 11.8 2.12 2.23 18.4 16.36 8.75 2.34 40.83 23.24 8.13 4.62 56.98 21.27 12.41 0 57.87 Average Voter Liberalism 49.55 15.46 8.45 95.97 Sources: a Authors’ calculations based on appropriations data from Grapevine Surveys on state tax support for higher education, FTE enrollment data from National Center for Education Statistics’ Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System, and state population data from the U.S. Census Bureau. b Authors’ calculations from student aid data from the National Association of State Student Grant and Aid Programs, FTE enrollment data from National Center for Education Statistics’ Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System, and state population data from the U.S. Census Bureau. c Author’s calculations based on data from the U.S. Census Bureau, various years. d Author’s calculations based on data from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, various years. e National Center for Education Statistics’ Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System. f Richard Fording’s website: http://www.bama.ua.edu/~rcfording 23 Table 2: Regression Estimates, Ordinary Least Squares with State and Year Fixed Effects (1) State Appropriations -0.972* (0.015) -0.006 (0.439) 0.039* (0.045) 0.045* (0.024) 0.012 (0.095) -0.00003 (0.998) -0.199 (0.484) 0.745*** (<0.001) -0.852* (0.036) 0.012 (0.254) 0.004 (0.347) -0.009* (0.010) -0.005* (0.037) -0.004 (0.085) (2) Non-Need-Based Aid -2.830 (0.717) -0.191 (0.306) 0.235 (0.614) 0.056 (0.830) 0.052 (0.723) -0.188 (0.375) -9.566** (0.004) 0.137 (0.888) -12.58* (0.026) 0.021 (0.887) 0.015 (0.830) -0.093* (0.040) 0.04 (0.183) -0.0005 (0.989) (3) Need-Based Aid 3.656 (0.348) -0.022 (0.677) 0.038 (0.767) -0.186 (0.339) 0.019 (0.758) -0.029 (0.780) 1.371 (0.556) 1.824** (0.007) -3.141 (0.205) -0.008 (0.928) 0.035 (0.271) -0.003 (0.852) 0.037 (0.251) 0.012 (0.516) -0.0003 -0.008 0.009 (0.737) (0.450) (0.128) Within R 0.52 0.36 0.44 N 1,450 1,450 1,450 Ethnic Diversity Intermarriage Rate Diversity*Intermarriage African American Hispanic Other, Non-Hispanic Gini Coefficient Per-Capita GDP Age 18-24 Age 5-17 Age 65+ College-Educated Pell Recipients Private Enrollment Average Voter Liberalism 2 p-values in parentheses * p<0.05 ** p<0.01 *** p<0.001 24 Note: The coefficients on the state and year fixed effects are omitted for brevity. The variables involving dollar amounts are in constant year 2005 dollars and are in natural logs. Because the student aid variables take on zero values for some observations, we increased them by “1” before logging. The standard errors are clustered by state. Table 3: Marginal Effects of Ethnic Diversity on State Higher Education Spending, 1980 States Ethnic Diversity Intermarriage Rate Marginal Effect of Fractionalization P-Value Minnesota 0.28 0.93 -14.98 0.019 New Hampshire 0.14 1.39 -14.68 0.022 Iowa 0.19 1.65 -14.52 0.023 Alabama 0.47 1.66 -14.52 0.023 South Dakota 0.26 1.76 -14.45 0.024 Connecticut 0.44 1.87 -14.38 0.025 Maine 0.11 1.9 -14.37 0.025 Vermont 0.1 1.97 -14.32 0.025 North Dakota 0.2 2.1 -14.24 0.026 Mississippi 0.52 2.13 -14.22 0.026 Nebraska 0.29 2.32 -14.1 0.028 Rhode Island 0.37 2.4 -14.05 0.028 Pennsylvania 0.33 2.48 -14 0.029 New Jersey 0.57 2.57 -13.94 0.03 Massachusetts 0.37 2.65 -13.89 0.03 Michigan 0.38 2.76 -13.82 0.031 Wisconsin 0.28 2.88 -13.75 0.032 New York 0.59 3.16 -13.57 0.035 Illinois 0.54 3.42 -13.4 0.037 Kansas 0.35 3.79 -13.17 0.041 Montana 0.23 4 -13.04 0.043 Delaware 0.5 4.02 -13.03 0.044 Utah 0.32 4.12 -12.96 0.045 Washington 0.42 4.19 -12.92 0.046 Indiana 0.31 4.45 -12.76 0.049 Virginia 0.52 4.51 -12.72 0.05 Maryland 0.59 4.54 -12.7 0.05 West Virginia 0.13 4.62 -12.65 0.051 Ohio 0.31 4.84 -12.51 0.054 Missouri 0.32 4.97 -12.43 0.056 25 Louisiana 0.52 5.06 -12.37 0.057 Tennessee 0.39 5.24 -12.26 0.06 Texas 0.63 5.39 -12.17 0.062 Idaho 0.27 5.45 -12.13 0.063 Oregon 0.35 5.76 -11.93 0.069 Georgia 0.58 6.05 -11.75 0.074 South Carolina 0.5 6.33 -11.57 0.079 Wyoming 0.25 6.55 -11.43 0.084 Table 3 Continued Ethnic Diversity Intermarriage Rate Marginal Effect of Diversity P-Value Florida States 0.58 6.66 -11.36 0.086 Arkansas 0.41 7.47 -10.85 0.105 North Carolina 0.5 7.68 -10.72 0.11 Arizona 0.57 8.23 -10.38 0.125 Kentucky 0.23 8.32 -10.31 0.128 Colorado 0.46 8.43 -10.25 0.131 California 0.67 8.7 -10.08 0.139 Alaska 0.51 8.84 -9.99 0.143 Oklahoma 0.47 8.91 -9.95 0.146 Nevada 0.6 10.23 -9.11 0.192 New Mexico 0.62 12.54 -7.66 0.295 Hawaii 0.53 16.6 -5.1 0.525 26 Table 4: Marginal Effects of Ethnic Diversity on State Higher Education Spending, 2009 States Kentucky Alabama West Virginia North Dakota Tennessee South Carolina Mississippi Indiana New Hampshire Minnesota Pennsylvania Michigan Iowa Nebraska Ohio Wisconsin South Dakota Maine Rhode Island Missouri Delaware Ethnic Diversity 0.23 0.47 0.13 0.2 0.39 0.5 0.52 0.31 0.14 0.28 0.33 0.38 0.19 0.29 0.31 0.28 0.26 0.11 0.37 0.32 0.5 Intermarriage Rate 1.81 2.69 2.86 3.2 3.5 3.69 3.75 3.81 3.86 4.08 4.18 4.19 4.38 4.46 4.47 4.48 4.57 4.61 4.92 5.16 5.28 Marginal Effect of Diversity -14.42 -13.86 -13.76 -13.54 -13.35 -13.24 -13.2 -13.16 -13.13 -12.99 -12.93 -12.92 -12.8 -12.75 -12.74 -12.74 -12.68 -12.66 -12.46 -12.31 -12.23 P-Value 0.024 0.031 0.032 0.035 0.038 0.04 0.041 0.041 0.042 0.044 0.045 0.046 0.048 0.049 0.049 0.049 0.05 0.051 0.055 0.059 0.061 North Carolina 0.5 5.38 -12.17 0.062 Massachusetts 0.37 5.48 -12.11 0.064 Vermont 0.1 5.53 -12.07 0.065 New York 0.59 5.84 -11.88 0.07 Louisiana 0.52 5.86 -11.87 0.07 Virginia 0.52 5.93 -11.82 0.072 Arkansas 0.41 6.5 -11.47 0.083 Connecticut 0.44 6.59 -11.41 0.085 Illinois 0.54 6.74 -11.31 0.088 Montana 0.23 6.8 -11.28 0.089 Georgia 0.58 6.86 -11.24 0.09 Idaho 0.27 6.92 -11.2 0.092 Maryland 0.59 7.65 -10.74 0.109 New Jersey 0.57 7.75 -10.67 0.112 27 Utah 0.32 8.16 -10.42 0.123 Florida 0.58 8.26 -10.35 0.126 Kansas 0.35 8.7 -10.08 0.139 Texas 0.63 10.07 -9.21 0.186 Table 4 Continued States Oregon Wyoming Colorado Washington Arizona California New Mexico Nevada Oklahoma Alaska Hawaii Ethnic Diversity Intermarriage Rate Marginal Effect of Diversity P-Value 0.35 0.25 0.46 0.42 0.57 0.67 0.62 0.6 0.47 0.51 0.53 10.22 10.8 11.58 11.73 13.8 13.81 13.89 15.63 16.26 18.57 35.54 -9.12 -8.75 -8.26 -8.17 -6.86 -6.86 -6.81 -5.71 -5.31 -3.86 6.86 0.192 0.216 0.249 0.256 0.361 0.362 0.366 0.466 0.504 0.646 0.585 28 Table 5: Marginal Effects of the Intermarriage Rate on State Higher Education Spending, 2009 States Ethnic Diversity Intermarriage Rate Marginal Effect of Intermarriage P-Value Vermont 0.1 5.53 -0.96 0.707 Maine 0.11 4.61 -0.74 0.764 West Virginia 0.13 2.86 -0.44 0.85 New Hampshire 0.14 3.86 -0.3 0.895 Iowa 0.19 4.38 0.48 0.806 North Dakota 0.2 3.2 0.64 0.737 Montana 0.23 6.8 1.1 0.521 Kentucky 0.23 1.81 1.2 0.474 Wyoming 0.25 10.8 1.44 0.363 South Dakota 0.26 4.57 1.62 0.288 Idaho 0.27 6.92 1.86 0.198 Minnesota 0.28 4.08 1.89 0.189 Wisconsin 0.28 4.48 1.96 0.166 Nebraska 0.29 4.46 2.19 0.106 Indiana 0.31 3.81 2.42 0.063 Ohio 0.31 4.47 2.51 0.05 Missouri 0.32 5.16 2.62 0.037 Utah 0.32 8.16 2.64 0.035 Pennsylvania 0.33 4.18 2.84 0.02 Kansas 0.35 8.7 3.09 0.009 Oregon 0.35 10.22 3.09 0.009 Massachusetts 0.37 5.48 3.49 0.003 Rhode Island 0.37 4.92 3.49 0.003 Michigan 0.38 4.19 3.67 0.002 Tennessee 0.39 3.5 3.72 0.001 Arkansas 0.41 6.5 4.08 0.001 Washington 0.42 11.73 4.24 <0.001 Connecticut 0.44 6.59 4.59 <0.001 Colorado 0.46 11.58 4.89 <0.001 Oklahoma 0.47 16.26 5.06 <0.001 29 Alabama 0.47 2.69 5.08 <0.001 Delaware 0.5 5.28 5.51 <0.001 South Carolina 0.5 3.69 5.62 <0.001 North Carolina 0.5 5.38 5.64 <0.001 Alaska 0.51 18.57 5.75 <0.001 Virginia 0.52 5.93 5.82 <0.001 Louisiana 0.52 5.86 5.93 <0.001 Mississippi 0.52 3.75 5.97 <0.001 Table 5 Cont. States Ethnic Diversity Intermarriage Rate Marginal Effect of Intermarriage P-Value Hawaii 0.53 35.54 5.98 <0.001 Illinois 0.54 6.74 6.2 <0.001 Arizona 0.57 13.8 6.73 0.001 New Jersey 0.57 7.75 6.79 0.001 Georgia 0.58 6.86 6.8 0.001 Florida 0.58 8.26 6.85 0.001 Maryland 0.59 7.65 6.99 0.001 New York 0.59 5.84 7.01 0.001 Nevada 0.6 15.63 7.26 0.001 New Mexico 0.62 13.89 7.51 0.001 Texas 0.63 10.07 7.77 0.001 California 0.67 13.81 8.31 0.001