INSTITUTIONAL LOGICS, PERFORMANCE FEEDBACK, AND THE ADOPTION OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE PRACTICES TIMOTHY J. ROWLEY University of Toronto 105 St. George Street Toronto ON M5S 3E6 rowley@rotman.utoronto.ca ANDREW V. SHIPILOV INSEAD Boulevard de Constance 77305 Fontainebleau France Tel: 33 1 60 72 44 24 E-Mail: shipilov@insead.edu HENRICH R. GREVE INSEAD 1 Ayer Rajah Ave. 138676 Singapore henrich.greve@insead.edu ABSTRACT Institutional entrepreneurs often advocate new goals for organizations, yet little is known about how organizations respond to these goals—especially when the institutional logic underlying the goals is contested. We combine insights from institutional logics and performance feedback theory to develop a model that addresses how organizations react to such contested goals and to the accepted goal of profitability. We show that Canadian firms adopted practices consistent with the logic of board reform as a function of gaps between their profitability aspirations and their position on a corporate governance score devised by institutional entrepreneurs. 1 Early research in institutional theory focused on the taken-for-granted nature of institutional environments in which organizations uniformly react to normative, mimetic and coercive pressures (DiMaggio and Powell 1983). However, adoption of new institutions is often less uniform and more contentious than this early account described (Greenwood et al. 2011; Haveman and Rao 1997; Thornton and Ocasio 1999). Current theory suggests that institutional environments are complex and contain multiple, contested institutional logics, defined as “the socially constructed, historical patterns of material practices, assumptions, values, beliefs, and rules by which individuals produce and reproduce their material subsistence, organize time and space, and provide meaning to their social reality” (Thornton and Ocasio, 1999: 804). There has been much work on how new institutional logics replace old ones (Thornton et al. 2012), and attention is now turning to how organizations respond to the complexity of multiple contested logics. With the co-existence of competing logics organizations must decide whether and to what degree to adopt practices associated with each logic. Accordingly, Greenwood et al. (2011) developed a framework of “filters”—organizational attributes that affect whether or not organizations accept or resist a particular logic. Consistent with this shift toward the organization, we examine why firms differ in their responses to contested logics especially as they are faced with contested goals associated with these logics. Such goals are created by institutional entrepreneurs who pioneer scoring mechanisms demonstrating the extent to which organizations adopt practices consistent with the logic that the entrepreneurs are trying to spread. Examples include standardized scores to evaluate schools’ performance (Herman and Golan 1993), environmental or quality certifications for companies (Guler et al. 2002), and ease of doing business scores for governments (La Porta et al. 1999). Institutional entrepreneurs make these scores public and rally support for the need of attaining higher scores, expecting organizations to treat such attainment as a performance goal. This way, the entrepreneurs apply pressure on organizations to adopt the logic underlying these scores. Yet, when the institutional logics are contested, so are these goals. The introduction of contested goals can lead to unintended consequences—while they prompt some organizations to affirm their identity as the proponents of the logic underlying the scores and adopt corresponding practices, the goals can also push the other organizations to affirm the identity of the opponents of this logic, thus they would resist its practices. 2 Moreover, whether or not organizations will even pay attention to contested goals will depend on their profitability, which affects the propensity to take risks related to repairing a profitability shortfall or safeguarding superior profitability. This combination of ideas results in a theoretical model with two elements predicting how organizations respond to contested logics. The first uses the concept of identity from the institutional logics perspective. It suggests that the organization’s ability to achieve a contested goal relative to other organizations affects the degree to which it adopts this goal as part of its identity. This will have an impact on the organization’s subsequent adoption of practices associated with this goal. The second element invokes performance feedback theory that examines how organizations make changes when responding to deviations between their actual performance and aspiration levels. We argue that decision makers use performance feedback based on profitability as a filter affecting their responses to contested goals. When their profitability is below aspirations, firms that are also below a contested goal are more likely to reject that goal and associated practices even though this could attract repercussions from institutional entrepreneurs supporting the logic of a contested goal. In contrast, when their profitability is above aspirations, firms that also exceed a contested goal can more easily justify greater commitment to its logic and are thus more likely to adopt its practices. This model is significant because it expands the institutional logic and performance feedback theories. It enriches institutional logics theory by focusing on profitability-based performance feedback as a novel and distinct filter affecting logic adoption. It contributes to performance feedback theory which has focused on commonly agreed upon metrics such as profitability or market share, but has overlooked how new contested goals emerge in the organizations’ environment (Gavetti et al. 2012). We show that when it comes to adopting institutional practices, the affirmation of firms’ identities through their position on contested scores makes them resist any kind of changes, especially when their profitability deviates from aspirations. Furthermore, whether a firm considers adoption of a particular contested practice to be a risky change depends on the firm’s identity. This comes in contrast with the predictions of traditional performance feedback theory which assumes that adoption of a particular practice is a risky behavior for all firms and they 3 will be likely to adopt more new practices when their performance is below aspirations, while they will adopt less when their performance is above aspirations. Our theory describes nuanced organizational-level processes that predict some firms’ persistent rejection of practices associated with new institutional logics, and thus explains the persistent heterogeneity observed in some institutional environments. Our study context is the spread, from 2001 to 2010, of corporate governance practices aimed at reforming the boards of large Canadian organizations. During this period, board reform was the new institutional logic of governance, and its intention was to motivate directors and their boards to better represent external shareholder interests. To facilitate the diffusion of this logic, institutional entrepreneurs created a publicly available governance ranking based on the firms’ adoption of practices consistent with board reform. Firms could respond to this ranking either by adopting its practices or choosing not to adopt. The next section provides an overview of the emergence of the board reform logic in Canada that is based on our interviews with key experts. We also reviewed more than two thousand articles in the Canadian business press (e.g., National Post, The Globe and Mail) that described this logic as well as the extant institutional logic of management control. This research helped explain the emergence of governance ranking as a performance score over which there was much disagreement among the proponents of these two logics. This overview is followed by development of a model of how organizational identity and performance feedback interact to determine organizational responses to institutional logic contestation. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE LOGICS IN CANADA The board of directors oversees the actions of management on behalf of public corporation shareholders. The logic of board reform is a socially constructed pattern of practices, assumptions, and rules according to which companies’ boards become more independent of management (Westphal and Zajac 1998). This logic stems from the work of theorists who maintained that reducing board dependence on management was necessary to improve firms’ ability to maximize shareholder value (Beatty and Zajac 1994; Berle and Means 1932; Crystal 1984; Fama and Jensen 1983). Yet because the prevailing view for many preceding decades was that governance and profitability were not strongly linked, the balance of control in most economic systems tipped toward managers rather than boards. Proponents of management control argued 4 that, whereas management had developed the specific skills needed to understand key issues and achieve performance goals, board members committed much less time to the organization. Hence, according to this logic, management control, rather than more board oversight, would increase shareholder value (Shipilov et al. 2010). By the turn of the 21th century, there was a growing discontent with the logic of management control. Corporate scandals in 2002 finally triggered concrete action, and stakeholders mobilized to lessen managerial control in Canada. In 2002, the CEO of one of Canada’s largest institutional investor firms summarized this dissatisfaction in telling us that “the pendulum has swung too far and it is time to balance managerial power with better boards.” The charge was led by the Ontario Teachers’ Pension Plan (OTPP), a large institutional investor; the Canadian Coalition for Good Governance (CCGG), a newly formed investors’ trade association; and The Globe and Mail, Canada’s principal business newspaper. These organizations commissioned ongoing research that scored corporations’ board practices and compared them with “best practices” standards. The Globe and Mail published these governance scores for all Canadian corporations listed on the S&P-TSX index, and the OTPP used them to seek improvements in low-scoring firms. One OTPP executive explained the rationale for publicly comparing board practices as follows: “Sunlight is a great disinfectant and so is shame…. These governance scores tell us which boardrooms we should be knocking on…High scores give us confidence that the board has some influence and have our best interest at heart.” ” In the language of institutional theory, these three stakeholders were institutional entrepreneurs that sought change by destabilizing the status quo. The governance scoring and ranking was conducted by the Clarkson Centre for Board Effectiveness at the University of Toronto and was underwritten by the institutional entrepreneurs identified above. Beginning in 2002 (for the 2001 fiscal year), the Clarkson Centre examined proxy statements and public documents annually in order to score the governance practices of each corporation in the Toronto Stock Exchange index. The results were used to calculate the Board Shareholder Confidence Index (BSCI), and the BSCI scores were sent to each corporation (and other relevant stakeholders) and published on the Clarkson 5 Centre website. Each year The Globe and Mail published “Board Games”—a feature that included all the governance scores and extensive commentary, so board practices and comparisons became public knowledge. However, many corporate executives and board chairs resisted the change. Early on, most of the organizations in opposition to the board reform took the passive form by simply not adopting the board reform practices. When confronted by the media on this issue, they invoked their opposition to reforms and their adherence to the management control logic. One CEO told us, “My board is a necessary evil. The public markets require us to have a board but it is not much more than a cost and distraction.” Another CEO reflected: “Managers manage and boards drink tea [so] more oversight will not make Canadian companies better [financially]. Giving more power to boards is counterproductive.” Some directors held similar views: “Management has all the information and invests all of themselves into the company. How can a board oversee these people if they are the experts?” Many board members likewise took issue with outside influence, and the chair of a Canadian bank argued that “the right board practices must fit with the particulars of each board and should be chosen by people in the boardroom … not by critics.” The strongest opposition to board reforms came from closely-held and family-controlled firms, which insisted that—despite being publicly traded—they were a different form of organization requiring different governance principles and practices (Shipilov et al. 2010). A small minority of firms with substantial family-ownership stakes raised tension and engaged in more active political contestation; in fact, the Clarkson Centre was threatened with lawsuits. In addition, The CCGG’s Managing Director interviewed in 2008 indicated that “many corporations see us as no more than [a] nuisance and maybe worse. They think we will give up soon and things will [return to the] … old ways.” There were also efforts made to attack the credibility of the scores and of the stakeholders promoting them. One corporation’s CEO sent a menacing email to the faculty member leading the Clarkson Centre: “if this witch hunt is not stopped [then your] career will be in jeopardy.” Institutional theory suggests that the companies could have mitigated external pressures by ceremonial adoption of board reform practices (Meyer and Rowan 1977). Yet, adoption of such practices had real costs as well as had consequences for the balance of power between the board and the management. 6 First, adoptions distracted managers’ and board members’ time and attention from the other areas as well as affected political climate in the organizations. For example, increased director independence required firing some directors and hiring the new ones; separating the CEO and Chair positions required convincing the CEO that another board member would be the Chair as well as overcoming political opposition inside the board to individual candidacies. Similarly, achieving committees’ independence required changing their compositions and often lead to changing managers’ compensation systems. All of these tasks took time and had a strong potential to increase tensions within the board, as well as between the boards and the management. Second, initial adoption of some board reform practices signified adoption of their underlying logic and willingness to be judged by its goals. Finally, initial adoption of some board reform practices gave independent directors more say into how the company should be run, thus these directors pushed for even more adoptions regardless of the costs involved. Many advocates of the board reform argued that the costs of adopting these practices were justified, because they helped companies’ performance. Yet, many advocates of the management controlled boards argued that adopting board reform practices would have a negative impact on the firms’ performance and will not justify the costs. Thus, there was no consensus on the existence of the causal relationship between firms’ financial performance and their adoption of the board reform practices. The board reform logic comprises the broad groups of structural, evaluation, and equity-related practices. Structural practices include splitting the positions of CEO and Chairman of the Board as well as achieving independence of the board of directors and of its audit and compensation committees. Evaluation practices include the development of formal mechanisms for evaluating directors and the board as a whole. Equity-related practices include using company shares to compensate directors; eliminating dual share structures, the repricing of options, and excessive dilution of shares; and aligning managers’ compensation with the firm’s performance on the stock market. Figures 1a and 1b plot the rate at which these practices were adopted during 2001–2010 by the companies making up the Toronto Stock Exchange index. --- Insert Figures 1a and 1b about here --- 7 Institutional investors used the governance ratings to induce low-scoring corporations to adopt new board reform practices. Such adoptions increased, but there was evidence suggesting that corporations below the average governance scores continued to resist board reform. One board chair expressed their common sentiment: “Not only are the practices unrelated to anything we are willing to do but even if we want to make some changes we could never win. We would have to blow up our current board. Impossible.” The CEO of a family-controlled firm had a similar view: “Running a company means producing good returns for shareholders, not engaging in a check-the-box exercise. This system [governance scoring] is out to get us.” However, corporations that scored high in the ranking system responded differently. As the CCGG Managing Director commented with regard to his meetings with boards in 2009, “the best [governancescoring] boards are the most willing to listen to our suggestions and are more likely to adopt new practices.” Indeed, our tabulations of adoptions of board reform practices show that the firms above the average governance rating were more likely to adopt than firms below the average governance rating, with an average difference of 8.36 percent across all governance practices. A similar pattern was seen for return on assets (ROA), though there the gap was 5.51 percent between firms whose ROA was above and below the average. These gaps are large considering that the overall rate of adoption for all practices was 19.9 percent. By the end of our study, despite the pressures from the proponents of the board reform logic, many firms still either passively resisted board reform practices by not adopting them or engaged in active resistance by publicly speaking out against the board reform. This suggests that there was no uniform view on the appropriate separation of powers between the management and the board, thus the logics of “board reform” and “management control” remained contested. In other words, despite strong pressures from the institutional entrepreneurs over ten years, Canadian companies did not exhibit isomorphism with respect to adopting the board reform practices. Such persistent heterogeneity in the adoption cannot be explained by theory of taken-for-granted institutions (Meyer and Rowan 1977) or replacement of institutional logics (Thornton and Ocasio 1999). The theory of organizational filters may do so if we can find the correct filters, i.e. attributes that affect organizational decisions to adopt or to resist adoption of board reform. 8 PERFORMANCE FEEDBACK ON CONTESTED AND PROFITABILITY GOALS There is a growing recognition among institutional scholars that organizations differ in their responses to external pressures, especially when institutional environments contain different contested institutional logics over a long period of time. Greenwood et al. (2011) developed a framework for explaining heterogeneity of organizational responses based on the recognition that an organization’s adoption of different practices from contested logics can be affected by “filters”: attributes that affect how organizations perceive institutional complexity and construct a repertoire of accepted responses. We pursue this line of reasoning by examining the effects of organizational identity, as proposed by Greenwood et al. (2011), and we add financial performance as our own proposed filter. An organization’s responses to institutional logics are influenced by its identity—defined as its claims of membership in socially prescribed categories—because the identity restricts some options while enabling others (Meyer and Hollerer 2010). Consistently with the identity argument, Shipilov et al. (2010) showed that, when contested practices spread in multiple waves, an organizations’ adoption of previously diffused practices solidifies its identity as an adopter of their underlying logic; this leads to a path-dependent effect that renders the organization more likely to adopt additional practices from the same logic. A logic is accepted when there is a general consensus in the institutional field about the merit of values, assumptions and beliefs underlying the logic’s practices for achieving some organizational or field level outcomes. A logic is contested when such consensus is lacking and the field contains multiple logics each of which is supported by a number of actors. Alternative goals are embedded at the core of the alternative institutional logics, making goal conflict central to institutional logics theory. Thornton (2002) documents how the shift from editorial to market logic led publishers to shift from goals based on prestige and sales growth towards a focus on short term profits. Mohr and Lee (2000) examined how the shifts from an individualist logic based on race to a corporate logic in universities lead to a shift from affirmative action to outreach goals. These and other studies examined a variety of tactics used by institutional entrepreneurs to facilitate the diffusion of their institutions—appeals to different types of rationality (Townley 2002), using identity discourses (Mohr and Lee 2000) or affecting hiring, promotion decisions and authority structures 9 (Thornton 2002), yet they overlooked a distinct tactic of quantifying the goal attainment through introducing scoring systems on goals consistent with the entrepreneurs’ institutional logic. This tactic involves creating a rating or a certification mechanism that shows how well or poorly organizations adhere to the diffusing institutional practices, such as ISO certifications for companies (Guler et al. 2002). If a given institutional logic has strong supporters in the institutional field, then such scores can be used to congratulate the companies that achieved a high score for their compliance and to criticize the companies that achieved low scores. The expectation of institutional entrepreneurs, who champion such scores, is that their attainment becomes a goal in itself and the desire to achieve this goal along with the public pressures to do so will make all companies equally likely to adopt their logic. What is not known, however, is how companies react to scores especially if they do not adopt their underlying logic. Even though institutional entrepreneurs expect all companies to adopt logic consistent practices to increase their score and to avoid public shaming, surprisingly the non-adopters of the underlying logic might reject these practices even more because their low standing on the contested goal forces them to affirm their identity as adherents to the alternative logic and its goals. Thus, despite the best intentions of the institutional entrepreneurs, the creation of such scores might hinder the diffusion of practices they champion, yet the existing research on institutions doesn’t examine how and why this might happen. To examine this, we start with the observation that when a particular logic is contested, the performance scores and goals associated with this logic are contested as well. “Board reform” was a contested logic in Canada because there was no agreement among directors and managers on whether adopting its practices would improve firm performance. The creation of a governance score (Board Shareholder Confidence Index) by the institutional entrepreneurs was an attempt to impose performance goals associated with the board reform logic. Because board reform was contested, the BSCI performance score and the goal of attaining higher BSCI scores was also contested by the proponents and the opponents of this reform. When an identity becomes positively verified, a social actor’s commitment to the identity increases (Burke and Stets, 1999). Managers seek organizational membership in institutionalized social categories that 10 allow the organization to be viewed in positive terms, causing organizations to generally respond to external pressures in ways that preserve or create positive identities (Dutton et al. 2010; Sauder and Espeland 2009). Thus, the desire for a positive identity affects an organization’s response to institutional pressure and, in particular, to the adoption of new practices. For example, organizational identities in the oil and gas industry affect whether firms perceive environmentally friendly protocols as a threat or rather as an opportunity (Sharma 2000). Contested scores affect an organization’s propensity to adopt practices advocated by the scores’ creators through their impact on the organization’s identity. To understand how this happens, we borrow the terminology of “aspiration level” from performance feedback theory. The aspiration level is defined as the borderline between perceived success and failure of on a particular goal dimension (Cyert and March, 1963; Schneider, 1992). Although it is usually applied to goals accepted by the focal actor, such as the decision makers inside the firm, it can also refer to a goal imposed by external actors (Locke et al. 1988), such as institutional entrepreneurs. Comparison of an organization’s performance to its reference group defines whether or not it performs below or above aspirations. When institutional logics are contested, so will be the corresponding aspiration levels. As a contested score gains visibility in the institutional field, the discrepancy between an organization’s actual performance and the performance of the others on this score will affect the organization’s propensity to adopt or reject practices that the score is designed to promote. This will occur irrespective of whether the organization actually agrees that the average performance of the others on this score is actually worth aspiring to. Organizations that are high adopters of the logic-consistent practices are above aspiration levels on the scores associated with this logic and are singled out for praise by the logic’s supporters. Low adopters are below aspiration levels and thus are targeted for criticism even though these organizations may not actually aspire to achieving high scores on the contested goals. Thus the average BSCI score across the Canadian economy formed contested aspiration levels for all companies in the country. The further an organization’s contested score is below aspiration levels, the more likely it will reject that score and its logic. Adopting just a few board reform practices as a symbolic gesture is a dangerous 11 strategy for such organization. While doing so would have suggested that the organization accepts the board reform logic, it would still be performing below aspirations on the governance score and would risk acquiring a negative identity (i.e. an organization paying only a lip service to board reform) despite the efforts that its managers made to relinquish their authority. Therefore, managers and board members of an organization performing low on the governance score are more likely to pursue the positive identity of a managerial control firm, rather than a negative identity of a board reform firm that fails to fully implement board reform practices. Executives in such organizations will not be receptive to external challenges to their authority over the corporate policy (Brehm and Brehm 1981; Westphal 1998; Wright et al. 1992). Such managers will defend the status quo by denying the need to give more power to the boards, justify their existing management control practices or question the motives of the institutional entrepreneurs who seek to impose board reform (Ashforth and Gibbs 1990). Because adoption of the board reform practices represents a threat to a firm that identifies itself as the proponent of the management controlled boards logic, the behavior consistent with maintaining a positive identity of a managerial control firm becomes to hold its position on the governance score and reject corresponding practices. Thus, even though decision-makers in a firm don’t buy into the need to reach an aspiration level on the contested goal imposed by the institutional entrepreneurs, the difference between the firm’s performance on the contested goal and that aspiration level publicized by the score will still be consequential for their rejection of contested practices. Conversely, organizations performing above contested aspirations (i.e. if their BSCI score is above the national average) gain public affirmation of the positive identity of the adopters of the board reform logic. Following identity theory, decision makers in such organizations will seek out opportunities to enhance this positive identity further, which can be done by adopting even more practices consistent with the board reform logic. Doing so would entail a relatively low cost, as these executives already overcame their natural reluctance to relinquish control and shift structural power to the board (Westphal 1998). Thus, the higher the performance of an organization on the board reform score relative to the aspiration level, the more likely the organization is to adopt other board reform practices. These arguments lead to the following hypotheses: 12 H1: An organization is less likely to adopt a contested institutional practice if its performance based on the contested goals is below that of its aspiration level. H2: An organization is more likely to adopt a contested institutional practice if its performance based on the contested goals is above that of its aspiration level. One assumption behind research on performance feedback is that performance and associated aspiration levels represent commonly agreed upon and uncontested goals for companies and individual executives (March and Shapira 1987). Financial performance and financial aspirations, frequently operationalized as profitability, are a key component of research on performance feedback in organizations precisely because of the profitability’s commonly-agreed upon nature. That is, organizational success is widely defined as the ability to reach or exceed profitability goals, while the inability to do so is considered a failure. Performance feedback theory also suggests is that performance below aspirations causes search for alternative actions and risk taking in the form of new practices’ adoption. For example, reduction of firms’ market share below their aspiration levels in the contexts where market share is a close correlate of profitability caused format changes for radio stations (Greve, 1998) or change of syndicate partners for investment banks (Baum et al, 2006). Lower return on assets relative to aspiration levels caused organizations to engage more in innovations (Greve 2003a), make investments (Greve 2003b), change strategic positioning (Park 2007), engage in acquisitions (Iyer and Miller 2008), and take risks more broadly (Miller and Chen 2004). That such effects have been found over a wide range of outcomes testifies to the power of profitability in shaping managerial action. This is because profitability ensures organizational survival, increases managerial compensation, and is a broad indicator of operational sustainability. Although profitability is a frequent predictor of change in such business actions as innovation, investment, acquisitions, and strategic positioning, research on institutional theory has not demonstrated an effect of profitability on the diffusion of institutional practices. This fact may simply reflect an empirical omission, but there is also reason to believe that investigation of a direct effect between profitability performance feedback and adoption of institutional practices would yield no findings. Managers who seek to improve profitability seldom adopt practices that have weak or no performance consequences. Managers will 13 focus instead on actions that they see as more consequential in response to gaps between their profitability and aspiration levels. Institutional goals can be important in their own right when an institution is so well established that its goals are binding on all organizations in the institutional field. Yet this is not the case for goals associated with contested institutional logics. Contested institutions yield more choice to organizations than in environments dominated by a single institutional logic. On average, such goals will be lower in the goal hierarchy than profitability precisely because there is no consensus on whether their attainment contributes to organizational survival, and operational sustainability. Thus, we should expect different reactions to contested logics and goals depending on the organization’s financial performance: The effect of profitability performance feedback on the adoption of such practices will be indirect and localized within the extreme cases of adopters of different logics. When an organization simultaneously performs below contested aspirations and below profitability aspirations, its attention will be on profitability rather than the contested logic. Because fixing profitability problems will be much higher on its managers’ agenda than improving the standing on the contested goals (i.e. goals of board reform), they will make changes in the areas that are more directly related to profitability. Building a positive identity associated with a contested logic that is not directly linked to financial performance is of a secondary concern for organizations performing below profitability aspiration levels. Managers in such firms can exploit this uncertain link to justify resistance against adoption of contested practices, because they can argue that adoption will distract managers’ and boards’ attention from fixing profitability shortfalls, when these practices are in fact unrelated to profitability. Thus, we propose: H3: An organization is less likely to adopt a contested institutional practice if its performance based on the contested goals is below aspiration levels and its profitability is also below aspirations. Performance feedback research also suggests that when performance based on profitability is above aspirations, the risk taking is reduced because decision makers avoid making changes that could disrupt superior performance. This is why Greve (2003: 91-92, 100-101) finds that firms with higher ROA than their aspirations reduced R&D investment and innovations. Similar findings of lower rates of change and new practice adoption when profitability is high are common in the performance feedback literature (Iyer and 14 Miller 2008; Miller and Chen 2004). Even though performing above profitability aspirations reduces the propensity for risk taking in general, organizations that also perform above contested aspirations will find the adoption of associated practices to be a highly appropriate risk reduction behavior given their positive identity as adopters of the board reform logic. Thus, managers in such organizations will switch their attention from making risky changes in innovation, R&D, acquisition or partnering strategies to adopting more board reform practices. This will help them attain the new levels in the contested goal without risk because their organizations already agree with the underlying logic. Furthermore, because the rhetoric advocating the contested practices typically involves some claims of effects on profitability, managers who have adopted the board reform logic will add its goals and practices to their profitability enhancing heuristics. Even if the contested practices in fact are unrelated to profitability, such managers may nonetheless perceive that the firm experiences increased profitability after practices’ adoption. This is because profitability has a high unexplained component (McGahan and Porter 2002), and managers who believe in the value of specific changes typically try to attribute profitability improvements to their actions while attributing profitability drops to environmental conditions(Meindl and Ehrlich 1987). This sets the stage for superstitious learning in the firms that both adopt contested institutional logic and experience profitability performance above aspirations supporting their belief that the adopted institutional practices were in fact beneficial (Denrell 2003; Levitt and March 1988). Thus, they subsequently adopt more of them. These arguments result in the following hypothesis: H4: An organization is more likely to adopt a contested institutional practice if its performance based on the contested goals is above aspirations and its profitability is also above aspirations. We have suggested that the adoption of practices stemming from a contested institutional logic is influenced not only by performance relative to the goals consistent with that logic but also by profitability relative to its aspiration level. According to performance feedback theory, we can subdivide performance feedback into social and historical aspirations. Social aspirations are formed when organizations compare their performance against peer groups while historical aspirations are formed when organizations compare 15 their performance against its own past performance. Falling behind relative to either type of comparison based on financial goals has been shown to affect an organization’s willingness to change (Argote and Greve 2007; Greve 1998, 2003c). Moreover, there are contextual differences in the relative weight placed on social versus historical aspiration levels and in the choice of peer groups, depending, for example, on the organization’s network position (Shipilov et al. 2011). While this research examined how firms set uncontested profitability aspirations, it is mute on how firms set their contested aspirations. Understanding the formation of contested aspirations is important because they are a key building block in a model explaining heterogeneity in firms’ responses to contested practices. Contested goals are imposed by outside actors, and hence firms’ decision makers will pay more attention to social than to historical aspirations. Comparisons with peers yield an external performance benchmark for contested goals, but historical comparisons in such a context are difficult. Organizations do not have a long track record on attaining contested goals, which are relatively new, so the required level of performance leading to acceptance (or rejection) of an institutional logic is unclear from historical comparisons of an organization’s own past performance. For profitability goals, in contrast, both social and historical aspirations are well-defined. Firms have records of their own profitability going back a long time, and the profitability of peers is also an unambiguous criterion for immediate social comparisons. In other words, firms can clearly establish how well they must perform in order to exceed their past profitability and that of their peers. These considerations lead to our final hypothesis. H5: An organization will pay attention to its social aspirations when responding to performance feedback based on a contested goal and will pay attention to both historical and social aspirations when responding to profitability performance feedback. DATA AND METHODOLOGY Sample and Data Collection We obtained access to the Clarkson Centre’s Board Shareholder Confidence Index for 2001–2010 and to the data on Canadian companies’ adoption of governance practices for the same period. Information on the adoption of practices was collected by the Clarkson Centre from the companies’ annual proxy statements. 16 We also conducted interviews between 2001 and 2012 to capture the evolution of key stakeholders’ sentiments about the BSCI. The sample of companies covered by the BSCI consisted of those included in the Toronto Stock Exchange (TSX) index, which comprised about 200 Canadian companies in each year. The proxy statements contain information about board membership, board practices, and the ownership structure of all companies in our sample; this allowed us to construct annually updated networks of interlocking directorates. Collecting data on these networks was necessary to rule out alternative explanations for the mimetic drivers of diffusing practices. For each TSX member company, we collected data on director attributes, and organization characteristics (e.g., size and industry of operations) and performance from such publicly available sources as Compustat, Thomson One Banker, and Bloomberg Professional Service. Our qualitative fieldwork suggested that the time frame chosen for the analysis (i.e., 2001–2010) was justified for several reasons. First, our key contribution to the literature is examining how institutional logics and feedback based on different performance goals affect the spread of contested practices. The study’s time frame begins when the BSCI was created and started disseminating information about company performance with respect to the board reform. By the end of the study period, board reform was well established—so much so that the key institutional entrepreneurs (the CCGG, the OTPP, and The Globe and Mail) started reallocating funding to other initiatives. Dependent Variable Our dependent variable is companies’ adoption of governance practices in line with the logic of board reform; these are the same practices used by the Clarkson Centre to construct the BSCI. As described in the methodology section below, the analysis is set up so that each practice is tracked separately, but the adoptions are pooled in the analysis. There are 11 practices in total concerning the structure, evaluation process, and equity. The first set comprised four structural practices. (1) Board independence. Relationships with management increase the risk that a director will place the interests of executives before those of shareholders. The BSCI considered the corporate board to be independent (i.e., dominated by outsiders without connections to the 17 firm’s management) when at least two thirds of its directors were independent. To identify dependencies between directors and management, BSCI applied stringent measures. Specifically, it followed the CCGG guidelines in considering board members to be not independent under any of the following conditions: when (a) they were now employees of the organization or were so at any time during the previous three years; (b) they were executives of organizations “affiliated” with the focal organization; (c) their organizations currently provided legal, auditing, or consulting services to the focal organization or did so within the last three years; or (d) they had a kinship relation to the focal organization’s CEO or Chairman of the Board. (2) and (3) Independence of audit and compensation committees. The BSCI coded the audit and compensation committees (individually) as independent if all committee members were independent directors. (4) Board chair and CEO split. When the CEO and board chair positions are not separate, it is more difficult for the board to operate independently of management influence. The BSCI considered the organization to qualify on this criterion if the CEO and chair positions were occupied by different individuals—unless they had a kinship relation. The second set of practices involved performance evaluations. (5) Director evaluation involved peer-topeer assessment of each director’s performance, usually on an annual basis. (6) Board evaluation was also based on directors’ assessments and focused on the quality of board meetings, of board information packages, of the chair’s leadership, and of specific board processes. The third set consisted of five equity-related practices. (7) Director stock ownership captured the alignment of interests between directors and the company, a primary goal of board reform that could be achieved by increasing the portion of directors’ compensation paid via company shares. The BSCI coded the company as having adopted this practice if the average value of share ownership by the company’s directors exceeded 4 times their annual retainer. (8) Dual share structure. The rationale for this criterion is that board effectiveness increases when shareholders can influence its decisions by voting—influence that is diminished when only some shares qualify as “voting” shares. A company was viewed by the BSCI as not having a dual share structure, and thus as enabling the influence of common shareholders, when more than 50% of its equity controlled more than 50% of the votes. (9) Share dilution occurs when options granted to executives and directors make up a significant proportion of the outstanding shares, thus diluting returns that would 18 otherwise go to the shareholders and so running counter to board reform logic. A company was scored as exhibiting share dilution unless options granted to directors and managers (resp., CEO’s) constituted no more than 10% (resp., 5%) of the company’s outstanding shares. (10) Option repricing. When a company’s share performance has suffered, the cost of exercising directors’ stock options can be greater than the cost of purchasing stock at market value. In this case a company may decide to lower the exercise price in order to align it with the market value of the stock, and such repricing is seen as relieving directors of their responsibility for the company’s performance. A company was considered not to exhibit option repricing if it had not lowered the exercise price within the preceding three years. (11) Alignment between CEO compensation and share price. Setting CEO compensation is a responsibility of the directors, and it should reflect (as dictated by board reform logic) the company’s actual performance. A company was coded for proper alignment if CEO compensation did not increase by more than 25% following a year during which the firm’s share price decreased by more than 25%. Finally, we emphasize that the actual practices and the specific numeric weights used to determine their absence or presence (e.g., the ratio of share ownership to annual retainer that determines director stock ownership) were based on the governance guidelines stipulated by the Toronto Stock Exchange and the Canadian Coalition for Good Governance and thus directly reflect the demands of these institutional entrepreneurs. Each practice defined by the BSCI yielded a binary indicator variable, labeled Board reform practice, which was set to 1 if the focal company employed a given practice in a particular year (and set to 0 otherwise). We pooled our data by “stacking” the matrices of single-practice diffusion regressions into one large matrix (Shipan and Volden 2006; Wei et al. 1989). An organization at risk for adopting a particular practice will generate an observation for that practice. With respect to board evaluation, for example, our dependent variable Board reform practice is set to 1 if the organization was observed to adopt board evaluation in year t (and to 0 otherwise). Once an organization has adopted a practice, it can no longer generate an observation for that practice. Our data structure therefore consists of organization-year observations only for the companies at risk for adopting new governance practices (because they do not yet employ them). 19 Independent Variables Our key performance measures were the firms’ ROA and BSCI score; the former measure was obtained from Compustat and the latter from the Clarkson Centre. The BSCI score ranges between 0 and 100 points. The Clarkson Centre researchers used 100 points as the initial value for each company and then subtracted points for each reform practice that the company failed to adopt. We used the following formula to construct historical aspiration levels for ROA and BSCI: Historical aspirationst = (1 − a)(Historical aspirationst – 1) + (a)(Performancet – 1). (1) Here Performancet – 1 is the ROA (or BSCI, as applies) at time t − 1, and a is a number (between 0 and 1) that represents the weight given to the immediate prior performance as compared with the weight given to more distant performances. If the historical aspiration level is weighted more toward recent performance, then it will adjust quickly to short-term performance variations; if it is weighted more toward past performance, then short-term performance variations have little impact. We computed social aspirations for each firm as the average ROA and BSCI for all firms in the TSX index but excluding the focal firm. Firms are more likely to react to the performance of similar others and so we weighted each firm’s performance by 1/[1 + w], where w was set to 0 if the two firms were in the same industry and to 1 otherwise (Greve 2008). Because firms may use historical and social aspirations simultaneously (Cyert and March 1963), we aggregated them based on the following formula for aspiration level AL: ALt = G(Social aspirationst) + (1 − G)(Historical aspirationst), (2) where G is the weight given to social aspirations. When G = 0, the firm’s aspirations are solely historical; when G = 1, its aspirations are entirely social. So if a firm’s aspiration level is based equally on social and historical aspirations, G = 0.5. To determine how firms react when their performance is above or below aspiration levels, we computed separate AL values based on ROA and BSCI and then subtracted them from the actual ROA and BSCI. To enable comparison of the slopes above and below the aspiration level, we split each relative 20 performance variable for both performance metrics into two variables. ROA below AL equals zero for observations where relative performance based on ROA is greater than zero and equals the relative performance otherwise; ROA above AL equals zero for observations where relative performance based on ROA is less than zero and equals the relative performance otherwise. Analogous definitions hold for the variables BSCI below AL and BSCI above AL. We control for a range of additional factors that may affect an organization’s adoption of contested practices. For each year, we computed the number of practices compatible with board reform logic that an organization had already adopted, thus creating the Own practice variable. An organization might also adopt practices simply because it shares directors with prior adopters. We constructed affiliation matrices in which each Xij entry denotes the number of directors in common between organizations i and j. A matrix of this type was constructed for each year in our observation window. We then computed Interlock practice as a count of the number of contested practices adopted by the firm’s interlocking partners. Network centrality is often associated with early adoption of innovations and with other important performance outcomes (Shipilov and Li 2008). To capture an organization’s position in the network of interlocking relationships, we used a measure of normalized eigenvector centrality (Bonacich 1987). To control for the stock market performance of companies, we computed Market/book value as a separate control variable. We chose this measure over the alternatives because market-based performance measures are typically the most salient from the perspective of shareholders. Canadian companies with shares listed in the United States may be more receptive to new governance practices because US rules on governance were tougher, especially after passage in 2002 of the Sarbanes–Oxley Act. We therefore controlled for US exposure via an indicator variable, US stock crosslisting, which was set to 1 only if the focal organization was cross-listed on the New York Stock Exchange or Nasdaq. A company with an extremely low BSCI score will likely attract considerable attention from external stakeholders, especially those that favor board reform. To capture this dynamic we use another indicator variable, Extremely low BSCI, which was set to 1 only if the company’s BSCI score failed to exceed 25 (i.e., a score that would put the company at the very bottom of BSCI tables). 21 Governance in banks and other financial institutions is a hot spot, too, given the importance of the financial sector to the overall health of the economy. We therefore included the indicator variable Financial sector, which was set to 1 if the focal company operated in that sector (and to 0 otherwise). Directors’ oversight of large organizations also attracts attention from external stakeholders because of the disproportionate effects that governance failures would have in organizations of that size. Hence our models include the natural log of net sales (Ln net sales) for each company in the sample. Our interviews and content analysis of the business press suggested that stock ownership by members of the CCGG influenced board decisions to adopt the second wave of contested practices. To capture this phenomenon, the indicator variable CCGG ownership is set to 1 if CCGG members held ownership stakes in the firm (and to 0 otherwise). We employed an indicator variable for the focal practice of each observation and thereby accounted for differences in the base rate of diffusion (some practices spread more rapidly because they are easier to adopt or are viewed as providing greater benefits). For identification, we omit one practice from the set of indicator variables. Finally, all of our models include year fixed effects to control for the effect of time on the diffusion rates. The independent variables are lagged by one year. Estimation We estimated a panel logit model using either the population average or random effects (via the “xtlogit” command in STATA) along with Huber–White robust standard errors clustered by organization (Shipan and Volden 2006); the logit approach is appropriate because our dependent variable is binary. We predicted adoption of governance practices at time t + 1 as a function of the firm’s BSCI score (and of other independent and control variables) at time t. The data we used cover no more than eight time periods per organization,1 which means that the fixed-effects estimator of the logit model is biased (Lancaster 2000). Simulations have revealed that the population-average estimator outperforms the fixed-effects estimator for short time panels in logit models (Greene 2004). The disadvantage of using the population-average estimator is that, unlike a random-effects estimator, it does not yield a likelihood ratio—which is needed to compute The data for 2001–2010 amount to ten time periods. One time period is lost because we lagged independent variables to avoid simultaneity bias, and another time period is lost because we initialized historical aspirations (i.e., firms’ historical aspirations for 2001 were undefined). 1 22 the BIC statistic when testing Hypothesis 5. Therefore, we first built our regression models using a population-average estimator and then replicated our results with a random-effects estimator. Another advantage of using population-average and random-effects (rather than fixed-effects) estimators is that they do not require the omission of observations for firms that did not adopt a given practice throughout the entire observation period. In other words, we are particularly interested in understanding what factors cause firms to persist in their decisions not to adopt board reform practices, and using a fixed-effects estimator would have forced us to exclude persistent non-adopters. ANALYSIS AND RESULTS Table 1 reports descriptive statistics and correlations between variables. All the correlations are within a range that indicates the absence of multicollinearity. Because our regression models contain interactions, we computed the variance inflation factor (VIF) for each model; all the models’ maximum VIF statistics were well below the cutoff level of 10. --- Insert Table 1 about here --We built hierarchically nested models to test Hypotheses 1–4, and the results are reported in Table 2. We used the population-average estimator in the first four models. Model 1 is a baseline; in addition, Model 2 includes ROA above and below aspiration levels, Model 3 includes BSCI above and below aspiration levels, and Model 4 includes interactions between ROA and BSCI above and below aspirations. Model 5 replicates Model 4 but uses instead a random-effects estimator. Given equation (2), in each model we assumed that firms—when adopting or resisting governance practices—react solely to social aspirations for BSCI (GBSCI = 1) but react equally to social and historical aspirations for ROA (GROA = 0.5). The results are qualitatively similar across the models, so we interpret the full Model 5. According to Hypothesis 1, a firm whose BSCI score is below its aspiration level is less likely than other firms to adopt contested practices. Because BSCI below AL takes negative values only, a positive and significant coefficient for this variable provides support for H1 (p<0.05). Conversely, Hypothesis 2 indicates that a firm is more likely to adopt such practices if its BSCI score is above aspiration levels. Because BSCI above AL takes only positive values, a positive coefficient for this variable supports H2 (p<0.05). 23 In Hypothesis 3 we argued that underperformance of profitability aspirations and contested performance below the peer group makes firms less likely to adopt contested practices. To test this hypothesis, we evaluated the interaction between BSCI below AL and ROA below AL; a negative coefficient for this interaction supports our hypothesis (p<0.05). According to Hypothesis 4, performance above the firm’s own profitability aspirations and above its peer group’s performance on contested criteria renders the focal firm more likely to adopt contested practices. To test this hypothesis, we interacted BSCI above AL with ROA above AL; here our hypothesis is supported by a positive coefficient for the interaction (p<0.1). --- Insert Table 2 about here --Figure 2 illuminates how interactions between aspiration levels for both goals affect the likelihood of adoption; it plots the predicted probability of adopting a new practice, where the probability at the graph’s origin is set equal to the average adoption probability for the data set. Thus, the reported probabilities cover a realistic range of variation. The curve without interactions (small square symbols) shows an appreciable increase in adoption of contested practices across the entire range of BSCI scores. The curve for ROA and BSCI scores above aspirations (large square symbols) shows significant increases in the propensity of firms above peer adoption levels of BSCI to adopt governance practices. The curve with ROA below aspirations and governance scores below aspirations (no symbols) shows that this condition significantly decreases the propensity to adopt governance practices. --- Insert Figure 2 about here --Finally, in Hypothesis 5 we argued that the attention companies pay to historical versus social aspirations is a function of the type of performance feedback to which they are responding. Hypotheses concerning different aspiration levels are tested by comparing the fit of two models: one in which social and historical aspirations are equally weighted when setting the overall aspiration level versus one in which aspiration levels are adjusted to reflect theoretical criteria. This approach is similar to that adopted in the learning literature for identifying “depreciation factors” for past experience (Baum and Ingram 1998), and it has been implemented in other studies examining heterogeneity in aspiration levels (Greve 2002; Shipilov et 24 al. 2011). Comparing the fit of nonnested models is traditionally based on the Bayesian information criterion (BIC) (Raftery 1996). Table 3 summarizes the tests for Hypothesis 5. As reported in the table, we varied the weight G given to social (versus historical) aspirations for both BSCI and ROA to see how well the results fit the data as compared with the case where GROA and GBSCI are both equal to 0.5. The top value in each table cell is the Wald statistic for Model 4 (computed using a population-average estimator), and the bottom value reports the BIC for Model 5 (computed using a random-effects estimator). We allowed G to vary from 0 to 1 in increments of 0.1, so this analysis amounted to running 121 regressions for each model. These regressions helped us identify which weights of the social and historical aspiration levels produce the best-fitting model. --- Insert Table 3 about here --Wald statistics approximately follow a chi-square distribution, with differences greater than 3.84 lending support to the best-fitting model at p < 0.05 (higher chi-square values indicate a better fit). Yet because the test is nonnested for these models, the difference in Wald statistics should be viewed as merely indicative. Between-model BIC differences exceeding 6 indicate strong support for the model with a smaller BIC, where “strong support” is roughly equivalent to an 0.05 significance level in non-Bayesian inference (Raftery 1996). For the reference model, in which GROA = GBSCI = 0.5, the BIC is 3384 and the Wald statistic is 229. There is strong support for our chosen model, in which GROA = 0.5 and GBSCI = 1.0, since its BIC is 3369 (and since 3384 − 3369 > 6); here the Wald statistic is 235, which also supports our choice. Models for which GROA ranges between 0.3 and 0.5 and GBSCI ranges between 0.9 and 1.0 provide a still better fit, although not significantly better than when GROA = 0.5 and GBSCI = 1.0. In sum, we find support for Hypothesis 5 (p<0.05), which states that firms—when deciding whether or not to adopt contested governance practices—refer only to social aspirations for the governance score and to a mix of social and historical aspirations for financial performance. Some results concerning our control variables are of particular interest. First of all, firms whose interlock partners had adopted board reform practices were themselves, as expected, more likely to follow 25 suit (i.e., the coefficient for Interlock practice is positive and significant). This finding is consistent with prior research on mimetic diffusion of practices through networks (Davis and Greve 1997). Second, though our models include indicator variables reflecting the intrinsic appeal of each practice across the population, these variables do not capture variation in the extent to which practices appeal to individual firms; that purpose is served by the Own practice variable. The negative and significant coefficient for this variable confirms the existence of a “high-hanging fruits” mechanism: once a firm has adopted some of the BSCI governance practices, there remain fewer such practices for them to adopt. Because these leftovers are evidently practices that the focal firm’s managers and board members had already decided were relatively unappealing, that firm will naturally be more reluctant to adopt them than the ones initially adopted. Third, the coefficient for Centrality is negative and significant. This is because a firm with a high centrality in the network occupies a core position within the field and so is shielded from the pressure of alternative institutions; this makes it less likely to adopt a new and contested logic. In contrast, it is peripheral organizations whose adoptions drive acceptance of such institutional logics because they are less wedded to the status quo (Leblebici et al. 1991). Supplementary Analyses The analysis reported in Table 2 is conducted by pooling all three groups of practices—structural, evaluation, and equity-related—into a single dependent variable. To check whether firms’ adoption (in response to aspiration–performance gaps) differed by practice group, we performed a separate analysis of each one’s diffusion. The results were substantially weaker in each of the three analyses due to the loss of statistical power needed for modeling diffusion dynamics, suggesting that our empirical strategy of analyzing the practices’ joint diffusion was more appropriate. We also checked for whether firms with low BSCI scores also had poor financial performance. If such an effect exists and can be easily observed by managers, then the implication is that adherence to board reform logic is objectively associated with superior financial performance. To check for the presence of this effect, we computed a correlation between ROA and BSCI on the full sample of firm-year-practice observations. This dataset doesn’t drop firm year practice observations after the firms adopted a particular 26 governance practice (as we have done in the main analysis), because we would like to capture whether firms improved ROA even after the adoption of specific practices. The correlation was extremely low (r = -0.001) and not significant. Similarly, a correlation between the number of board reform practices adopted by firms (variable Own Practice) and ROA was also low (r=0.001) and not significant. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS We have sought to extend the work on firm responses to competing institutional logics by specifying and testing a model that combines the theory on organizational identity (Greenwood et al. 2011) with performance feedback (Greve, 2003). A key element of our theory is the idea that institutional entrepreneurs aim to impose goals on organizations in order to gain acceptance of the institution they are trying to popularize and to spread its associated practices. Institutional entrepreneurs make salient firms’ positions with respect to other firms on such goals, affecting the firms’ identities and consequently the adoption of contested practices. However, because organizations are addressing contested logics and goals, we should expect variation in responses across firms. We make two specific arguments related to explaining such behavioral patterns. First, firms scoring relatively low on goals associated with a contested logic are unlikely to accept that logic because doing so would create a negative identity for them. Instead, publication of contested scores pushes these firms to affirm a positive identity of the proponents of the alternative logic and they become less likely to adopt the practices spearheaded by these entrepreneurs. In contrast, firms scoring relatively high on such goals are pushed to affirm their identity as adopters of the score’s logic, thus they are more likely to adopt more of its practices. This mechanism helps explain the continued divergence in practices seen in complex institutional fields (e.g., Greenwood et al., 2011). Second, we also invoke performance feedback theory to predict that firms with low profitability and low scores on the contested goal are likely to have a further reduction of the adoption likelihood. This is because they will address profitability shortfalls with other behaviors (such as investment in R&D, increased innovation or the like) and because they do not consider adoption of contested practices to be a profitability enhancing strategy given their identity. In contrast, in profitable firms with high 27 adoption levels of contested goals, managers posit causal links between the two and hence further increase their levels of adoption, especially since such actions represent a low risk strategy given their chosen identity. Our evidence offers support across the board. The rate of adopting board reform practices increases when firms’ corporate governance score relative to peers is high and decreases when the governance score relative to peers is low. In addition, we find that (i) profitability below aspirations reduces adoption rates for firms whose governance score is below that of their peers and (ii) profitability above aspirations increases adoption rates for firms whose governance score is above peer levels. In other words, higher profitability gives organizations the latitude to pursue goals related to board reform, and this effect is strongest in the organizations that indicate prior acceptance of board reform as a logic. In turn, lower profitability provides firms that adopt the management control logic an excuse to avoid adoption of the board reform practices. Finally, organizations set their aspiration levels differently for contested corporate governance goals than for uncontested profitability goals. With respect to profitability, firms use both the performance of their peers and their own past performance as a reference; with respect to governance, they refer only to the performance of their peers. These findings are an important extension of work on the diffusion of institutions. It has been shown by others that organizations mimetically adopt new practices of uncertain value, thereby spreading institutional structures and norms (Davis and Greve 1997; DiMaggio and Powell 1983; Galaskiewicz and Burt 1991). We demonstrate the existence of a more strategic form of diffusion that has not been previously documented: the imposition of goals by institutional entrepreneurs leads a firm to adopt (or not) depending on its own performance with respect to these goals irrespective of other firms’ actions. Thus the firms are not acting through imitation of other firms in their networks or more broadly in the interorganizational field, but rather they are choosing a position relative to a field-level scoring mechanism. This is a new finding, yet it is consistent with the more political view of institutions that has been promoted by the theory of institutional logics—in particular, its recent turn toward logics that do not rapidly displace others but instead remain in contestation over a period of time (Greenwood et al. 2011). Thus, both the firm’s network position and its 28 own characteristics matter for important organization-level outcomes (Shipilov 2009), such as the adoption of diffusing practices. Our findings also contribute to performance feedback theory in several ways. First, the finding that profitability below aspirations led to less adoption of institutional practices by the proponents of the management controlled board logic supports the shifting of goals from lower level goals to profitability that so far has seen little empirical testing (Greve, 2008). Second, the contrast in findings between the goal imposed by institutional entrepreneurs and the usual findings on goals such as profitability or market share strongly suggest that contested goals have effects that contrast with accepted goals like profitability, and likewise that adoption of institutions has causes that are distinct from those of changes in business practices like R&D investment, innovation, and acquisition strategy. Performance feedback based on profitability doesn’t have a direct effect on the adoption of contested practices, rather it acts as the moderating mechanism affecting attention to institutional actions or business actions for firms that perform above or below contested goals. Additionally, the organization’s identity affects its considerations of appropriate search behaviors in response to performance feedback. That is, an organization which has an identity of a supporter for the board reform logic views adoption of new board reform practices as a low risk behavior to be followed when its financial performance is above aspirations; while an organization with an identity of the management control firm views the non- adoption of a board reform practice as a low risk behavior, in which it will engage even if its financial performance is below aspirations. Thus, examining performance feedback based on profitability in isolation from the performance feedback based on contested goals that forces the firm to affirm its identity by taking sides with a particular logic will give an incomplete picture of the diffusion of institutional practices. The underlying logic of our theoretical model is that managers’ action is driven by their comparisons of current performance with aspiration levels, but the mechanisms driving action in Hypotheses 1 and 2 are different from the mechanisms driving action in Hypotheses 3 and 4. In the first two hypotheses, the action is driven by an organization’s identity, which becomes affirmed and publicized through its performance on a contested goal. Because it is the pressure towards the positive confirmation of a firm’s identity in the 29 environment of contested goals and not the risk taking in the environment of commonly accepted goals that drives action in the first two hypotheses, we expect and find different results from what could have been predicted by a model linking a firm’s profitability performance feedback to its adoption of R&D activities. Such traditional performance feedback model would have predicted that firms performing below aspirations will always adopt new practices, as they search for solutions to improve their performance, while firms performing above aspirations will always reject new practices as they don’t want to make changes that jeopardize their performance. Instead, we find that firms performing below contested aspirations resist adoption, while firms performing above contested aspirations are more likely to adopt. In the second two hypotheses, the action is driven by the relative propensity of the organization to take risks and to make inferences on whether profitability is affected by the adoption of contested practices which, in turn, are simultaneously driven by contested and profitability performance feedbacks. Developing such a model is a new theoretical contribution, as the current institutional logics theory doesn’t examine aspiration levels and the consequences of comparing performance to aspirations on contested goals for identity adoption. Similarly, the current rendering of the performance feedback theory assumes that all goals are accepted by the managers, as profitability goals are, and overlooks contested goals. Thus, the effects in our theoretical model extend both institutional and performance feedback theories. More broadly, the move in organizational research from institutions leading to isomorphism (DiMaggio and Powell 1983) to institutions being replaced by new institutions (Thornton and Ocasio 1999) or remaining in contention (Hoffman 1999) might be a result of researchers gaining the necessarily conceptual tools for seeing institutional environments as complex and contentious, and organizations as choosing how much to adapt to each of the potentially conflicting logics (Greenwood et al. 2011). For organizational decision making, firm level theories such as performance feedback provide concepts and processes with strong explanatory power that can augment the explanations at the level of the organizational field that have been common so far. These behavioral explanations nicely complement the more political perspective of institutional adoption that is exemplified by research on institutional logics (Thornton et al., 2012). The most obvious avenues for extending this research include identifying firm identities via the 30 organizational characteristics (e.g. ownership structures) that empower a firm’s proponents of governance reform as well as examining how firms’ adoption decisions differ as a function of such characteristics. There are many other possible extensions as well. Although our investigation has focused on organizations deciding between two different institutional logics, our understanding could benefit from research on how organizations react to, and choose among, multiple contending logics. Questions also remain about just how entrepreneurs advance (and render prominent) their own goals. What characteristics of institutional entrepreneurs, and of the new logics and goals they promote, are most strongly associated with having an effect on the aspiration levels of organizations? Developing theory and conducting empirical research along these lines may well benefit from cross-fertilization with the field of social movements (King and Soule 2007); after all, institutional entrepreneurs can use similar tactics—and benefit from similar situations—as grass-roots social movements (Rao 1998). In sum, there are many potentially fruitful areas that are ripe for extending the work in this paper on contested logics and organizational responses to new and evolving institutions. Our study does have some limitations, which stem primarily from the institutional context from which it derives. It is a classical dilemma of institutional research that sensitivity to a specific context is needed to inform the investigation, even as it leads to limited generalizibility. For example, we have provided clear evidence regarding the effects of governance performance vis-à-vis a contested institutional logic (board reform) but we have not established the extent to which institutional entrepreneurs are able to induce such effects in other contexts. This is an important area for future research. Also, our paper addresses an institutional context in which multiple specific practices are viewed as being consistent with a new environment. Analogous phenomena have been observed elsewhere—as in the multiple practices that constitute due process in the workplace (Edelman 1990)—but it is not a universal feature of institutionalization. Future research may benefit from comparing multi- with single-practice institutions as well as from a focus on between-practice relations such as those explored in this paper. We produce a simplified view of an organization as a unitary entity that either adopts or doesn’t adopt the contested logic. Clearly, organizations have a considerable degree of internal heterogeneity, which 31 we cannot observe in our dataset. Some groups inside organizations might favor the adoption of the contested logic while the other groups might resist the adoption. Groups who have power in the organization might use different tactics to impose its views, for example, using their power for keeping the discussion of the contested logic off the organizational agendas or using their power to defeat the motions in support of the logic. Different environmental conditions might give one group more power over the other, and this could affect whether an organization as a whole accepts or rejects the specific logic (Thornton and Ocasio 1999). Future research could account for this internal heterogeneity and examine how the distribution of power inside organization among different interest groups interacts with performance feedback in its impact on the logic adoption decisions. In conclusion, our aim has been to inform and advance research in institutional theory by drawing attention to performance goals as a distinct filter affecting organizations’ responses to contested institutions. We also hope to have advanced the performance feedback theory by tracking the emergence of contested goals and the organizational reactions to these goals. Our results emphasize that institutions spread not only through inertial and mimetic processes, as portrayed in previous studies, but also via a feedback cycle between the contested goals and organizational responses to them that affect, in turn, their further adoption. Such findings broaden our understanding by showing that firms respond more strategically to institutional pressures than has been recognized before. Finally, we hope that the ideas and results presented in this paper become part of a solid foundation for a more complete understanding of the mechanisms that underlie institutionalization and of the relative importance of various performance goals that shape the this process. REFERENCES Argote, L., H.R. Greve. 2007. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm—40 Years and Counting: Introduction and Impact. Organ. Sci. 18(3) 337-349. Ashforth, B.E., B.W. Gibbs. 1990. The Double-Edge of Organizational Legitimation. Organ. Sci. 1(2) 177-194. Baum, J., P. Ingram. 1998. Survival-enhancing learning in the Manhattan Hotel Industry, 1898-1980. Management Sci. 44(7) 996-1016. Beatty, R., E. Zajac. 1994. Top management incentives, monitoring and risk sharing: A study of executive compensation, ownership and board structure in initial public offerings. Admin. Sci. Quart. 39 313-335. Berle, A.A., G.C. Means. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, New York. Bonacich, P. 1987. Power and centrality: The family of measures. American J. of Soc. 92 1170-1183. 32 Brehm, S., J. Brehm. 1981. Psychological reactance: A theory of freedom and control. Academic Press, New York. Crystal, G. 1984. Questions and Answers on Executive Compensation. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Cyert, R., J. March. 1963. A Behavorial Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Davis, G., H. Greve. 1997. Corporate elite networks and governance changes in the 1980s. American J. of Soc. 103 1-37. Denrell, J. 2003. Vicarious Learning, Undersampling of Failure, and the Myths of Management. Organ. Sci. 14(3) 227-243. DiMaggio, P.J., W.W. Powell. 1983. The iron case revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Rev. 48(April) 147-160. Dutton, J., L. Roberts, J. Bednar. 2010. Pathways for positive identity construction at work: Four types of positive identity and the building of social resources. Acad. of Management Rev. 35(2) 265-293. Edelman, L.B. 1990. Legal Environments and Organizational Governance: The Expansion of Due Process in the American Workplace. American J. of Soc. 95(6) 1401-1440. Fama, E., M. Jensen. 1983. The separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics 26 301-325. Galaskiewicz, J., R.S. Burt. 1991. Interorganization contagion in corporate philanthropy. Admin. Sci. Quart. 36 88-105. Gavetti, G., H.R. Greve, D.A. Levinthal, W. Ocasio. 2012. The Behavioral Theory of the Firm: Assessment and Prospects. Acad. Management Annals 6(1) 1-40. Greene, W. 2004. The behavior of the maximum likelihood estimator of limited dependent variable models in the presence of fixed effects. Econometrics J. 7 98-119. Greenwood, R., M. Raynard, F. Kodeih, E.R. Micelotta, M. Lounsbury. 2011. Institutional Complexity and Organizational Responses. Acad. Management Annals 5(1) 317-371. Greve, H. 1998. Performance, aspirations and risky organizational change. Admin. Sci. Quart. 43 58-86. Greve, H. 2002. Sticky aspirations: organizational time perspective and competitiveness. Organ. Sci. 13(1) 1-17. Greve, H. 2003a. A Behavioral Theory of R&D Expenditures and Innovations: Evidence from Shipbuilding. Acad. Management J. 46(6) 685-702. Greve, H. 2003b. Investment and the behavioral theory of the firm: evidence from shipbuilding. Indust. and Corporate Change 12(5) 1051-1076. Greve, H. 2003c. Organizational learning from performance feedback. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Greve, H. 2008. A behavioral theory of firm growth: Sequential attention to size and performance goals. Acad. Management J. 51 476-494. Guler, I., M.F. Guillen, J.M. Macpherson. 2002. Global competition, institutions, and the diffusion of organizational practices: The international spread of ISO 9000 quality certificates. Admin. Sci. Quart. 47 207232. Haveman, H., H. Rao. 1997. Structuring a theory of moral sentiments: Institutional and Organizational Coevolution in the Early Thrift Industry. American J. of Soc. 102(6) 1606-1651. Herman, J.L., S. Golan. 1993. The Effects of Standardized Testing on Teaching and Schools. Educational Measurement: Issues and Practice 12(4) 20-25. Hoffman, A.J. 1999. Institutional evolution and change: Environmentalism and the U.S. chemical industry. Acad. Management J. 42(4) 351-371. Iyer, D.N., K.D. Miller. 2008. Performance Feedback, Slack, and The Timing of Acquisitions. Acad. Management J. 51(4) 808-822. King, B.G., S.A. Soule. 2007. Social Movements as Extra-Institutional Entrepreneurs: The Effect of Protests on Stock Price Returns. Admin. Sci. Quart. 52(3) 413-442. La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, R. Vishny. 1999. The quality of government. J. of Law, Econom. and Organ. 15(1) 222-279. Lancaster, T. 2000. The incidental parameters problem since 1948. Journal of Econometrics 98 391-414. Leblebici, H., G.R. Salancik, A. Copay, T. King. 1991. Institutional Change and the Transformation of Interorganizational Fields: An Organizational History of the U.S. Radio Broadcasting Industry. Admin. Sci. Quart. 36(3) 333-363. Levitt, B., J. March. 1988. Organizational Learning. Annual Review of Sociology 14 319-340. 33 Locke, E.A., G.P. Latham, M. Erez. 1988. The Determinants of Goal Commitment. Academy of Management Review 13(1) 23-39. March, J.G., Z. Shapira. 1987. Managerial Perspectives on Risk and Risk Taking. Management Sci. 33(11) 14041418. McGahan, A.M., M.E. Porter. 2002. What Do We Know about Variance in Accounting Profitability? Management Sci. 48(7) 834-851. Meindl, J.R., S.B. Ehrlich. 1987. The Romance of Leadership and the Evaluation of Organizational Performance. Acad. Management J. 30(1) 91-109. Meyer, J.W., B. Rowan. 1977. Institutionalized organizations: Formal stucture as myth and ceremony. American J. of Soc. 83 340-363. Meyer, R., M. Hollerer. 2010. Meaning structures in a contested issue field: A topographic map of shareholder value in Austria. Acad. Management J. 53(6) 1241-1262. Miller, K.D., W.-R. Chen. 2004. Variable Organizational Risk Preferences: Tests of the March-Shapira Model. Acad. Management J. 47(1) 105-115. Mohr, J.W., H.K. Lee. 2000. From affirmative action to outreach: Discourse shifts at the University of California. Poetics 28(1) 47-71. Park, K.M. 2007. Antecedents of Convergence and Divergence in Strategic Positioning: The Effects of Performance and Aspiration on the Direction of Strategic Change. Organ. Sci. 18(3) 386-402. Raftery, A.E. 1996. Bayesian model selection in social research. P. Marsden, ed. Sociological Methodology. Basil Blackwell, Oxford, 111-163. Rao, H. 1998. Caveat emptor: The construction of nonprofit consumer watchdog organizations. American J. of Soc. 103(4) 912-961. Sauder, M., W.N. Espeland. 2009. The Discipline of Rankings: Tight Coupling and Organizational Change. American Sociological Rev. 74(1) 63-82. Sharma, S. 2000. Managerial Interpretations and Organizational Context as Predictors of Corporate Choice of Environmental Strategy. Acad. Management J. 43(4) 681-697. Shipan, C.R., C. Volden. 2006. Bottom-Up Federalism: The Diffusion of Antismoking Policies from U.S. Cities to States. American J. of Political Sci. 50 825-843. Shipilov, A., H. Greve, T. Rowley. 2010. When Do Interlocks Matter? Institutional Logics and the Diffusion of Multiple Corporate Governance Practices. Acad. Management J. 53(4) 846-864. Shipilov, A., S. Li. 2008. Can You Have Your Cake and Eat It Too? Structural Holes' Influence on Status Accumulation and Market Performance in Collaborative Networks. Admin. Sci. Quart. 53 73–108. Shipilov, A., S. Li, H. Greve. 2011. The Prince and the Pauper: Search and Brokerage in the Initiation of Status-Heterophilous Ties. Organ. Sci. 22(6) 1418–1434. Shipilov, A.V. 2009. Firm Scope Experience, Historic Multimarket Contact with Partners, Centrality, and the Relationship Between Structural Holes and Performance. Organ. Sci. 20(1) 85-106. Thornton, P., W. Ocasio. 1999. Institutional logics and the historical contingency of power in organizations: Executive succession in the higher education publishing industry, 1958-1990. American J. of Soc. 105(3) 801843. Thornton, P.H. 2002. The rise of the corporation in a craft industry: Conflict and conformity in institutional logics. Academy of Management Journal 45(1) 81-101. Thornton, P.H., W. Ocasio, M. Lounsbury. 2012. The Institutional Logics Perspective: A New Approach to Culture, Structure and Process. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Townley, B. 2002. The Role of Competing Rationalities in Institutional Change. Acad. Management J. 45(1) 163-179. Wei, L.J., D.Y. Lin, L. Weissfeld. 1989. Regression Analysis of Multivariate Incomplete Failure Time Data by Modeling Marginal Distributions. J. of the American Statistical Association 84 1065-1073. Westphal, J., E. Zajac. 1998. The symbolic management of stockholders: Corporate governance reforms and shareholder reactions. Admin. Sci. Quart. 43 127-153. Westphal, J.D. 1998. Board Games: How CEOs Adapt to Increases in Structural Board Independence from Management. Admin. Sci. Quart. 43(3) 511-537. 34 Wright, R.A., V.G. Wadley, M. Danner, P.N. Phillips. 1992. Persuasion, reactance, and judgments of interpersonal appeal. European J. of Social Psych. 22(1) 85-91. 35 Table 1: Descriptive Statistics Variable Mean S.D. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 Board reform practice 0.199 0.399 1 2 Financial sector 0.151 0.359 -0.039 1 3 Extremely low BSCI 0.050 0.219 -0.063 0.026 1 4 US stock crosslisting 0.342 0.474 0.079 -0.050 -0.150 1 5 CCGG ownership 0.447 0.497 0.074 -0.050 0.107 0.123 1 6 Market/book value 0.363 20.795 0.020 0.020 0.005 0.051 -0.049 1 7 Ln net sales 7.070 2.068 0.007 0.141 0.033 0.023 0.025 -0.032 1 8 Centrality 4.075 14.747 -0.087 0.509 0.046 -0.173 -0.006 0.013 0.299 1 9 Interlock practice 43.743 37.885 0.079 0.140 -0.005 0.083 0.070 0.035 0.542 0.196 1 7.504 1.714 0.077 -0.038 -0.434 0.150 -0.166 0.030 0.013 -0.161 0.183 1 10 Own practice 11 12 13 11 ROA below AL -1.182 3.279 0.020 0.054 0.051 0.031 0.086 -0.027 0.229 0.058 0.149 -0.090 1 12 ROA above AL 1.380 2.782 0.023 -0.169 -0.054 -0.017 0.004 0.041 -0.065 -0.107 -0.092 0.038 0.179 1 13 BSCI × ROA below AL -12.916 15.124 0.104 -0.156 -0.575 0.207 -0.020 -0.018 -0.141 -0.243 -0.007 0.700 -0.091 0.073 1 14 BSCI × ROA above AL 3.459 6.247 0.097 -0.069 -0.128 0.122 0.069 0.024 -0.042 -0.127 0.117 0.583 -0.032 -0.013 0.473 Note: N = 3,506 36 Table 2: Logit Models of Governance Practices Adoption Financial sector Extremely low BSCI US stock crosslisting CCGG ownership Market/book value Ln net sales Centrality Interlock practice Own practice ROA below AL Model 1 0.167 (0.180) −0.655* (0.303) 0.160 (0.118) 0.100 (0.273) 0.005 (0.004) 0.027 (0.032) −0.032*** (0.008) 0.007*** (0.002) −0.051 (0.035) Model 2 0.159 (0.181) −0.651* (0.303) 0.158 (0.118) 0.097 (0.273) 0.005 (0.004) 0.020 (0.032) −0.032*** (0.008) 0.007*** (0.002) −0.048 (0.035) 0.018 (0.017) 0.000 (0.017) Model 3 0.219 (0.183) −0.496 (0.330) 0.140 (0.119) 0.104 (0.277) 0.005 (0.004) 0.028 (0.032) −0.030*** (0.008) 0.008*** (0.002) −0.225*** (0.058) 0.019 (0.017) 0.001 (0.017) 0.016** (0.006) 0.030** (0.010) −1.906*** (0.346) 3,506 26 −1.862*** (0.350) 3,506 28 −0.740 (0.462) 3,506 30 ROA above AL BSCI below AL BSCI above AL BSCI × ROA below AL BSCI × ROA above AL Constant Observations Degrees of freedom Model 4 0.229 (0.182) −0.575+ (0.331) 0.127 (0.118) 0.087 (0.276) 0.005 (0.004) 0.025 (0.032) −0.032*** (0.008) 0.008*** (0.002) −0.215*** (0.058) −0.005 (0.019) −0.021 (0.021) 0.012+ (0.006) 0.022* (0.011) −0.005* (0.002) 0.004+ (0.002) −0.785+ (0.461) 3,506 32 Note: All models contain fixed effects of individual years and individual practices. +p < 0.1; *p < 0.05; **p < 0.01; ***p < 0.001, two tailed tests 37 Model 5 0.252 (0.219) −0.692+ (0.377) 0.202 (0.140) 0.173 (0.301) 0.005 (0.004) 0.037 (0.037) −0.036*** (0.008) 0.009*** (0.002) −0.289*** (0.070) −0.006 (0.021) −0.028 (0.024) 0.015* (0.007) 0.025* (0.012) −0.005* (0.003) 0.005+ (0.003) −0.542 (0.525) 3,506 32 Table 3: Effects of Varying the Weights Assigned to Social Aspirations for BSCI and ROA Weight for BSCI Social Aspirations (GBSCI) 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 0.0 224 224 224 225 226 228 229 231 233 233 234 3388 3388 3388 3388 3387 3385 3383 3380 3377 3374 3372 0.1 224 224 225 225 226 228 229 231 233 234 234 3388 3388 3388 3388 3387 3385 3382 3379 3376 3373 3371 0.2 224 225 225 225 227 229 230 232 234 235 235 3388 3388 3388 3388 3387 3384 3381 3378 3375 3372 3370 0.3 224 225 225 226 227 229 231 233 235 236 236 3388 3387 3388 3387 3386 3383 3380 3377 3373 3371 3369 0.4 224 225 225 226 227 229 231 234 235 236 236 Weight for 3387 3387 3387 3387 3386 3383 3380 3377 3373 3370 3368 ROA Social 0.5 224 225 224 225 227 229 231 233 234 235 235 Aspirations 3387 3387 3387 3388 3386 3384 3380 3377 3374 3370 3369 (GROA) 0.6 224 225 225 225 226 228 230 232 233 234 234 3387 3387 3387 3388 3387 3384 3381 3378 3375 3372 3370 0.7 224 225 224 225 226 227 229 231 232 234 234 3387 3387 3387 3388 3387 3385 3382 3379 3376 3373 3371 0.8 224 224 224 225 226 227 229 231 232 233 233 3387 3387 3387 3388 3387 3385 3382 3379 3376 3373 3371 0.9 224 224 224 225 226 227 229 231 232 233 233 3387 3387 3387 3388 3387 3385 3382 3379 3376 3373 3371 1.0 224 224 224 225 226 228 229 231 232 233 234 3387 3387 3387 3388 3387 3385 3382 3379 3376 3373 3371 Notes: The top value in each cell is the Wald statistic; the bottom value is the BIC statistic. We vary the weight G given to social (versus historical) aspirations for both BSCI and ROA performance. G=1 means that a firm pays attention only to social aspirations, G=0 means that a firm pays attention only to historic aspirations, G=0.5 means that a firm pays attention both to social and historic aspirations. We track how changes in GROA and GBSCI improve model fit as compared to the baseline where GROA =GBSCI =0.5. Higher Wald statistics with differences greater than 3.84 support the bestfitting model at p < 0.05. Between-model BIC differences exceeding 6 indicate strong support for the model with a smaller BIC (equivalent to p < 0.05). For the reference model, in which GROA = GBSCI = 0.5, the BIC is 3384 and the Wald statistic is 229. There is strong support for the model in which firms pay equal attention to social and historic aspirations based on profitability (GROA = 0.5) but they pay no attention to historic aspirations based on governance score GBSCI = 1.0. This model’s BIC statistic is 3369 and the Wald statistic is 235. 38 39 Figure 2: Predicted probability of adoption 40