Report for Gundagai Shire on Efficiency and Scale Projections Arising From Proposed Amalgamations. This report provides detailed consideration of scale, efficiency, liability and harmonisation matters raised in my earlier report: ‘Response to IPART Assessments: Coolamon, Gundagai, Junee and Temora Councils’. In particular I consider the proposed merger of ‘Gundagai and Tumut’ and the tripartite proposal of ‘Gundagai, Tumut and Tumbarumba’ against the Gundagai stand-alone case. IPART deemed Gundagai Shire to be ‘Not Fit’ according to (i) scale and capacity, (ii) sustainability and (iii) efficiency. In particular IPART (2015, p. 219) state that ‘the proposed Rural Council Proposal (sic) is not as good as the ILGRP’s preferred option to merge with Tumut’. Moreover, the IPART (2015, p. 219) report states that ‘Gundagai’s small and declining population of 3,450 in 2031 means it is unlikely to cost-effectively provide services to the local community’. Therefore IPART makes three claims which can be subject to empirical test: (i) that the scale of Gundagai is presently insufficient and that it can be improved through the proposed amalgamation, (ii) that the proposed amalgamation will be more cost-effective (technically efficient) than the stand-alone case and (iii) that the council is relatively inefficient. Assessing these claims is the principle aim of the report, although I also provide information on other important matters relating to amalgamation which should be considered in the absence of a comprehensive merger business case. I stress that this report should not be considered as a substitute for due diligence. 1 Data Envelopment Analysis of Existing Scale and Efficiency Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) allows for a nuanced estimation of relative municipal scale and technical efficiency. Unlike other empirical techniques DEA does not require a priori specification of functional form, is able to accommodate multiple outputs, and provides specific point estimates for each council or proposed amalgamated entity. Technical efficiency (TE) is evaluated in terms of the ability of a council to convert inputs (staff and capital) into a set of outputs (number of residential assessments, number of farm assessments, number of business assessments and total length of municipal roads) (see Drew, Kortt and Dollery (2015a) for the justification of the DEA specification employed). It is important to note that the Independent Local Government Review Panel (ILGRP), Office of Local Government (OLG) and Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal (IPART) have provided various estimates of an assumed optimal scale for rural councils based on 2031 population projections. However, none of the agencies have provided a publicly documented empirical analysis to support the assumptions. Moreover, it is clear that 2031 population projections are the incorrect functional unit for evaluating municipal scale. Put simply, councils do not produce people. Instead, local government produces a heterogeneous mix of goods and services orientated towards ‘service to property’ (for example, rubbish, water and sewerage). Higher tiers of government tend to have a ‘services to individual’ orientation (for instance, education, health and welfare) but Australian local government does not. Moreover, over a quarter of municipal expenditure is associated with the provision of road infrastructure and this is, in fact, negatively correlated with population (ie. as population increases the length of municipal road responsibilities tend to decrease). Therefore, the approach taken by the various independent and Government agencies implicitly and erroneously assumes that: 2 1. Councils do not spend resources in servicing businesses 2. Councils do not spend resources on building and maintaining transport infrastructure 3. The cost of servicing individuals living on farms is the same as the cost structure for servicing individuals living in ‘town’ 4. That the cost of servicing a property increases in proportion to the number of individuals living in a property (ie. that the cost of servicing a house with four people is four times the cost of servicing a house with a single person). Clearly, the implied assumptions are void ab initio. Moreover, this fundamental misconception regarding the nature of NSW local government has resulted in incorrect conclusions regarding appropriate municipal scale and concomitant effects on efficiency. Thus, the following DEA scenario testing fills a critical gap in the ‘independent expert’s’ analysis. DEA employs linear programming to create an efficient frontier (comprised of the councils which most efficiently convert inputs into outputs) and then estimates relative efficiency of councils lying in the interior of the efficiency frontier according to their distance from the frontier. The data envelopment algorithm is detailed below: min θ,λ θ, s.t. -yi + Yλ ≥ 0, θxi – Xλ ≥ 0, I1′λ = 1 λ≥0 3 where yi is a vector of outputs and xi is a vector of inputs, θ is a scalar (the efficiency score for each council) and λ a vector of constants. The subscript i refers to the ith council and the inequalities ensure non-negative weights. The CRS (Constant Returns to Scale) specification evaluates inefficient councils against any peer on the frontier – irrespective of size. The variable returns to scale (VRS) algorithm is achieved by adding the convexity constraint I1′λ = 1 so that inefficient councils are only evaluated against municipalities of a similar size. Under both estimates efficient councils are given a score of 1 and inefficient councils assigned a score between 0 and 11. Scale estimates are simply the quotient of CRS and VRS efficiency scores and a third estimate (non-increasing returns to scale (NIRS)) is made by imposing the restriction I1′λ ≤ 1 so that the nature of the scale inefficiency can be determined. An input orientation was adopted for the DEA which ‘minimises inputs while satisfying at least the given output levels’ (Ji and Lee, 2010, p. 268). This orientation is to be preferred given that councils take outputs as exogenous (that is, councils have little control over the number of rateable properties nor the length of municipal roads in the short-run). Tables 1 and 2 present measures of relative scale and technical efficiency for the existing municipal structures in NSW calculated according to 2014 financial data. This provides valuable contextual information for interpreting the individual scale and efficiency estimates of existing Gundagai, Tumut and Tumbarumba councils (see, Table 3 for details). The bootstrapped DEA estimates suggest that Gundagai and Tumbarumba are slightly under optimal scale, whilst Tumut is considerably over-scaled2.Thus, any merger predicated on a correct specification of scale would appear to be ill-advised. 1 Thus a council with an efficiency score of 0.95 is far more technically efficient than a council with a score of 0.45. 2 It might be noted that the scale estimates are slightly different to the previous report. This is because the current estimates have been bias corrected which is an empirical method for providing greater certainty in estimates for important decision-making purposes. Essentially, bias correction repeats the DEA routine hundreds of times using re-sampling procedures and then employs a supplementary algorithm to adjust ‘raw’ 4 We now turn to scenario testing in order that we might fully appreciate the scale and technical efficiency implications of the proposed amalgamation structures. Table 1. Scale Results for New South Wales Councils – Pre Amalgamation 2014 Amalgamation Scale Number Mean scale Stand. Dev. Min. Max. status Entire State OS 12 1 0 1 1 IRS 72 0.93758 0.080932 0.664797 0.999984 DRS 68 0.924319 0.090352 0.580372 0.999587 Notes: OS = optimal scale; IRS = increasing returns to scale; DRS = decreasing returns to scale. Table 2. Efficiency Results (CRS) for New South Wales Councils – Pre Amalgamation 2014 Amalgamation Efficiency Number Mean CRS Stand. Min. Max. status Measure Efficiency Dev. Entire State OS 12 1 0 1 1 IRS 72 0.676465 0.149675 0.328472 0.99997 DRS 68 0.701715 0.156546 0.3776 0.999002 Notes: OS = optimal scale; IRS = increasing returns to scale; DRS = decreasing returns to scale. Table3. Bootstrapped Existing Scale and Efficiency of Gundagai, Tumut and Tumbarumba Municipalities, 2014 Amalgamation CRS Scale Returns to status Scale Gundagai 0.636079 0.960236 IRS Tumut 0.56616 0.822201 DRS Tumbarumba 0.387183 0.971039 IRS Notes: OS = optimal scale; IRS = increasing returns to scale; DRS = decreasing returns to scale. scale and efficiency scores (see, Simar and Wilson, 2000). It is a time consuming procedure which is only possible in a dedicated report of this type. 5 Data Envelopment Analysis Scenario Testing Cooper, Seiford and Tone (2007) outline an empirical method for estimating the efficiency and scale effects arising from proposed mergers in the Japanese banking industry. I have adapted this method in order that I might estimate the efficiency and scale effects of putative municipal merger options. In common with all empirical techniques some assumptions must be made. In particular, I assume that the inputs and outputs of merged entities will be the sum of the inputs and outputs of the existing councils. In the case of outputs this seems to be an indisputable assumption – it is completely reasonable to expect that the merger of councils will not alter the sum of the length of municipal roads nor the sum of residential farm and business assessments in the short-run. Moreover, the prohibition on forced redundancies for nonsenior staff found in s354F of the Local Government Act (1993) along with the stipulation that staff numbers should be maintained in rural centres (s228CA(2)) would seem to suggest that staff expenditure following amalgamation is likely to be materially consistent with the sum of existing staff expenditures. Indeed, staff expenditure increased in the short-run following the 2007/08 Queensland amalgamations (Drew, Kortt and Dollery, 2013). It is possible however, that a council may alter the quantum of capital employed to provide municipal services subsequent to amalgamation and this could introduce a small error into the scale and efficiency projections (Drew, Kortt and Dollery, 2015a). However, it should be borne in mind that (i) evidence from the 2007/08 Queensland amalgamations suggests that additional capital will be deployed in the short-run following merger (Drew, Kortt and Dollery, 2013) and (ii) that the same assumption has been made for all four merger cases (thus any error introduced is likely to be the same for all cases and will therefore have little effect on the decision making utility of the empirical strategy). Once again, we have employed an iterative algorithm to provide added confidence in the DEA estimates. 6 Table 4 provides details of the CRS efficiency and scale estimates arising from the various merger scenarios. VRS efficiency is not relevant because it adjusts for the effect of scale – the entire purpose of this exercise is to gauge the effect of merger on scale and hence on CRS technical efficiency. Unsurprisingly (given the results detailed in Table3), both of the proposed amalgamation scenarios would result in far worse scale outcomes than the standalone case. Moreover, the CRS relative technical efficiency estimates are lower for each of the proposed amalgamations when compared with the stand-alone case. Thus, we have empirically evaluated the first two assumptions made in the IPART (2015) report. In both cases IPART’s (2015) assumptions, based on it’s fundamental misconception of the nature of NSW municipal services, have been empirically shown to be incorrect: the proposed mergers will in all probability result in decreasing returns to scale and less cost-effective service provision. With respect to the third claim made by IPART (2015) – that Gundagai Shire is relatively inefficient – it is important to note that Gundagai’s existing relative technical efficiency is just marginally lower than the average for NSW councils with increasing returns to scale (IRS). Table 4. Bootstrapped Scale and Efficiency of Merged Entities Gundagai, Tumut and Tumbarumba Municipalities, 2014 Amalgamation status CRS Scale Returns to Scale Gundagai stand alone 0.636079 0.960236 IRS Gundagai-Tumut 0.592894 0.64096 DRS Gundagai-Tumut0.516644 0.488395 DRS Tumbarumba It is interesting to note that the empirical evidence seems to have close parallels with the survey results cited in the IPART (2015, p. 220) report which had just ‘24% of respondents agreeing to a merger, with 50% of these agreeing it should be with Tumut’. Therefore, it 7 appears that Gundagai residents intuitively understand that merger, in and of itself, will not improve scale and technical efficiency. This conclusion by the residents of Gundagai is also supported by IPART’s (2015) own data relating to the ‘fitness’ outcomes of previously merged councils. Just 7 out of the 26 merged entities arising from the 2000 to 2004 NSW amalgamations were deemed by IPART to be ‘fit’ for the future. It is therefore somewhat surprising that the very same document would urge councils to merge in order to become ‘fit’3! 3 One council, Canada Bay, chose to pursue a voluntary merger in their quest for a ‘fit’ assessment. 8 Implicit and Explicit Liabilities Table 5 provides details of the gross implicit and explicit liabilities which might be assumed by Gundagai residents in the event of a merger. I have elected not to present this data nett of assets given my observation that asset values may not be sufficiently robust as to allow for accurate calculations. Gundagai’s total explicit and implicit liabilities per assessment is comparable with Tumut but around half of Tumbarumba’s figure. A merger with Tumut would result in a slightly lower total liability per assessment for Gundagai residents (approximately $290 per assessment) whilst the tripartite merger proposal would result in a slight increase for Gundagai residents (around $231 per assessment). However, great care must be taken with this data – in particular, with respect to the estimated cost to bring assets to a satisfactory condition. The OLG definition for this estimate in the special schedule of the municipal financial statements is vague and, in fact, a tautology. As a result of this definition deficit, there has been a significant unexplained reduction in this estimate across the state (around 25% reduction in the ‘estimated cost to bring assets to a satisfactory standard’ over the last two financial years). This emphasises the need for careful due diligence prior to an unconditional offer to merge. There has been some conjecture that NSW government compensation will address inequities arising from assumption of liabilities. This is completely incorrect. Under the current Fit for the Future package it is quite likely that the compensation provided by Government will not even cover the one-off costs of amalgamation (let alone ongoing disruption costs and diseconomies of scale). Moreover, it has been claimed, in the media, that the estimated cost to bring assets up to a satisfactory condition is not an implicit liability. This statement is also demonstrably false. If the combined entity is ever going to address infrastructure backlogs – which is one of the principal motivations for Fit for the Future – then clearly at some stage residents of the combined shire will be required to provide the funding. 9 Table 5. Implicit and Explicit Liabilities upon Merger (per Assessment Share in Parentheses) $’000 Council No. Assessments Borrowings (Current and Non-Current) Other Liabilities (excluding borrowings) Gundagai 2,539 Tumut 6,377 Tumbarumba 2,513 GundagaiTumut GundagaiTumutTumbarumba 8,916 3,002 (1.182) 6,878 (1.079) 3,641 (1.449) 9,880 (1.108) 13,521 (1.183) 2,728 (1.074) 5,075 (0.796) 4,560 (1.815) 7,803 (0.875) 12,363 (1.082) 11,429 Estimated Cost to Bring Assets to a Satisfactory Standard 60 (0.024) 0 (0.000) 2,753 (1.096) 60 (0.007) 2,813 (0.246) Total Explicit and Implicit Liabilities 5,790 (2.280) 11,953 (1.874) 10,954 (4.359) 17,743 (1.990) 28,697 (2.511) Source: Number of assessments from OLG (2015); Financial data from audited financial statements 2014-15. Community of Interest There have now been a total of five municipal de-amalgamations following forced mergers: four in Queensland and one in Victoria. Thus, the spectre of subsequent de-amalgamation must be considered to be a very real proposition. When amalgamation is followed by deamalgamation the community is generally required to pay for both events – the effect on municipal financial sustainability is therefore devastating. One reason why amalgamations fail is because ‘experts’ in capital cities have neglected to consider whether the existing communities are sufficiently similar as to avoid a loss in economic welfare (Drew and Dollery, 2015g). The best people to make this judgement are the residents of the respective jurisdictions. However, a large difference in the OLG socio-economic rating along with differences in the proportion of individuals identifying in certain demographic categories suggests that there may be significant differences in the populations. 10 The whole raison d’etre for decentralised government is that ‘by tailoring outputs of such goods and services to the particular preferences and circumstances of their constituencies, decentralised provision increases economic welfare above that which results from the more uniform levels of such services that are likely under national provision’ (Oates, 1999, p. 1121). Therefore, it follows that if communities with different preferences for municipal goods are forced to amalgamate then a loss of economic welfare will be the likely result. This in turn may promote de-amalgamation activism (Drew and Dollery, 2015g). Table 6. Community Indicators, 2014. Council Population No. Councillors ATSI NESB Average wage Gundagai Tumut Tumbarumba 3,747 11,316 3,521 8 7 8 2.4 4.5 2.5 1.5 3.2 3 43,134.90 45,408.50 41,838.80 Socio Economic Rating 64 41 59 Over 65 Under 15 19.9 19.6 20.1 20.7 20.2 18.7 Source: ABS (2015). It is also important for careful consideration to be given to the political structure of any proposed merged entity in order to ensure that a merger, rather than a take-over results (Spicer, 2012). There is no correct solution; however, I have proposed a possible political structure just to illustrate the complexity and importance of this decision. My proposal is for two wards to be drawn according to the previous municipal boundaries (with four representatives apiece). This would increase the likelihood that both communities might have an equal voice in the early years following amalgamation. However, this structure could also result in a ‘hung’ chamber (as was the case leading up to the Delatite de-amalgamation). Moreover, it effectively halves the democratic representation for Gundagai residents. My point in floating this suggestion is to illustrate that the political structure of an amalgamated entity will be critical to the success of the venture. I do not believe sufficient attention has been given to this matter by councils contemplating amalgamation. 11 Decision makers might also consider the strategic implications of a voluntary amalgamation. It is true that a voluntary merger should secure Government funding. However, it is also true that the Fit for the Future funding model is unlikely to cover the cost of merger. Moreover, it is by no means certain that the Government will take the political risk of denying the same level of funding to communities forced to amalgamate. In addition, to my mind, voluntary merger effectively shuts the door on any prospect of a de-amalgamation should the merged entity fail to satisfy residents. Given the increasing occurrence of de-amalgamations, and the empirical evidence in this report which casts doubt on the success of the proposed mergers, I believe it is important for residents to consider whether it might be prudent to keep future options open. 12 Harmonisation Table 7 details the existing fees and rates applicable to various categories of properties in the three municipalities. After an amalgamation, fees and charges will need to be harmonised. The final rates set for an amalgamated entity would be decided by the new Administration. However, it is reasonable to expect that residents currently paying relatively low fees (for instance Gundagai’s average domestic waste charge of $283.92) might be required to pay more should the council merge with an entity with higher charges (for example, Tumut which has a domestic waste charge of $344.75). The probability of this outcome is quite high when one considers that the international scholarly evidence has demonstrated that service levels are invariably increased following amalgamation (see, for instance, Dur and Staal, 2008; Steiner, 2003). Table 7. Existing Rates and Charges Requiring Harmonisation ($) Council Average Residential Rate 434.93 Gundagai 697.47 Tumut Tumbarumba 384.18 Source: OLG (2015). Average Farm Rate Average Business Rate Typical Water and Sewer 1,967.81 1,043.91 1,640.69 505.88 1,861.43 709.68 1,123 1,107 1,268 Average Domestic Waste Charge 283.92 344.75 312.90 13 Conclusion IPART (2015) made three empirically testable claims in its assessment of Gundagai. The first two claims – based on what appears to have been flawed assumptions – have failed to stand up to robust empirical scrutiny. Specifically, I find both merger scenarios will result in overscaled entities with a concomitant reduction in efficiency. With respect to the last claim – that the council is relatively inefficient – the empirical evidence suggests that Gundagai shire exhibits technical efficiency which is only marginally below the level of it’s peers. I also examined the implicit and explicit liabilities which might be assumed by Gundagai residents should the merger proceed. I found that – on a per assessment basis – a merger with Tumut would result in a marginal decrease in total gross liabilities, but that a merger with Tumut and Tumbarumba might be expected to result in a slight increase in total gross liabilities. I also explored some of the complex decision making which will need to be addressed around political structure and rate and fee harmonisation. I believe that the success of any merged venture will depend heavily on the detail relating to these decisions. In short, neither of the proposed merger scenarios will produce superior results to the standalone case in terms of technical efficiency or scale. Continued participation in REROC should adequately address capacity elements. Thus, there is no empirical basis for the assumptions put forward by IPART(2015) in its report4. This is an independent critique of the IPART assessments based on a desk top analysis of IPART reports, audited financial statements, and Fit For the Future proposals. I have no conflict of interest to declare and had no part in the IPART assessment process, nor in compiling the various Fit For the Future proposals for Gundagai Shire. It is my understanding that Teresa Boyd, CA is investigating the effect of a merger on the ‘sustainability’ claim made by IPART (2015). 4 14 The advice provided is based on my professional judgement after reviewing various documents associated with the IPART assessment and conducting a number of empirical estimations. I have taken source documents at face value and have made no efforts to verify the accuracy of financial statements or other documentation as this was outside of my brief. It must therefore be stressed that this report is in no way to be considered as a substitute for due diligence. Moreover, any council contemplating merger should seriously consider conducting thorough due diligence, particularly in relation to the written down value of assets, estimates of required maintenance and accuracy of non-current liabilities. 15 References Abelson, P. and Joyeux, R. (2015). Smoke and Mirrors – Fallacies in the New South Wales Government’s Views on Local Government Financial Capacity. Public Money and Management, 35(4): 315-320. Coelli, T., Prasada Rao, D., O’Donnell, C. and Battese, G. ( 2005). An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis – Second Edition. Springer: New York. Commonwealth of Australia. Local Government (Financial Assistance) Act 1995. Cooper, W., Seiford, L. and Tone, K. (2007). Data Envelopment Analysis – Second Edition. Springer: New York. Drew, J. and B. Dollery. (2014). Would Bigger Councils Yield Scale Economies in the Greater Perth Metropolitan Region? A Critique of the Metropolitan Local Government Review for Perth Local Government. Australian Journal of Public Administration, 73(1), 128-137. Drew, J. and Dollery, B. (2015a) Less Haste More Speed: The Fit for Future Reform Program in New South Wales Local Government. Australian Journal of Public Administration, DOI: 10.1111/1467-8500.12158. Drew, J. and B. Dollery. (2015b). Road to Ruin? Consistency, Transparency and Horizontal Equalisation of Road Grant Allocations in Eastern Mainland Australian States. Public Administration Quarterly, 39(3): 517-545. Drew, J. and Dollery, B. (2015c) How High Should They Jump? An Empirical Method for Setting Municipal Financial Ratio Performance Benchmarks. Australian Journal of Public Administration, DOI: 10.1111/1467-8500.12152. Drew, J. and Dollery, B. (2015d). Inconsistent Depreciation Practice and Public Policymaking: Local Government Reform in New South Wales. Australian Accounting Review, 25(1), 28-37. Drew, J. and Dollery, B. (2015e). Summary Execution: The Impact of Alternative Summarization Strategies on Local Governments. Public Administration Quarterly, In Print. Drew, J and Dollery, B (2015f). A Fair Go? A Response to the Independent Local Government Review Panel’s Assessment of Municipal Taxation in New South Wales. Australian Tax Forum, 30: 1-19. Drew, J and Dollery, B (2015g). Breaking Up is Hard to do: The De-amalgamation of Delatite Shire. Public Finance and Management, 15(1): 1-23. Drew, J., Kortt, M. and B. Dollery. (2013). Did the Big Stick Work? An Empirical Assessment of Scale Economies and the Queensland Forced Amalgamation Program, Local Government Studies, DOI: 10.1080/03003930.2013.874341. 16 Drew, J., Kortt, M. and Dollery, B. (2015a). No Aladdin’s Cave in New South Wales? Local Government Amalgamation, Scale Economies and Data Envelopment Specification. Administration & Society, DOI: 10.1177/0095399715581045. Drew, J., Kortt, M. and Dollery, B. (2015b). Peas in a Pod: Are Efficient Municipalities Also Financially Sustainable? Australian Accounting Review, In Print. Dur and Staal (2008). Local Public Good Provision, Municipal Consolidation, and National Transfers. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 38: 160-73. Fahey, G. (2015). A Functional Municipal Expenditure Analysis for New South Wales. Masters Dissertation, Unpublished. ILGRP (Independent Local Government Review Panel) (2013). Revitalising Local Government: Final report of the NSW Independent Local Government Review Panel, October 2013. ILGRP: Sydney. IPART (Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal) (2015). Assessment of Council Fit for the Future Proposals: Local Government – Final Report, October 2015. IPART: Sydney. Ji, Y. and Lee, C. (2010). Data Envelopment Analysis. The Stata Journal, 10(2): 267-280. Ladd, H. and Yinger, J. (1989). America’s Ailing Cities: Fiscal health and the Design of Urban Policy. John Hopkin’s University Press, London. QTC (2009), Review of Local Government Amalgamation Costs Funding Submissions—Final Summary Report. QTC: Brisbane. QTC (2012), De-Amalgamation Analysis of Sunshine Coast Regional Council. QTC: Brisbane. Simar, L. and Wilson, P. (2000). A General methodology for Bootstrapping in NonParametric Frontier Models. Journal of Applied Statistics, 27(6): 779-802. Spicer, Z. (2012). Post-Amalgamation Politcis: How Does Consolidation Impact Community Decision-Making? Canadian Journal of Urban Research, 21(2): 90-111. Steiner, R (2003). The Causes Spread and Effects of Intermunicipal Cooperation and Municipal Mergers in Switzerland. Public Management Review, 5(4): 551-71. TCorp (NSW Treasury Corporation) (2013). Financial Sustainability of the New South Wales Local Government Sector: Findings, Recommendations and Analysis. TCorp: Sydney. 17