An assessment of the contract farming system in improving market access for smallholder poultry farmers in Bangladesh Ismat Ara Begum1, Mohammad Jahangir Alam2, Sanzidur Rahman3 and Guido Van Huylenbroeck4 Abstract The poultry sector in Bangladesh has undergone a phenomenal transformation from a backyard system to commercial farming since the 1990s. However, the sector faces a number of obstacles to overcome before small farmers can get remunerative price from their production. Contract farming system is one such institutional initiative that could play an important role in mediating and bridging these issues which are beyond reach of the small scale poultry farmers. The present chapter explores ways to link smallholders with commercial poultry production and examines whether contract farming can improve market access for smallholder poultry farmers in Bangladesh. Contract farming can improve market access and inadequate farm income amongst smallholder through production credits, marketing facilities and extension services. Our results show that contract farming can be taken as a promising strategy for small scale commercial poultry farming business aimed at enhancing farm income, improve efficiency in production and providing assured market. Well-organized contract farming does provide such market linkages and appear to offer an important way through which smallholders can run farms commercially. 1 Department of Agricultural Economics, Ghent University, 9000 Ghent, Belgium and Department of Agricultural Economics, Bangladesh Agricultural University, Bangladesh; E-mail: ishameen@yahoo.com 2 Department of Agricultural Economics, Ghent University, 9000 Ghent, Belgium and Department of Agribusiness and Marketing, Bangladesh Agricultural University, Bangladesh 3 4 School of Geography, Earth and Environmental Sciences, the University of Plymouth, UK Department of Agricultural Economics, Ghent University, 9000 Ghent, Belgium 1 1. Introduction The poultry sub-sector is an important avenue in fostering agricultural growth and reduce malnutrition for the people in Bangladesh. Poultry meat alone contributes 37 percent of the total meat production in Bangladesh. Apart from this, poultry contributes about 22 to 27 percent of the total animal protein supply in the country (Prabakaran, 2003). This subsector has proved as an attractive economic activity, thereby, indicating its` importance for the entire economy. The sector accounts for 14 percent of the total value of livestock output and is growing rapidly (Raihan and Mahmud, 2008). During 1970-80, the poultry population growth rate was 0.7 percent which increased to 4 percent per year during 19902005 (Begum, 2008). The current market size is $1 billion with about 150,000 small and medium enterprises. The sector employs nearly 5 million people directly or indirectly (The Poultry Site.com, 2007). Although meat production has been increasing over time in the country but the per capita availability (2.92 kilogram/year) is far below the minimum requirement (7.67 kilogram/year) (Begum, 2008). Moreover, local scavenging chickens dominate poultry production (86 percent) and remaining 14 percent of the meat comes from commercial farming system, of which 90 percent comes from small scale commercial farms and only 10 percent from large scale commercial farms (BBS, 2005). The poultry production of Bangladesh is mostly under small farmers’ management system. Huque and Stem (1993) found that about 96 percent of egg and 98 percent of chicken meat were produced by small farmers in Bangladesh. However, this situation has not changed significantly over time. Despite the contribution of poultry sector to the economy and small farmers’ livelihood, the production system is not adequately market oriented. There are a number of obstacles to overcome before small farmers can get remunerative price as well as profit from poultry production. Given this backdrop, the present chapter explores ways to link small farmers 2 with commercial poultry production system and evaluate whether contract farming can improve market access for smallholder poultry farmers in Bangladesh. The remainder of the chapter is organized as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of the existing poultry production and input-output marketing system in Bangladesh. A case study of contract farming system in Bangladesh poultry sector is discussed in Section 3. Section 4 discusses the effectiveness of contracting system in promoting smallholders’ access to modern marketing channels which is then followed by a discussion of external factors. Section 6 provides conclusions and draws policy implications. 2. Overview of current poultry production and marketing system 2.1. Existing poultry production system The poultry farming system in Bangladesh can be broadly divided into two: (a) traditional rural backyard or scavenging system; and (b) commercial system. Scavenging poultry farm can be defined as domesticated fowl (from a few to 60 birds) maintained either for hobby or for non-commercial egg and meat production. These chickens roam in and around the farmer’s homestead area which serves as a major part of their feed requirements. Commercial poultry farming can be defined as those farms which have a number of domesticated fowl (more than 200 birds) maintained primarily for commercial egg and meat production with housing, management and marketing facilities. Operationally, small scale commercial producers in Bangladesh refer to those having less than 5,000 birds in each batch, whereas large scale poultry producers have more than 5,000 birds. Most of the poultry farms in Bangladesh are under small commercial farm category. 2.2. Marketing system of poultry products Transformation from backyard to commercial farming was not only due to technological progress or sectors` development policy but also by institutional innovations in input delivery and marketing of outputs. The expansion of the commercial poultry sector has 3 resulted in a decline in real prices of poultry products and consumption has consequently increased (Begum et al. 2012). But marketing system of poultry products are not well organized yet. Till now broilers are sold as live birds on weight basis and table eggs are sold at a rate for 100 eggs through bargaining. A brief discussion on input and output market for poultry and its products is presented below. 2.2.1. Day old chicks Among 120 hatcheries in the country, 50 are fully functional at present, others are either partially operating or are temporarily closed. Out of these hatcheries, 50 percent are located in those areas where concentration of poultry farms is the highest. Of these, approximately 56 percent of the hatcheries are involved in the production of day-old chicks (DOCs) from parent stock and 11 of these hatcheries procuring DOCs are government owned (Saleque, 1999). Main hatcheries in Bangladesh such as Aftab Bahumukhi Farm Limited, Paragon Poultry Limited, Biman Poultry Complex, Quazi Farms Limited etc. are totally dependent on import of parent stock from USA, the Netherland, France, Germany etc. Bangladesh totally depends on exotic strains of chicken which is sensitive to temperature, nutrition and management. As a result, the productive performance of foreign strains in Bangladesh varies widely. However, buyers and sellers use strain of breeding stock as the main criteria to differentiate products. Hatcheries use different brand names for broiler DOCs and some of them have established goodwill among buyers by providing quality DOCs, which also established differentiated products in practice. The hatchery owners set the price of DOCs independently but consider the reaction of competitors in the market. The price of DOCs varies month to month, as for example during 2010, broiler DOCs price varied from Taka5 18 to Taka 75, and Layer DOCs varied from Taka 12 to Taka 75 (Chowdhury, 2011). There is no bargaining between buyer and seller of DOCs at any point in the supply chain, it is basically a supply driven market. They usually sell DOCs in cash at a fixed price to farm 5 Local currency (1US$=69 Taka) 4 owners and agents but provide a commission to the agents. The hatchery owners sell the DOCs at the hatchery or through their sales center’s directly or through sales agent’s to poultry farmers. Generally DOCs are packed either in paper boxes or bamboo baskets. A few hatcheries use their own or hired pickup to transport DOCs from the hatchery to the sales center’s and/or agent’s store. Generally most of the time poultry farmers do not transport DOCs by specialized vehicles; usually they carry on by passenger buses, rickshaw or vans. Such transportation is hazardous and increases the likelihood of mortality during movement. 2.2.2. Poultry feed One of the major problems of the development of the poultry sub-sector in Bangladesh is related to lack of sufficient and appropriate feeds (Mitchell, 1997). Two types of feeds, manufactured and mixed ingredients feed are used in the poultry sector. The manufactured feeds of different feed mills available in the market are not homogeneous in nature. The manufacturers differentiate poultry feeds on the basis of quality, brand name, sales promotion, and packaging. Marketing chain of feed is also different. Some feed manufacturers distribute feeds through agents, some use wholesalers and retailers; some have their own sales centers. By looking at the competition in the market, the feed millers set the price of feeds independently. Feed millers usually set the prices for wholesalers and aratdars, giving little scope for bargaining except that rates of commission may vary depending on the volume of purchase. Feed millers usually promote their products through advertising and providing quality assurance and incentives such as differential commissions to wholesalers and some millers also provide incentives to farmers. Generally, feed manufacturer do fix the prices for wholesaler. The wholesalers sell feed both in cash and credit to retailers and farmers. In setting sale price, some of the wholesalers charge a fixed margin on the total cost of feed marketed and others add a certain percent of total cost as profit. The price of feed varies from brand to brand. For example, during 2010, broiler feed 5 price per ton varied from Taka 30,000 to Taka 32,000, and layer feed price varied from Taka 24,000 to Taka 27,000 (Chowdhury, 2011). Most of the feed ingredients such as maize, meat bone meal, soybean meal, protein concentrate etc. are imported and therefore sensitive to the movement in world prices. Poultry feeds are mainly imported from Germany, China, Thailand, India and Taiwan. The exact number of feed mills in operation at present is not definitely known but a report stated that there are 35 feed mills with 850 dealers at the private sector who are producing and distributing poultry feed in the country. These feed mills are owned and operated by the private sector, but their distributional system in rural areas is inadequate and their production does not meet quantity demanded. 2.2.3. Veterinary drugs Vaccination and medication of Newcastle, Fowl Pox, Fowl Cholera, Fowl Typhoid, Coccidiosis, Gumboro, are usually done by the poultry farmers. The mortality rate of poultry is high (35-40 percent) due to disease and predators. Although the government gives some necessary vaccine at low cost price to help poultry farmers, but in most of the cases, the farmers are in urgency to buy vaccines at a high price from the open market. However, vaccines are not served equally in all parts of the country, especially in the remote parts of the rural areas. Vaccination failure is very common in Bangladesh due to improper transportation and storage, handling and application. Most poultry farmers use vaccines without knowing maternal antibody status of the flocks they are raising. The marketing chain for drugs is simple and composed of three actors: the pharmaceutical companies, the wholesalers and the retailers. The pharmaceutical companies distribute drugs to wholesalers. The retailers purchase drugs from wholesalers and sell to poultry farmers. So, from the above discussion it is clear that the poultry input sector in Bangladesh is plagued with multifarious problems including high prices of inputs. Production risk is another leading problem in the poultry sector. It mainly occurs in broiler farming due to 6 death or loss of birds. Outbreak of disease also causes considerable economic loss and erodes confidence in poultry farming. For example, Gumboro and New Castle are epidemic diseases, and they cause large quantity of losses. Aside from production oriented problems, one of the main factors that obstruct growth of poultry sector is the lack of efficient marketing system, such as collection, storage, processing and marketing of poultry products. Farmers also face problems related to marketing of their products. However, previous research studies have pointed out and recognized that the production oriented problems faced by commercial poultry farms are: lack of capital, inadequate knowledge of poultry rearing, outbreak of diseases, inadequate availability of inputs, inadequate institutional credit, guaranteed and profitable markets for their output etc. (Karim and Mainuddin, 1983; Ahmed, 1985; Haque, 1985; Islam and Shahidullah, 1989; Ukil and Paul, 1992; Bhuiyan, 1999; Uddin, 1999; Begum, 2005; Begum and Alam, 2005; Begum et al., 2005). 2.3. Poultry output price and marketing channel Poultry outputs particularly broilers are live product. Therefore, if farmers fail to sell broilers at the right time, they face great losses. Thus, the biological nature of broiler is one of the important causes of output price instability. Broilers are sensitive product. They cannot be stored for a long time without proper storage facilities. For this reason, the farmer wants to sell their products immediately. Moreover, market price can fluctuate. Prices observed in time are the results of seasonal patterns of change. Measuring seasonal variation is required to know the short run fluctuations in time series data. Average monthly wholesale price of big size (1 to 1.5 kilogram) poultry in Dhaka market was used to measure seasonal price variation. Data were collected from the Department of Agricultural Marketing (DAM). Data covered the period from January 1992 to December 2003. The ratio-to-moving average method was used in this study to measure seasonal variations. Figure 1 depicts the seasonal indices. As shown in Figure 1, poultry price in March is 106 7 percent of those of the average month, typical October price is 93 percent of those of the Dec Nov Oct Sep Aug July June May Apr Mar Feb 108 106 104 102 100 98 96 94 92 90 88 86 Jan Seasonal Indices average month, and so on. Month Figure 1: Poultry seasonal price fluctuation in Dhaka market during 1992-2002 Poultry marketing channel is a long traditional marketing system. Number of intermediaries is higher for poultry products (Figure 2). Consequently, farmers sometime are forced to sell at lower price because of inadequate market information, transport facilities etc. Moreover, price spread is higher; therefore, sometimes the farmers’ prices are not remunerative. Chand et al., (2009) showed that, in 2009, DOC cost was Taka 38 per unit and production cost per bird was Taka 94, but due to price fluctuation farmers had to sell matured bird between Taka 80 to Taka 100 per kilogram at the farm gate. Farmer Wholesaler Retailer Consumer Institutional buyer Figure 2: Marketing channels of poultry products 8 From the above discussion, it is clear that that the poultry input markets are not competitive and demand supply imbalance is a barrier to smooth functioning of the market implying that the commercial poultry sector is not well organized in Bangladesh. For good sectoral performance, markets should function well which is not present in the case for Bangladesh poultry sector. However, the modern technology adapted in the poultry sector seems appropriate for easy transfer to remote and small rural villages of Bangladesh. But, successful transformation of the modern technology throughout the poultry sector requires institutional support, particularly for the poor and small farmers, to facilitate greater market access which has been changing dramatically in its procurement practices, specification and standard requirements by various stakeholders (e.g., food manufacturers, wholesalers/ exporters and retailers) upto the final consumers. Contract farming system is one such institutional initiative that could play an important role in mediating and bridging these issues/ limitations that are largely out of reach of the small scale poultry farmers. 3. Contract farming system in Bangladesh poultry sector Contract farming offers several potential advantages over independent farming. Contract farming has been proposed as one important avenue for private farms to take over the role previously served by the state in the provision of information, inputs and credit (World Bank, 2001). It is the context of the contract which can make a big difference as there are many actors and factors in the environment which influence the working and outcome of the contract. The way farmers perceive contract farming define their relationship with companies and differ across cultures (Asano-Tamonoi, 1988). In fact, there is so much diversity in the type of farms, farmers, nature of contracts, and socio-economic environment that it is better to focus on the specific situation than the generic institution of contract farming. As the contract farming system in poultry production is relatively a new concept in 9 Bangladesh, there is a need to assess the pioneer company’s profile and also to discuss the contractual agreement between farms and farmers. Contract poultry farming system was started by a big company named Aftab Bohumukhi (Multipurpose) Farms Limited (hereafter ABFL). Besides ABFL, some other nongovernmental organizations like BRAC, PROSHIKA have also came forward to support rural people by providing kind or cash through setting up of contract farming and running of small scale poultry farms. ABFL is one of the leading poultry farms in Bangladesh established in 1991 at Bhagalpur in Kishoregonj district located about 110 km northeast of Dhaka city. ABFL is one of the subsidiary companies of the Islam group that predominantly engaged in the agricultural sector. ABFL first introduced contract growing system of commercial broiler as an experimental extension program for a selected group of 20 farmers who had to enter into an agreement (contract growing) with ABFL on production and marketing of broiler products. The ABFL farm is different from the integrated farms in other countries because it started as an agro-based farm and tends to include small farmers in its activities. ABFL’s activities are associated with poultry, dairy and agro-services. The main objectives of ABFL are to generate farmer’s income and to look after their interest. As a result, ABFL includes all categories of farms according to land sizes (small, medium and large) in their contractual agreement. To develop the poultry farming system as an income generating activity as well as to promote proper scientific and professional support, ABFL took up in 1994 an elaborate contract growing program involving rural people. ABFL has its own feed mill and hatchery. The farm consists of a modern hatchery that produces 60,000 broiler and layer parent birds and supplies 100,000 DOCs per week for the fast growing poultry industry. Also, the farm has commercial facilities to supply eggs and poultry meat to Dhaka city to consumers 10 through conveniently located sales centers. The poultry complex of ABFL is one of the biggest and largest complexes in the country. ABFL’s poultry feed mill was first established primarily to provide balanced feed for the ABFL contract poultry farm. It was later expanded to meet the demand of poultry feed throughout the country. At present ABFL has 3 feed mills with a capacity of 10,000 metric ton/month and it distributes balanced feed to farms throughout the country using its own distribution system. The term ‘contract’ in broiler production may vary from country to country and the nature of the integrator company. The agreements between ABFL and the farmer are very simple indeed. Any farmer located in the company area is eligible to enter into a contractual agreement. The responsibilities of the contract farmer and ABFL in the vertically integrated farming system are shown in Table 1. Table 1: Salient features of contract arrangements of ABFL in Bangladesh I. Name of the Company AFTAB Bahumukhi Farms Limited II. Type of the Company Private Limited Company III. Product/services dealing with a) Commercial broiler: live broiler, dressed broiler b) Parent stock IV. Form of contract arrangement handled Formal input-output (up to 2003) V. Backward linkage activities for contracted product/services a) Package of input/Services i) Day old chicks ii) Feed iii) Veterinary and medical services iv) Cash loan for operational expenses b) Size of the contract farmers (in 2003) i) Commercial broiler: 560 farmers ii) Parent stock: 122 farmers 11 c) Geographical locations covered Only Kishorganj district d) Volume of input/product delivered per i) Commercial broiler: Feed: 100 metric month ton (MT) per month ii) Parent stock: Feed 1000 MT per month e) Value of input/service delivered per i) Commercial broiler: Taka 50,000,000 month ii) Parent stock: Taka 175,000.000 VI. Forward linkage activities for contracted product/output/services a) Output/services Own sales center for dressed broiler, dealer for feed and chicken b) Criteria for selecting contract farmers: Anyone can enter c) Approximate market share of the 10 percent for chicks company: VII. Provision for enforcement of contract VIII. System of ensuring product quality Mostly informal and social Inspection, supervision, laboratory test Source: Begum (2008) According to the agreement, ABFL extends credit facilities to the farmer, provides DOCs, feeds, veterinary supplies by kind on credit, and implements the final marketing of the output. The feed and other inputs supplied by the contractor represent over 90 percent of the total cost of the production which means farmers only pay 10 percent of the annual average cost. According to the agreement, a farmer builds a covered shed at his/her own cost ensuring congenial and healthy environment for proper growth of the birds under the direct supervision of the ABFL experts. The average duration of the grow-out cycle is roughly 5 to 7 weeks for an averaged sized (1.5 kilogram) broiler. ABFL buys the matured broiler from the contract farmer by paying a fixed price per kilogram of live broiler and then market these broilers through ABFL sales centers in Dhaka. All the credit liability of the contract farmer is adjusted against the price of their products. Thus, in this farming system, farmers can get financial support from the integrator without any interest rate to run the 12 business smoothly. However, the number of birds per batch to be reared and managerial decisions are taken by the farmers. The vertical stages of ABFL broiler contract farming system are shown in Figure 3. However, after the bird flu rumor in 2003 following incidences in Asia, ABFL has changed the contractual agreement from input supply on credit to cash but till now in ‘parent stock contract system’, ABFL follows credit system. ABFL Hatching Egg Farm Feed Eggs ABFL’s Feed Mill ABFL’s Hatchery Feed Broiler Chicks Contract farm Live Broilers ABFL’s Processing Plant Dressed Broilers ABFL’s Broiler Sales Center Figure 3: The vertical stages of ABFL broiler contract farming There are two types of risks in poultry production. One is production risk and another is price risk. Numerous studies of contract farming have emphasized risk reduction as a principal incentive for producers to enter into contracts (Roy, 1972; Covey and Stennis, 1985; Dornbush and Boehlje, 1988; Herbert and Jacobs, 1988; Lawrence and Kaylen, 1990; 13 Johnson and Foster, 1994; Knoeber and Thurman, 1995). There have been varying degrees of success over the years, across countries and across several types of insurance programs (Hazell et al., 1986; Hueth and Furtan, 1994; Mishra, 1996). ABFL is the only farm in Bangladesh that has introduced an internal insurance scheme to cover the risk of loss of the contract farmers in case of immature death of chicks by diseases and other cogent reasons. In contractual system, ABFL’s growers’ payment depends upon production outcomes and not upon price outcomes, thus farmers can avoid price risk. ABFL’s contract growers are freed from production risk such as outbreak of diseases or epidemics since the integrator provides technical assistance and insurance. According to ABFL’s insurance scheme, ABFL operates a contributory security fund. Farmers contribute Taka 1.50 per chick to the fund at the time of purchase. For chick mortality of within a range, a portion of the initial contribution or risk premium is refunded. For example, if chick mortality is less than 3 percent, 4-6 percent, 7-10 percent and 11-15 percent then 80, 40, 20, 10 percent of contribution respectively is refunded to the farmer. If the mortality rate is above 15 percent, the farmer can claim full insurance compensation. In this case, for birds up to 20 days of age Taka 20 per bird is paid after deducting 15 percent from the total number of lost birds. For birds beyond 20 days of age, Taka 30 is paid per bird after calculating the benefits from bird upto 20 days age (Table 2). This means that lower mortality rates lead to higher rates of compensation, but over 15 percent mortality leads to claim of full insured value compensation. Because of this measure, farmers feel secured and are encouraged to take up this venture. Table 2: Poultry insurance scheme of ABFL Premium Taka. 1.50 per bird Claim Mortality rate Refund 0-3% 80% premium 4-6% 40% premium 7-10% 20% premium 14 11-15% 10% premium Above 15% Taka 20/bird Within 20 days deducting 15% After 20 days deducting 15% Taka 30 /bird Source: Begum, 2008 Integrator also faces same production and price risk, moreover the company has to anxiety whether Farmers sell broiler outside the contract or divert inputs supplied on credit to other purposes. Sometimes poor management capacity of illiterate farmers may reduce yield. 4. Effectiveness of contracting system in promoting smallholders’ access to modern market channel In the era of market liberalization, globalization and expanding agribusiness, there is a danger that small farmers could face difficulty in participating successfully in the market. Evidences say that in many countries such farmers could become marginalized as larger farms get more emphasis for a profitable operation. So, for Bangladesh, like in many developing countries across the world, it is necessary to find out whether benefits of contract farming system reaches small farmers or not. Thus, to ensure efficiency and equity, it is necessary to develop institutional mechanisms which facilitate small farmers’ access to inputs, credit, and technical assistance and reduce uncertainty in marketing of output. This will in turn raise their productivity, profitability and income. Contract farming is an appropriate institutional form that tackles many of these constraints in an integrated manner. In developing country, small poultry farms always play a central role in sectoral development. But the main constraints of small farms are access to resources and markets. First, small farmers often lack necessary production and marketing information. Second, small farmers may lack sufficient savings and the availability of external credit is limited because of bureaucratic complexities. Third, small farmers operate near subsistence level and are at more risk averse than the large farmers. Finally, public intervention (such as 15 public extension service and policies) to promote commercial poultry production have had higher impact on large farmers than on small farmers. Thus, it is clear from these constraints that, in the interest of both efficiency and equity perspective, contract farming could be a possible institutional mechanism which could facilitate small poultry farmer’s access to credit, technical assistance and inputs and also reduce the uncertainty in marketing of output. Therefore, if the contract farming system can be developed and policy biases towards large scale commercialization reduced, then small farmers will be able to raise their income by taking poultry as a main or subsidiary occupation. Contract farming system involves small farmers for some reasons. One of the main reasons is that in developing countries the integrated farm faces difficulties in finding enough small farmers to produce the amount they needed. Another reason is that, the farmers fear that large farmers might collectively bargain to bid-up prices paid to them for their product. Moreover, large farmers sometimes try to break the contract rule. As scale economies are associated with specialized technology adoption, a vertically integrated farm tries to involve few large farms into their production and distribution system. Contract farming has also been a component of the most successful income generating projects for small farmers in developing countries. Some studies, especially in Latin America, found that contract farming system could run smoothly by including small farmers. For example, there has been widespread use of contracts involving small farmers in Latin American countries. In Guatemala, smallholders are contracted to produce broccoli and snow peas for export to the United States. In Ecuador, the multi-national Frito Lay contracts small farmers to produce a particular variety of potato for processing into chips for the domestic market. There are some more case studies such as frozen vegetables in Mexico (Runsten and Key, 1996; Key and Runsten, 1999), confectionery peanuts in Senegal (Warning and Key, 2002), and various agricultural commodities in Indonesia (Patrick, 2004), that follow the examples of contract farming and have successfully incorporated small farmers in their operation. 16 On the other hand, some evidences from different countries suggest that the vast majority of contract farming schemes exclude small farmers (Singh, 2000). Generally, capital intensive large farms make small farmers’ entry to the contracting system difficult because of high transaction cost and economies of scale. The total number of poultry farms has decreased in developed countries like Japan, USA and Canada after the introduction of the vertically integrated contract faming system. In the mid-1990s, eighty percent of the poultry production in Thailand came from only ten large companies (World Bank, 2001). Recently, a new FAO guide argues that well managed contract farming has proven to be effective in linking the small commercial farm sector to sources of extensive advice, mechanization, inputs and credit, and to guaranteed and profitable markets for products. When efficiently organized and managed, contract farming reduces risk and uncertainty for both parties. The approach would appear to have considerable potential in countries where small scale agriculture continues to be widespread. In many cases small farmers can no longer be competitive without access to services provided by contract farming companies (FAO, 2001). In the case of Bangladesh, ABFL is different from integrated farms operating in other countries because ABFL has started as an agro-based farm and it include all categories of farms according to land size in its poultry contract farming. There was perhaps no special consideration for small farms but they were included as long as other requirements for engaging in poultry were met. Unlike vertically integrated farms in developed countries where big trading companies usually prefer contracts with large-scale farms and farmers to minimize transaction costs, ABFL has tried to be inclusive. One of the objectives of ABFL was to increase income and welfare of small farmers in the areas around the farm headquarters. This motivation may partly lie in the fact that the owner of the Islam Group, of which ABFL is a component, comes from the locality, so contribution to the improved 17 welfare of his local people through his business ventures might serve both a business as well as a welfare objective. Small farmers hold a strategic position in the economy of Bangladesh. They have limited working capital but they can provide abundant disguised family labor in the farming system. Although ABFL started with small farmers in its operation, it realized that it is in their interest to contract with large growers as well. They did this for two reasons. First, the firm encountered difficulties finding enough farmers to produce the amount of poultry they needed. Second, the government of Bangladesh restricted large-scale poultry farms by licensing to protect the small farmer. Begum (2008) found that ABFL’s contract farming system is based on the economic development perspective of small farmers. Out of 560 farms, about 93 percent were classified under small farm (having less than 2.5 acres of land), category. By considering poultry flock size, out of 560 farms, 201 farms reared up to 1200 birds/batch, 281 farms reared 1201 to 2000 birds/batch and only 78 farms reared more than 2001 birds/batch, thus it is overwhelmingly characterized as the operation of small farms. However, the study also mentioned that if the official classification of large farms (i.e., more than 5000 birds/batch) is considered, than only 3 farms out of the total 560 contract farms can be designated as large farms in the study area. 4.1. Smallholder’s benefit from contract farming system The contract farming system provides tremendous benefit to the integrator farm and the contract farmers. The integrator farm provides guarantee of regular supply of raw materials while the small farmer have access to a ready market for their products. Benefits from contract participation include improved market access, access to credit and technology, better management of risk, improved family employment and indirectly, development of a successful commercial farming system. 4.1.1. Contract farming and market access for smallholders 18 Generally, small farmers in Bangladesh are unable to take advantage of market opportunities and often have trouble accessing credit, obtaining information on market opportunities or new technologies, purchasing inputs and accessing output assured market with fair price. When markets are accessible, farmers may be subjected to price fluctuations or inequitable prices. For farmers, technical constraint in transforming from scavenging poultry farming to commercial poultry production is less obstructing than market constraint. Therefore, one of the principal motivations for smallholders to enter into contract farming is having an assured market with favorable price. Comparing the marketing system under conventional and contracting system, marketing channel of conventional system is longer than the contracting system. In contracting system, farmers sell poultry product to integrator directly. Consequently this system may serve to lower transaction cost associated with searching, collecting market information, negotiation, etc. can provide necessary backward and forward linkage, provide all the marketing facilities, increase the producers` price thus reducing price spread, consequently integrate small producers into the market. 4.1.2. Contract farming, productivity and profitability differences Contract farming generally implies that small farmers get benefit from contracts in terms of enhanced net return. Begum (2008) showed the difference in poultry production output between contract and non-contract farmers is statistically significant. Poultry production output for the contract farmers (11783 kilogram) is significantly higher than that of noncontract farmers (6763 kilogram). Productivity of labour is also significantly higher for contract farmers than non-contract farmers. Profitability of poultry farming was measured in terms of gross margin and net profit. Begum (2008) estimated per bird net return gain from contract and non-contract poultry farming system. The gross margin and net return (18.2 Taka and 17.2 Taka, respectively) of contract farms are significantly much higher than 19 the independent farms (Taka 12.9 and 10.0, respectively.). However, both contract and noncontract farmers operate profitably. 4.1.3. Contract farming and efficiency differences Contracting system is significantly related to farming efficiency. Begum et al., (2011) determined the level of technical, allocative and economic efficiency of small farmers of commercial and independent poultry farmers and also identify the factors causing efficiency by examining the relationship between efficiency level and possible socio economic factors. The study found that technical efficiency, allocative efficiency and economic efficiency of the non-contract farms are 91, 89, and 81 percent, respectively, which are below than the contract farms estimated at 96, 98 and 94 percent, respectively. Therefore, contract farms are more efficient than non-contract farms. The study also found contract farming is the most statistically significant factor associated with efficiency. This result is expected because under contractual agreement, in order to obtain sufficient supplies of the right quality of poultry meat at the right time, ABFL’s provides technical know-how assistance through ABFL’s recruited supervisor, production inputs, and production credit, which in turn improves farm efficiency. 4.1.4. Contract farming and income differences Begum (2008) compared contract and non-contract poultry farm income with non-poultry farm’s average income and showed average gross income of non-poultry farm was Taka 107121 per year whereas non-contract and contract poultry farm earned Taka 76653 and 127833 per year respectively only from poultry enterprise and poultry farm satisfies 55 percent of total income of contract farmers. Thus, the study concluded that if small farms plan to enter in contract farming system, they can obtain substantial income gains. 4.1.5. Contract farming and risk reduction 20 Increased income in contract farming is generally accompanied with lowering price risk for farmers. Risk and uncertainty are quite common in the poultry business. Small farmers have little access to information and face the risk of dropping substantial income if prices fluctuate downward. In contract farming system, a predetermined price for the poultry product is established during contract negotiations. As a rule, firms typically purchase the final product that falls within specified quality and quantity in accordance with the contract, and farmers are not subjected to incur losses in sales due to price fluctuations. In this respect farmers can lower their price risk. 4.1.6. Contract farming and production capacity utilization Contract farming can utilize production capacity more efficiently than non-contract farm. Begum (2007) found that, due to a lack of capital, non-contract farm sometimes fail to rear same amount of birds in every batch, whereas contract farms do not face such a problem. The author found that if non-contract farmers utilize the average maximum bird rearing capacity per batch, then average number of birds to be reared per year would be 8239 but actually they reared only 4251 birds (i.e., 51.5 percent of full capacity). In case of contract farms, the relevant figures are 10,466 birds whereas actual reared was 9,179 birds (i.e., 87.7 percent of full capacity). So, it indicates that contract farms can utilize their capacity more efficiently as compared with the independent farms. From the foregoing discussion it is observed that contract farming worked well before bird flu scare in the context of Bangladesh small farmers. Begum (2008) estimated per bird profit gain from contract and independent broiler farming system after changing contractual agreement because of bird flu. Results reveal that even after bird flu, per bird net return of contract farm is 1.4 times higher than the net return of independent farm. 21 No. of contract farm 2011 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 Figure 4: Number of contract farms of ABFL from 1994 to 2011 However, although ABFL started with 20 farmers in 1994, and the number reached to 650 in 2003, but after bird flu incidence, the number of ABFL’s contract farms came down to 200 in 2004 but subsequently increased to 315 in 2005 and 375 in 2011 (Figure 4). The figure indicates that the small farmers started taking interest to enter into contract poultry farming system by knowing its profitability although ABFL has changed its contractual agreement. So, it could be concluded that contract farming plays a significant role in small farmer development, because, existing rural credit institution such as agricultural bank in Bangladesh do not have many of the features which ABFL’s contract farming system have, such as collateral-free input loans, assistance with access to input and product markets, opportunity to get technical know-how and supervised credit. Thus, contract farming is undoubtedly an authentic way to produce quality chickens. This has been substantiated by research findings all over the world. 4.2. Integrator’s benefit from contract farming system Vertically integrated contract farming system will sustain in long run if both parties (integrator and contract farmers) benefit from the contract system in a sustainable way. Begum (2008) showed poultry farming is also profitable from integrator’s point of view. In 22 the study period ABFL bought the birds from the contract farmers at Taka 52.5 per kilogram and sold it to ABFL’s sales centre at Taka 85.05 per kilogram, so, gross revenue was Taka. 32.5 per kilogram. However, ABFL’s cost elements include credit, input supply, staff hires etc. which could be substantial but cannot be estimated with accuracy. Therefore, Taka 32.5 per kilogram was taken as the ABFL’s per bird gross return, not net return or profit. 5. External factors associated with contracting system Although, there are good reasons for expanding contract farming, but the evidence of it’s benefits to smallholders is mixed. Contract farming in developing country has experienced a mixed fortune, yielding some successes and some failures. Positive views basically maintain that contracts are an adequate mechanism to incorporate small farmers into dynamic modern markets by substituting failing markets for credit, insurance, information, factors of production, outlet produce and diminishing transaction costs and transfer of technology, (Glover, 1984; Grosh, 1994; Key and Runsten, 1999). Conversely, other authors warn about some undesired welfare effects for smallholders (Willson, 1986; Rickson and Burch, 1996). However, like many developing countries Bangladesh lack the laws and legal framework to support contractual agreements. Agreements at times may not be easily enforceable or even legally binding. Since prices specified in contract are based on expectations about future market behavior, substantial variations in the realization of the expectation can lead farms to engage in contractual holdup. For example, during the bird flu incidence, Bangladesh poultry sector got affected and as a result price varied significantly. Since an effective enforcement mechanism is absent, poultry farmers could do nothing to avoid the negative impact of contractual holdup. Some issues from integrator’s point of view is that the smallholder farmers may exercise opportunistic behavior by misuse or deviation of inputs supplied by the farm, fluctuating demand for poultry products, poultry diseases specially 23 avian flu, extra contractual sales by farmers, miss selection of appropriate farmers, miss-use of feeds etc. Farmer may also consume part of the production or even sell to third party as FCRs (feed conversion ratios) are not followed presently. The external factor outside of the control of the smallholders point of view includes delay payment from integrator, abnormally price hike of poultry feed and medicines etc. However, given the external factors which could undermine the system, the ABFL is a successful story of contract farming. 6. Conclusions and policy implications The future outlook is positive for the Bangladesh poultry industry because the demand for poultry products is expected to increase given its current low level of per capita consumption and anticipated growth in population and household incomes. To compete, the Bangladesh poultry industry must pursue production and marketing efficiency and the government must provide an environment that is conductive to productivity improvement. The chapter reveals that contract poultry farming system in Bangladesh is Dominated by smallholders. Potentially a way of overcoming market imperfections, minimizing transaction costs and gaining market access for smallholders. Benefits from this system include access to credit and technology, better management of risk and enhanced family employment opportunity. Increases productivity, profitability and efficiency, a win-win situation. Thus, contract farming undoubtedly is the most authentic way to produce quality poultry products and this system has to be spread all over Bangladesh to meet the domestic meat requirement and also for generating export market potential. Government policies are required to prevent malpractices by the companies and to restrict exploitation tendencies. It can be suggested that to increase poultry production and develop the poultry industry, the 24 government as well as other private integrators can take initiatives to establish an effective and well organized contract farming system in Bangladesh. 25 References Ahmed, R., (1985). Prospect and Problems of Broiler Production in Bangladesh. Proceeding of the First National Conference of Bangladesh Animal Husbandry Association, February 23-24, 1985, BRAC, Dhaka, Bangladesh. Asano-Tamanoi, M., (1988). Farmers, industries and the state: the culture of contract farming in Spain and Japan. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 30(3): 432– 452. BBS (2001). Statistical Yearbooks. Bangladesh. Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics, Statistics Division, Ministry of Planning, Government of the People’s Republic of Bangladesh, Dhaka, Bangladesh. BBS (2005). Statistical Yearbooks. Bangladesh. Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics, Statistics Division, Ministry of Planning, Government of the People’s Republic of Bangladesh, Dhaka, Bangladesh. Begum, I. A., (2005). An assessment of vertically integrated contract poultry farming: a case study in Bangladesh. International Journal of Poultry Science, 4(3): 167-176. Begum, I. A., (2007). Potentiality of vertically integrated poultry contract farming system in Bangladesh: profitability and productivity analysis. Bangladesh Journal of Agricultural Economics. Vol. XXIX No. 1 & 2: 107-117 Begum, I. A., (2008). Prospects and Potentialities of Vertically Integrated Contract Farming in Bangladesh, Unpublished PhD thesis, Department of Agricultural Development Economics, Hokkaido University, Japan. Begum, I. A., Alam, M. J., Buysse, J., Frija, A., and Van Huylenbroeck, G., (2012). Contract farmer and poultry farm efficiency in Bangladesh: a data envelopment analysis. Applied Economics, 44: 3737-3747. Begum, I. A., and Alam, M. J., (2005). Contract farming and small farmer: A case study of the Bangladesh poultry sector. Journal of Bangladesh Studies, 7 (2), Penn State Erie, USA. Begum, I.A., Osanami, F., and Kondo, T., (2005). Performance of vertically integrated contract poultry farming and independent poultry farms in Bangladesh: A comparative study, The Review of Agricultural Economics, 61: 101-117. 26 Bhuiyan, A. U., (1999). An Economic Analysis of Small Scale Poultry Farming of Kotwali Thana in Mymensingh District. Master thesis, Department of Agricultural Economics, Bangladesh Agricultural University, Mymensingh, Bangladesh. Chand, V., Chowdhury, S. D., Saha, M. K., and Hossain, M. K., (2009). IFC-SEDF sector studies and baseline surveys in poultry in Bangladesh. Final report, Associates for Development Services Limited, Dhaka, Bangladesh. Chowdhury, S. D., (2011). Commercial poultry farming in Bangladesh: the rolling tears of farmers and its consequences, Seventh International Poultry Show and Seminar, WPSA-BB, 25-27 March, 2011, Dhaka, Bangladesh. Covey, T., and Stennis, E., (1985). Analysis of the rough rice futures contract. Agricultural Economics Research Report No. 156, Mississippi State University, USA. Dornbush, C., and Boehlje (1988). An Economic Analysis of Contracting Arrangements Used by the Minnesota Turkey Industry. Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics Staff Paper, University of Minnesota, Minnenpolis, USA. FAO (2001). Contract farming: partnerships for growth, by Eaton, C. and Shepherd, A. FAO, vol.145, Rome, Italy, http://www.fao.org/icatalog/inter-e.htm Glover, D., (1984). Contract farming and smallholder out grower schemes in less-developed countries. World Development, 12 (11/12): 1143-1157. Grosh, B., (1994). Contract farming in Africa: an application of the new institutional economics. Journal of African Economies, 3 (2): 231-261. Haque, Q. M. E., (1985). Commercial Poultry Farming in Bangladesh. Proceeding of the First National Conference of Bangladesh Animal Husbandry Association, February 2324, 1985, BRAC, Dhaka, Bangladesh. Hazell, P., Pomerada, C., Valdes, A. (1986). Crop Insurance for Agricultural Development: Issues and Experience. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. Herbert, T. and Jacobs, J., (1988). Contracting, Coordination and Instability in the Navy Bean Industry. Agricultural Economics Report No. 504, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MX. Hueth, D., Furtan, W. (1994). Economics of Agricultural Crop Insurance: Theory and Evidence. Kluwer Academic publishers, Boston. 27 Huque, Q. M. E., and Stem, C., (1993). Current status of poultry production and marketing systems in Bangladesh. Bangladesh Agricultural Research Council/ USAID/Checchi & Company Consulting, Inc. Islam, M. M., and Shahidullah, M., (1989). Poultry knowledge of the farmers of a union in Mymensingh district in Bangladesh. Journal of Training and Development, 2(1): 1218. Johnson, C. and Foster, K., (1994). Risk preferences and contracting in the US hog industry. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, 26 (2): 393-405. Karim, A. M. A., and Mainuddin, G., (1983). Evaluation on the Field Activities of Backyard Poultry Raiser in Bangladesh, UNICEF, Dhaka, Bangladesh. Key, N., and Runsten, D., (1999). Contract farming, smallholders, and rural development in Latin America: The organization of agro-processing firms and the scale of out grower production. World Development, 27 (2): 381-401. Knoeber, C.R., and Thurman, W. N., (1995). Don’t count your chickens. Risk and risk shifting in the broiler industry. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 77: 486496. Lawrence, J. and Kaylen, M. (1990). Risk Management for Livestock Producers- Hedging and Contract Production. Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics, Staff Paper, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, USA. Mishra, P., (1996). Agricultural Risk, Insurance and Income: A Study of the Impact and Design of India’s Comprehensive Crop Insurance Scheme. Avebury Publishing, Aldershot, UK. Mitchell, D., (1997). The Livestock and Poultry Sub-Sector in Bangladesh, Mission Report, World Bank. Patrick, I., (2004). Contract Farming in Indonesia: Smallholders and Agribusiness Working Together, ACIAR (Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research) Technical Reports No. 54, University of New England, Australia. Prabakaran, R., (2003). Good Practices in Planning and Management of Integrated Commercial Poultry Production in South Asia, FAO Animal production and health paper, 159, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome, Italy. Raihan, S., and Mahmud, N., (2008). Trade and Poverty Linkages: A Case Study of the Poultry Industry in Bangladesh, Cuts Cite, Working Paper No. 6. 28 Rickson, R. E., and Burch, D., (1996). Contract farming in organizational agriculture: the effects upon farmers and the environment. In: Burch, D., Rickson, R.E. and Lawrence, G. (eds.), Globalization and agri-food restructuring– perspectives for the Australian region. Averbury, Brookfield, USA. Roy, P., (1972). Contract Farming and Economic Integration. Interstate Printers and Publishers, Danville, IL. Runsten, D., and Key, N., (1996). Contract farming in developing countries: Theoretical issues and analysis of some Mexican cases, Report LC/L.989, Unite Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, Santiago, Chile. Saleque, M. A., (1999). Scaling Up: Critical Factors in leadership, Management, Human Resource Development and Institution Building in Going from Pilot Project to Large Scale Implementation: the BRAC Poultry Model in Bangladesh. Singh, S., (2000). Theory and practice of contract farming- A review. Journal of Social and Economic Development, 3 (2): 228-46. The Poultry Site news desk: http://www.thepoultrysite.com/poultrynews/11617/ifc- supports-women-farmers-and-poultryentrepreneurs-in-bangladesh. The Poultry Site.com, April 24, 2007. Uddin, H., (1999). A Comparative Economic Analysis of Broiler and Layer Production in Some Selected Areas of Sadar Thana in Mymensingh District. A Master thesis, Department of Agricultural Economics, Bangladesh Agricultural University, Mymensingh, Bangladesh. Ukil, M. A. and Paul, D. C., (1992). Problems and Prospects of Broiler Industry. Conference of Bangladesh Animal Husbandry Association, Dhaka, Bangladesh. Warning, M. and Key, N., (2002). The social performance and distributional consequences of contract farming: An equilibrium analysis of the Arachide de Bouche program in Senegal. World Development, 30(2): 255 - 263. Wilson, J., (1986). The political economy of contract farming. Review of Radical Political Economics, 18(4): 47-70. World Bank (2001). Livestock Development, the Environment, Poverty and Global Food Security: A Strategy Paper for the World Bank. Washington DC. 29