THE RIGHT SPEED AND ITS VALUE Gonçalo Pacheco-de-Almeida HEC Paris, 1, rue de la Libération,78351 Jouy en Josas Cedex, France, pachecodealmeida@hec.fr Ashton Hawk Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University, 2100 Neil Avenue, Columbus, Ohio 43210, hawk@fisher.osu.edu Bernard Yeung NUS Business School, MRB Building, Biz 1, Level 6, 1 Business Link, Singapore 117592, byeung@nus.edu.sg Key words: time-based competition; speed capabilities; strategy dynamics; firm value; correlated random parameters; firm-specific coefficients 2 ABSTRACT Slow execution of investment projects often means substantial revenue losses while accelerating execution can be costly. Based on this investment speed tradeoff we develop an empirical proxy for a firm’s intrinsic speed capability. Using data on time-to-build of oil and gas facilities worldwide between 1996 and 2005 and random parameter regressions, we show that intrinsic investment speed is positively related to firm value, as measured by Tobin’s q; it is amplified by good corporate governance but often mitigated by the level of firms’ debt. We also obtain firmspecific coefficient estimates, which approximate the marginal market value of each firm’s speed capabilities. The evidence together suggests that firms possessing intrinsic speed capabilities substantially outperform slower competitors, but this performance advantage varies widely across firms. 3 INTRODUCTION Empirical evidence shows that over the last century rival imitation arrives faster (Gort and Klepper 1982, Agarwal and Gort 2001) and superior economic performance dissipates more rapidly (Ghemawat 1991, Waring 1996, Wiggins and Ruefli 2002, 2005). Generally, the race to take on new market opportunities has intensified (e.g., Jovanovic and MacDonald 1994). Thus, firms that execute investment projects faster gain more revenues (Eisenhardt 1989, Stalk and Hout 1990, D'Aveni 1994, Teece et al. 1997, Smith and Reinertsen 1998). Yet, accelerating investments generally results in higher investment costs (Scherer 1967, Mansfield 1971, Dierickx and Cool 1989, Graves 1989). Our contention is that execution speed of an investment project reflects a firm’s intrinsic capability, which is the ability to complete an investment project faster than others given the same cost. Intrinsic speed capabilities should be value enhancing. However, empirically observed speed is affected by not just a firm’s intrinsic speed capabilities, but also many other factors such as the nature of investment projects, local market conditions, or possible executive agency behavior. In addition, firms are likely to differ in their ability to deploy resources fast, implying the need to accommodate firm level heterogeneity. In this paper, using a simple firm level model to facilitate the empirics, we first show that investment completion speed is dependent on systematic factors such as technical complexity, size of a project, expected revenue flows when completed, as well as firm specific factors such as a firm’s intrinsic speed capability and possible sub-optimal behavior. We then derive an empirical proxy for firm speed based on the firm specific determinants of time-to-build. Finally, we examine the relation between speed and firm value, as captured by Tobin’s q, accommodating heterogeneity arising from the main influencing factors and as well as other firm 4 specific conditions. In these steps, we are able to show that speed is an intangible asset that stems from a firm’s intrinsic capabilities. We conduct our empirical investigation using time-to-build of oil and gas facilities worldwide from 1996 to 2005. This setting is particularly appealing because the speed of investment in new plants has a significant effect on firm performance – the loss of a single day’s revenue to plant construction delays can cost a company hundreds of thousands of dollars. Also, data on project execution speed is regularly published by the oil and gas industry trade press. There is substantial heterogeneity in firm speed estimates during the period of analysis. Using random parameter regressions to allow unobserved firm heterogeneity to moderate the effect of the independent variables on Tobin’s q while controlling for suboptimal project acceleration, we find that completing investment projects faster than industry average substantially increases firms’ market value. Additionally, good corporate governance, which likely limit the extent of suboptimal project acceleration, amplifies the effect of speed on firm performance. The returns from speed, however, are reduced for firms that have more debts and face higher discount rates. We also use the random parameters model to estimate firm-specific coefficients that approximate the marginal market value of each individual firm’s speed capabilities. The evidence together suggests that firms possessing intrinsic speed capabilities substantially outperform slower competitors, but this performance advantage varies widely across firms. The paper proceeds as follows. The next section reviews the extant literature and introduces the fundamental tradeoff that firms face when deciding on project investment speed. Next, we integrate this speed tradeoff in a reduced-form model of project development time to create an empirical proxy for firm speed and derive its effect on performance. We proceed to 5 describe our sample, variables, and estimation methodology before testing our model in the context of the worldwide oil and gas industry. Finally, we check the robustness and consider the implication of our results, and we close with a discussion of suggested avenues for further investigation. PRIOR LITERATURE: THE INVESTMENT SPEED TRADEOFF The strategy literature has extensively emphasized the importance of speed for firm competitive advantage. We now review the benefits and costs of speed as described in this literature. The Benefits of Speed Fundamentally, speed enables a firm to realize the revenue streams from an investment project early, while prolonging project development time incurs potentially severe opportunity costs. There are many empirical examples that support this assertion. For example, postponing the launch of a $10,000 car costs the automotive industry a daily expected $1 million loss in net revenues (Clark 1989); delaying the introduction of the HP 930 computer cost the PC industry approximately $1.1 million per day in revenue loss (Waldman 1986). Hendricks and Singhal (1997) show that on average delayed announcements in new product introduction decrease firm market value by 5.25% (or $-119.3 million in 1991 dollars) on average.1 Firm speed in the execution of investment projects matters in many strategic contexts, such as entering new markets, catching up with industry leaders, and competing in a dynamically changing environment. These ideas have been discussed at length in the dynamic capabilities (Teece et al. 1997, Helfat et al. 2007, Teece 2007) and time-based competition literatures (Stalk 1 Delay announcements may also signal unanticipated technical problems with projects, which affect market value independently of the magnitude of revenue loss during the delay. 6 1988, Stalk and Hout 1990).2 Most recently, Hawk, Pacheco-de-Almeida and Yeung (2012) show that firms that can complete investment projects fast face less pre-emption risks in waiting for demand or technical uncertainty to subside before investing and thus their investments generate greater value. The Costs of Speed Balancing the benefits of speed are the costs of hastening investment execution. Important investment projects require the commitment and deployment of valuable and rare firm-specific resources to product markets (Barney 1991, Ghemawat 1991). These firm-specific resources cannot be instantaneously purchased on strategic-factor markets, but must be internally accumulated by firms over time (Barney 1986, Dierickx and Cool 1989). Internal resource accumulation is generally subject to time compression diseconomies: reducing project development time often raises costs at an increasingly rate (Scherer 1967, Boehm 1981, Scherer 1984, Dierickx and Cool 1989). Early estimates of this time-cost tradeoff indicate that, on average, a 1% acceleration in project development time inflates investment costs by 1.75% (Mansfield 1971).3 Several possible explanations exist for time compression diseconomies. Speeding up a project usually involves crash investments, with the deployment of more resources to the project at each point in time. The law of diminishing returns (where one input, viz. time, is held constant) typically limits overall productivity and drives up investment costs. Also, investment acceleration often requires parallel processing of previously sequential development steps, which 2 See also the literature on time-pacing (Brown and Eisenhardt 1998, Eisenhardt and Brown 1998), red queen competition (Barnett and Hansen 1996, Barnett and Pontikes 2008), system dynamics (e.g., (Lenox et al. 2007), and innovation and technology timing (Mitchell 1991, Salomon and Martin 2008, Katila and Chen 2008). 3 In addition to the time-cost tradeoff, accelerating investments may also lower the final quality of a project, particularly in the context of new product development (Cohen et al. 1996). However, the effect of speed on project quality matters less in the empirical setting of our paper, where building oil and gas facilities must meet rigorous technical performance standards at the end of the construction process and before market operations start. 7 reduces internal information flow across stages of the development process and increases mistakes, rework, and costs. Note, however, that these costs are dependent on firms’ intrinsic capabilities: firms that are better at internal communication and coordination can accelerate project completion at a lower cost. The operations research literature has extensively examined this time-cost tradeoff (e.g., Graves 1989). This literature review suggests that firms face an important strategic decision with each investment: they need to decide on the optimal speed of completion of the investment project that balances the abovementioned benefits and costs of speed. We expect this optimal speed to be firm specific and increasing in firms’ intrinsic speed capabilities, ceteris paribus. AN APPLIED REDUCED-FORM MODEL OF INVESTMENT SPEED To empirically explore the performance implications of firm speed, we proceed in two steps. First, we derive an empirical model of the determinants of time-to-build of new oil and gas facility construction projects. By controlling for the nature of each project, local market conditions, and other industry- and project-specific characteristics, we are able to isolate the part of investment speed that is due to firm-specific factors. We use this information to build a proxy for firms’ intrinsic investment speed. Our second step is to use a random parameters model to regress firm value on firms’ intrinsic speed. The random parameter model allows us to estimate the effect of speed on firm performance incorporating sub-optimality and firm level heterogeneity in the relationship between intrinsic speed and firm value. These two steps of our analysis are described in the two subsections below. The Determinants of Project Completion Time We study the determinants of investment time by estimating the following empirical model: 8 ln πΜπ,π’,π‘ = π½0π + π½1 ln πΎπ,π’,π‘ + π½2 ln πΈπ,π’,π‘ + π½3 ln βΜ π,π’ + ππ,π’,π‘ (1) We describe the derivation of the model in Appendix I.4 Intuitively, regression (1) uses a number of systematic factors that are known to impact new plant construction in the oil and gas industry to estimate average project completion time. We expect average project time to vary by industry, accelerate when the economy grows, and take longer for larger and more complex projects. Regression (1) is structured accordingly, as follows. πΜf,i,t is a discounted transformation of the time-to-build of a new production facility f in industry i at time t, where each production facility f represents the ππ‘β (π ≥ 1) investment of firm π in industry π’, identified by vector π = (π, π).5 Every industry π’ is defined by a different project type π (refineries, petrochemical plants, and gas-to-liquids plants) and geographical market π, π’ = (π, π). Intercept π½0i is a vector of industry (and year) dummies and accounts for the expected variation in average project time-to-build across geographies, project type, and over time. Coefficients π½1 , π½2 ≥ 0 represent the elasticity of development time with respect to the stock of intangible and physical resources needed to build a new oil and gas plant, respectively. Intangible resources are typically accumulated during the first two phases – planning and engineering – of a new oil and gas plant development project. When planning and engineering a new plant, oil and gas companies primarily accumulate technological and managerial knowledge πΎπ,π’,π‘ > 0 that depends on the technical complexity of the project (e.g., the feedstock processes, 4 This regression extends the continuous-time model of optimal project speed with time compression diseconomies in Pacheco-de-Almeida and Zemsky (2007). For simplicity and tractability, we downplay the role of strategic interactions among firms (e.g., preemption, pricing, or innovation games) in our theoretical analysis. However, we empirically control for these effects in our robustness checks. 5 Μ π,π’,π‘ = (1 − π−πππ,π’,π‘ )⁄π, where ππ,π’,π‘ is the measure of time-to-build of a The functional form of the discounting is π plant development project in months. This positive monotonic transformation compresses the distribution of development time-to-build from the infinite interval (0, ∞) to the finite interval (0,1/π). See Appendix I for further details on the derivation. 9 mechanical and piping engineering specifications, and electrical design to be used in the new facility). The physical resources and equipment πΈπ,π’,π‘ > 0 needed to start production are accumulated and assembled during the third and last phase – construction – of a new plant development project. For each project type, the amount of equipment required for production is usually directly proportional to the size of the investment or a plant's production capacity. We assume that πΎπ,π’,π‘ and πΈπ,π’,π‘ , the knowledge and equipment factors affecting a firm’s project completion time (ππ,π’,π‘ ), are predetermined before a firm decides on completion time.6 Finally, πΎ coefficient π½3 = − 2 ≤ 0 corresponds to the revenue (βΜ π,π’ ) elasticity of development time. In sum, the expected signs of the model coefficients in (1) (π½1 , π½2 ≥ 0, π½3 ≤ 0) reflect our expectations that, the more (intangible and physical) resources needed to develop an oil and gas facility and the lower the project’s revenues, the longer firms take to bring new investments online. Our critical focus in regression (1) is on the error term, πf,i,t. Intuitively, a negative (positive) residual implies that a project is completed faster (slower) than the industry average speed. Deviations from industry average speed are due to either suboptimal acceleration or deceleration of a project or the fact that individual firms’ speed capabilities differ from the industry average. Both factors are included in the error term as they are unobservable at the project-level. Next, we describe each of these two factors and their effects on the estimation properties of the error term. For complex projects with a wide range of heterogeneous choices, this assumption would perhaps be too strong – πΎπ,π’,π‘ , πΈπ,π’,π‘ and ππ,π’,π‘ would likely be chosen simultaneously. However, for standardized technology and commoditylike outputs, as in most of our empirical setting, this assumption is not unrealistic. For example, the National Cooperative Refining Association publicly announced in November 2002 the development of a new 30 MMcfd hydrogen plant. At the time the investment decision was made, it essentially defined, for the most part, the type of technology and equipment needed in the project. 6 10 The structure of the error term in our model is given by πf,i,t = πf,i,t + π½0 ln ( 1−πf,i,t 1−πi ) (see Appendix I for technical details). As explained above, the first term πf,i,t ≠ 0 allows for the possibility that individual firms may suboptimize the investment speed of specific projects at given points in time. This may stem from exogenous shocks in the construction process (e.g., disruptions in the supply of third-party technical equipment). It may also be due to agency problems (Jensen and Meckling 1976), as managers may excessively accelerate “pet projects” or cause delay because of lackluster efforts. Managerial mistakes and bounded rationality may also cause suboptimal acceleration. Note that we also assume that, on average, firms operating in the oil and gas industry during our period of analysis (from 1996 to 2005) chose their development time ππ,π’,π‘ to maximize their projects’ profits, πΈ(ππ,π’,π‘ ) = 0. This assumption that oil companies collectively optimize on project speed is central to our estimation procedure and reasonable in our empirical setting for several reasons. During this period, governments offered fewer subsidies to render uneconomic projects financially viable or distort the returns from speed in the execution of investments in oil facilities. Companies were also increasingly subject to the discipline of global capital markets due to the current maturity stage of the oil industry. The second term ( 1−πf,i,t 1−πi ) in our model residual πf,i,t captures firms’ intrinsic speed capabilities relative to the industry average, where ππ,π’,π‘ ∈ (0,1) is a parameter that shifts firms’ time-cost tradeoff such that, for any fixed level of expenditures, a more capable firm (with higher ππ,π’,π‘ ) develops projects faster. Firms’ intrinsic speed capabilities include any organizational factors that allow firms to develop investment projects more quickly than competitors. For example, in our empirical setting of the oil and gas industry, firms differ in their ability to speedily accumulate and deploy the stock of tangible and intangible resources required to bring 11 new oil plants online. Some firms may be intrinsically faster at project development for a variety of reasons such as differences in project management processes or culture.7 Prior experience and skilled labor is another important source of investment speed, as extensively documented in the Oil and Gas Journal (OGJ) (e.g., 1990, Ganapati et al. 2000). Firms’ intrinsic speed capabilities (ππ,π’,π‘ ) , although an unobservable intangible construct, affect the estimation properties of the error term ππ,π’,π‘ . Specifically, πΈ(πf,i,t ) = π½0 πΈ (ln 1−πf,i,t 1−πi 1−πf,i,t ) ≤ π½0 lnπΈ ( 1−πi ) = 0 because of 1−π Jensen's inequality and the fact that πΈ ( 1−πf,i,t ) = 1 (by construction). Since πΈ(ππ,π’,π‘ ) ≤ 0, the i ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of the intercepts π½0π’ may be biased (but not the coefficients of the remaining variables). To conclude, our first-stage regression error term ο±f ,i ,t constitutes our empirical proxy for project speed, or how much firms’ development time ππ,π’,π‘ deviates from the industry average after controlling for project-specific characteristics. Our next step is to examine how these deviations from industry average speed affect firm value. The Effect of Speed on Performance Nonzero project speed ππ,π’,π‘ implies that a firm’s project completion time differs from the industry average because of either suboptimal behavior or firm specific speed capabilities. The implication is that there is firm heterogeneity in the relationship between the speed estimate and performance. Accordingly, we use the following random parameters model (see appendix II for associated discussion and derivation): For example, “an organization that has an outcome-oriented culture and is able to navigate the regulatory environment can speed up plant development” (senior oil and gas industry consultant). Also, ample evidence exists that, in oil and gas, a firm’s “[ability to pursue] a modular investment approach (…) speeds construction” (Stell 2003; see also Ganapati et al. 2000). 7 12 0 Ππ,π‘ = πΏπ,π‘ + πΏπ1 Θπ,π‘ + πΏπ2 Λπ,π‘ + ππ,π‘ (2) 0 where Ππ,π‘ is a measure of firm j’s performance at time t, πΏπ,π‘ are industry i (product, geography) and time t dummies plus a random constant term, and the coefficients πΏππ₯ = πΏ π₯ + ζππ₯ (π₯ = 1,2) vary per firm π, where πΏ π₯ is the common-mean coefficient across firms and ζππ₯ is a random term. ππ,π‘ is a mean zero i.i.d. stochastic error term. The variableο Λπ,π‘ ο captures other necessary control variables that are known to affect performance. The focal independent variable Θπ,π‘ (Θπ,π‘ = − (∑π,π’ Μ π’,π‘ ππ,π’,π‘ −π ππ’,π‘ ) /ππ,π‘ ) is the average standardized investment speed of all ππ,π‘ projects of firm π completed at time π‘ across all Μ and ππ’,π‘ are the average and standard deviation of project speed in industry i industries, where ππ’,π‘ at time π‘, respectively. The construction averages out randomness in ππ,π’,π‘ and captures the firm’s intrinsic speed capabilities relative to the industry average as well as average sub-optimality due to agency behavior. After controlling for suboptimal behavior, the resulting random parameter estimate πΏπ1 captures the varying effect of firms’ intrinsic speed capabilities on performance. In addition, the correlations between the random parameters in the model that are associated with control firm characteristics will further validate expected variations between the impact of intrinsic speed on firm value. We describe our empirical steps in more detail in the next section. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS We conducted our empirical analysis in the worldwide oil and gas industry from 1996 to 2005. The speed of investment in new oil plants has a significant impact on firm performance, as the loss of a single day’s revenue due to plant construction delays can cost a company hundreds of thousands of dollars. For instance, Spletter et al. (2002) estimated the gross margin loss per day of an average size ethylene cracker in the U.S. Gulf Coast during 1997-2002 at approximately 13 $411,000. The oil and gas industry also serves as an appropriate setting for this study because of public reporting of data on project execution time and the possibility of studying various regions and products simultaneously while maintaining a homogeneous sample. Data and variables Our data sample contains investment and timing information we collected from OGJ on a total of 2,659 refinery, petrochemical, and gas-to-liquids (GTL) plant construction projects. This sample covers virtually all plants built worldwide from 1996 to 2005. These plant investments were carried out by 847 firm subsidiaries in 99 different countries. Only a small fraction of the firms in the dataset invested in GTL plants (15 firms, as opposed to 386 and 527 firms that invested in refineries and petrochemicals, respectively). A total of 81 firms invested in at least two different types of projects during the period of analysis. The three countries with the highest number of projects by different firms included the United States (97 firms), China (71 firms), and India (63 firms). We matched each firm in our OGJ project dataset to their ultimate parent company using the Directory of Corporate Affiliations. Finally, we merged the investment dataset with financial information from Compustat on each publicly traded company. Our final sample size varies between 151 and 198 firm-year observations, depending on which measures we used for the independent variables in each regression. The operationalization of the variables in equation (2) is as follows. The dependent variable – firm π’s performance at time π‘ (Ππ,π‘ ) – is measured by Tobin’s q defined as the ratio of a firm’s market value to replacement costs of tangible assets. We proxy market value by the sum of market value of equity, book value of preferred stock, book value of long-term debt, and current liabilities less current assets. The replacement costs of tangible assets are measured as total assets less current assets and intangibles, plus the book value of inventory. Tobin’s q is 14 often used to capture the value of firms’ intangibles (e.g., Dowell et al. 2000, Morck and Yeung, 1991). Our conceptualization is that intrinsic speed capabilities are an intangible. Firm speed (Θπ,π‘ ) is the average standardized speed of all projects that firm π completed at time π‘ across all industries, where project speed (ππ,π’,π‘ ) is the residual of regression (1). In model (1), project development time (ππ,π’,π‘ ) is the lag between the start and end dates of plant development reported in the OGJ.8 The industry discount rate (π) is proxied by two different measures: the average WACC (weighted average cost of capital) and the average EBIDA (earnings before interest, depreciation, and amortization over total assets) across all oil companies with Compustat-CRSP Merged financial data from 1996 to 2005.9 The increase in 8 The official start (end) of plant development is assumed to be the date in which the project is first (last) reported in the OGJ minus (plus) 90 days. The 90-day lag occurs because the OGJ reports the status of each plant development project only twice per year, in April and October. Thus, if a project appears for the first time in one issue of the journal, we can only infer that development started sometime after the prior issue and before the current one. For simplicity, we assume that development started exactly in-between the two consecutive issues of the OGJ, thus the 90-day (3-month) lag. A similar logic applies to the official end date of the project, unless an expected completion date was reported, in which case, the latter is assumed to be the official end date. Since the OGJ lists updated, self-reported expected completion dates for almost all plants (90.5% of the sample), our official end date measure is reasonably accurate and should be consistent with firms’ internal records. The measurement error associated with the official start date of a project varies between 0 and 3 months and corresponds, on average, to 7.14% of the total development time of a plant (21 months). This relatively small project-specific error is likely washed out as we have several project observations per firm. We also do not expect substantial biases in firms’ timing of announcements of new projects (e.g., for strategic reasons). Bluffing in this industry is not very effective because firms’ actions are externally visible. The extremely regulated oil and gas industry is the center of attention of several government bodies, consulting companies, and subcontractors. Even at the very early stages of projects, the extent of under- or over-reporting is limited by the fact that firms need to apply in advance for construction permits from regulators, order plant components from a few global suppliers ahead of time, and often outsource the initial stages (study/planning) to external contractors. Bluffing is also not a sustainable long-term strategy because it reflects on companies’ reputations – especially in a setting with repeated interactions between incumbent firms that have operated in a mature industry for a long period of time. Finally, there are strong reasons to believe that, when plant development projects are reported for the first time in the OGJ, firms are credibly committed to the investment. This is the case because companies abandon or cancel only a very small fraction of the projects listed (about 1.5%). ππ,π’,π‘ is reported in months. 9 Compustat-CRSP Merged financial data was collected for a universe of firms operating from 1996 to 2005 in the oil products industry (SIC code 29) and the chemical industry (SIC code 28 excluding pharmaceuticals – SIC code 283). In contrast with our original sample from Compustat, the Compustat-CRSP Merged dataset was not restricted to only companies that invested in an oil plant during the period of analysis. This approach allows for a more accurate approximation to the industry discount rate. For each company, = ππππππ‘πππ πΌπππππ π΅πππππ π·ππππππππ‘πππ−πΌπππππ πππ₯ππ . We construct WACC as a weighted average between the Equity πππ‘ππ π΄π π ππ‘π Cost of Capital (ECC, proxied by the Earnings Yield = πΈπππππππ πππ πβπππ ππππ πΈππ πππππ and the Debt Cost of Capital (DCC = 15 revenues from plant development (βΜ π,π’ ) is operationalized as the average demand growth, which we proxy by the annual growth rate in real GDP in each location from the World Bank Development Indicators database.10 The amount of physical resources and equipment (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) required for a project is directly proportional to a plant’s production capacity. We operationalized this variable accordingly using OGJ data (in volume and mass units for refinery, GTL plants and petrochemical plants, respectively). Technological knowledge (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) depends on the technical complexity of each project. Complexity data is only available for refinery plants (see Nelson’s Complexity Index, in Leffler 2000: 216). However, restricting our dataset exclusively to refineries would create an unreasonably small final sample in regression (2) (after merging with Compustat-CRSP financials). Also, the complexity variable proved not statistically significant or only marginally significant in regression (1) with the restricted refinery sample. Therefore, we use our whole dataset (refinery, petrochemical, and GTL projects) and exclude the complexity measure from the estimation of the project speed residuals in regression (1). Model (1) included industry dummies as column vectors of product dummies (for refinery, petrochemical, GTL plants) and geography dummies (17 regions were identified; we assigned a dummy to each country with over 2% of the dataset projects and aggregated the remaining countries to prevent an excessive loss of data in the standardization of the project speed residuals). πΌππ‘ππππ π‘ πΈπ₯ππππ π using market capitalization as weights. Formally, we have that ππ΄πΆπΆ = πΈπΆπΆ ∗ πΏπππ ππππ π·πππ‘+πΆπ’πππππ‘ πΏπππππππ‘πππ ππππππ‘ πΆππππ‘ππππ§ππ‘πππ ππππππ‘ πΆππππ‘ππππ§ππ‘πππ+πΏπππ ππππ π·πππ‘+πΆπ’πππππ‘ πΏπππππππ‘πππ +π·πΆπΆ ∗ πΏπππ−ππππ π·πππ‘+πΆπ’πππππ‘ πΏπππππππ‘πππ ππππππ‘ πΆππππ‘ππππ§ππ‘πππ+πΏπππ ππππ π·πππ‘+πΆπ’πππππ‘ πΏπππππππ‘πππ . For both the average EBIDA and the average WACC we account for yearly differences in inflation by subtracting the inflation rate (calculated using the growth rate in the CPI-U from the Bureau of Labor Statistics). Therefore, we use the real discount rate in model (1). 10 Most prior work proxied demand growth by the four-year historical compound annual growth rate of production for the product-region (e.g., Gilbert and Lieberman 1987, Lieberman 1987, Henderson and Cool 2003). However, this operationalization is intractable in our empirical setting because our data covers a substantially greater number of plant locations (99 countries) and a wider spectrum of refining and chemical products and byproducts. 16 In equation (2) the key control variables in (Λπ,π‘ ) are those that reflect the quality of a firm’s corporate governance. The financial economics literature has well established that good corporate governance comprise of efficient management monitoring and shareholder protection, which positively affects firm valuation and Tobin’s q (Morck et al. 1988, Shleifer and Vishny 1997, Gompers et al. 2003). Critically, corporate governance affects the performance of the intrinsic speed variable in equation (2): good corporate governance will likely enhance the impact of intrinsic speed capabilities on firm value and at the same time it mitigates the suboptimal component in our proxy for speed (Θπ,π‘ ). We use two well-accepted measures of corporate governance in this paper. (1) Blockholding represents the percentage of common stock held by institutional investors owning at least 5% of a company’s outstanding common stock. Larger stockowners can often better monitor and control a company using voting rights associated with their holding. We obtain this variable by averaging quarterly institutional ownership data from Thomson Financial 13F Filings for each firm-year in our oil dataset. (2) For robustness, S&P Score is a percentile score based on each firm’s Standard and Poor’s Transparency and Disclosure Index (S&P Index). Standard and Poor’s generates this index by examining the annual reports and standard regulatory filings of 1,443 companies worldwide for 98 financial, governance, and ownership disclosure items. We sum the S&P Index across these reported disclosure ratings for each company and convert the total into a percentile score defined within our final company sample. Prior literature has widely used the S&P Index as an indicator of stockholders’ protection (Bushee 2004, Durnev and Kim 2005, Khanna et al. 2006). We follow standard practice in the Tobin’s q literature to include as other controls a firm’s R&D Intensity (R&D expenditures over total assets), Leverage (long-term debt over total assets), and Advertising Intensity (advertising expenditures over total assets). Advertising 17 Intensity is not reported in the final estimations because it proved statistically insignificant in all exploratory regressions of model (2) and is missing in many of our sample firms. Finally, we include year, industry, and country dummies based on parent-level data in our estimation of equation (2). For industry effects, we use 2-digit SIC codes (13 for Oil and Gas Extraction, 28 for Chemicals and Allied Products, 29 for Petroleum and Coal Products, and 50 for Wholesale Trade-Durable Goods). We based country dummies on the parent company’s home country. Statistical Method As discussed above and in Appendix III, we estimate equation (2) using random parameter regression methods.11 The random parameter model provides a distributional characterization of the relationship between speed capabilities and performance, the estimated mean and the estimated standard deviation across firms, which is assumed to follow a normal distribution πΏππ₯ ~π(πΏ π₯ + ζππ₯ , π 2 ). The common mean, πΏ π₯ reveals the average impact of intrinsic capabilities on firm value, assuming that sub-optimality can lead to over- or under-speeding in project completion across firms. Additionally, the use of simulation within the random parameter model allows us to obtain firm-specific estimates of πΏπ1 in order to study the nature of the speedperformance relationship at the firm level. We estimate the RPM using simulated maximum likelihood. For the simulation, we use 100 “smart” draws using the Halton sequence as in Greene (2001) (Halton draws avoid the “clumpy” draws that can occur with random draws and accelerate the convergence in the estimation process). In our estimation, we allow five key independent variables to be random: our measure of 11 For additional reviews and examples, see Revelt and Train 1998; Train 1998; Layton and Brown 2000; McFadden and Train 2000; Chung and Alcacer 2002; Train 2003; Greene 2004. 18 firm speed, corporate governance, R&D intensity, leverage, and the intercept. Our interest focuses on the mean and standard deviation estimates for the firm speed random parameter. These estimates allow us to infer whether speed creates value for firms on average (based on the significance of the mean estimate) and whether the firm heterogeneity plays an important role in the relationship (based on the significance of the standard deviation estimate). The random intercept acts as a random effect, addressing concerns regarding possible forms of omitted firm heterogeneity. The other three key control variables (corporate governance, R&D intensity, and leverage) are standard controls for Tobin’s q regressions and allow us to examine how different kinds of firm heterogeneity co-vary in the speed-performance relationship. Accordingly, we allow the random parameters in our model to be freely correlated. The underlying issue is that unobserved firm heterogeneity influences the correlation between the coefficients in the random parameter estimation of equation (2). If these estimated correlations conform to expectations, they add credence to our arguments. First, consider the correlation between two main regression random coefficients, πΏπ1 for the speed proxy and the coefficient, πΏπ2 , for corporate governance. We would expect that these two random coefficients to co-vary negatively. For a well governed firm, further incremental enforcement in monitoring improves firm value little (πΏπ2 is lower) and yet the speed capability proxy has less of a sub-optimal component and a greater intrinsic speed capability component so that the proxy should have high impact on performance (πΏπ1 is higher). Second, consider the correlation between πΏπ1 for the speed proxy and the coefficient for leverage. We would expect the parameters associated with firms’ speed capabilities and leverage to co-vary positively. Leverage directly affects unobserved heterogeneity in firm discount rates. Debt erodes firm value more (i.e., the negative effect of leverage on firm value is exacerbated) 19 for firms facing greater liquidity constraints and higher external cost of capital (the regression coefficient is more negative). These firms also typically have a higher discount rate, which lowers project investment profits and thus reduces the value of investment speed. (See Appendix III for more detailed derivation of these considerations.) Since the random parameters are allowed to be freely correlated, we obtain and report the random parameters covariance matrix ΩπΏ . Our estimation produces the Γ matrix, where Γ is a lower triangular Cholesky factor of the random parameters covariance matrix (ΩπΏ = ΓΓ′). While the elements of Γ have no direct interpretation, it allows us to determine whether correlated random parameters are a more appropriate econometric specification versus uncorrelated (by looking at the significance of the elements of Γ): if off-diagonal terms of the Γ matrix are significant, it suggests an uncorrelated random parameter model would result in model misspecification. We proceed to determine the significance of (1) the estimated standard deviations of the random parameters and (2) the estimated covariance terms between the random parameters. We use the delta method to calculate the asymptotic standard errors of the estimated (co)variance of each parameter.12 Finally, the random parameter model also allows us to obtain firm-specific coefficients in the speed-performance relationship. The use of simulation allows for the estimation of firmspecific parameters using Bayes theorem (Greene 2004). These firm-specific parameters enable vivid comparisons across firms and allow us to empirically identify firms that excel or lag in intrinsic speed capabilities. These firms should, then, become natural candidates for in-depth case study analyses. 12 We use the delta method: (1) with the function π = √Γ(π) ∗ Γ(π)′ for the estimated standard deviations (Γ(π) is the π π‘β row of the Γ matrix); (2) with the function π = Γ(π) ∗ Γ(π)′ for the πππ‘β estimated covariance term. The delta method uses a Taylor series approximation to the asymptotic standard errors of the standard deviation and covariance terms, which by construction are functions of several random variables (the elements of Γ above). 20 As a first step in our analysis, we conduct initial regressions using OLS with standard errors robust to clustering by firm before proceeding to the random parameter estimations. We further check the robustness of our estimations in the robustness section. ESTIMATION RESULTS We present descriptive statistics and correlation matrices for our variables in Tables 1(a)-1(c). All variables show substantial empirical variation. The mean and standard deviation of project development time for the 2,659 plant investments in our dataset are 20.796 and 14.584 months, respectively, with a maximum of 109 months. Tobin’s q also varies widely by more than one order of magnitude (i.e., a factor of 10) during the period of analysis and positively correlates with firm speed, which suggests that faster firms generally have higher firm value. **Insert Tables 1(a)-1(c) about here** We proceed to our multivariate analyses. We first use OLS to estimate (1) and use the residuals to produce the firm level proxy for intrinsic speed capabilities. These first-stage results are presented in Table 2. We find that the multivariate OLS regression results of model (1) are consistent with our theoretical predictions, independently of whether we use WACC or EBIDA as the industry discount rate in the complete sample or in the refineries subsample. Below we only comment on coefficient estimates that use the WACC measure in the complete 2,659 oil and gas project observations because this is usually considered a better proxy than EBIDA for the cost of capital. **Insert Table 2 about here** As expected, the revenue (GDP Rate) elasticity of development time is negative and significant (π½3 = −0.553, π < 0.1). Greater forecasted project revenues (or foregone revenues from investment delays) give firms more incentive to compress time in project development. 21 Also as predicted, the elasticity of development time with respect to the stock of physical resources (equipment) needed to build a plant is positive and highly significant (π½1 = 0.053, π < 0.01). Firms take longer to complete larger investment projects. As for the effect of complexity on development time, inferences can only be made for projects in the refineries subsample because complexity data is only available for refineries. Technological complexity slows down investments (as hypothesized) by an elasticity factor comparable to that of capacity. However, this effect is shown to be marginally significant or statistically insignificant. One possible explanation for this result is that project complexity matters less when firms already possess much of the technical knowledge in-house, a likely case when most firms are incumbents in a mature industry such as oil and gas. Since restricting our dataset exclusively to refineries would leave us with an unreasonably small final sample (after merging with Compustat-CRSP financials), we proceeded by excluding the complexity measure from the first-stage estimation and used the whole dataset observations (i.e., refinery, petrochemical, and GTL projects). Using the residuals from our first stage results, we construct our measure of intrinsic speed capabilities. Figure 1 graphically depicts that our speed measure has substantial variation in project and firm speed for the 2,659 investments by the 847 oil and gas firm subsidiaries in our sample from 1996 to 2005. The distribution of the estimated speed residuals from model (1) exhibits positive skewness, with the modal firm and project being slower than the industry average. While firms accelerated investments up to five standard deviations above the industry norm, they were never more than two standard deviations slower than the industry. By construction in our model, the speed residuals in Figure 1 represent the joint distribution of speed suboptimization and speed capabilities across projects and firms in our dataset. Assuming that speed capabilities are normally distributed in the population of oil firms, the positive skewness in 22 Figure 1 is suggestive of suboptimal project acceleration. We would expect that deliberate speed suboptimization is more likely to be biased towards excessive project acceleration than deceleration because of the extensive foregone revenues typically associated with delays in investment projects in the oil and gas industry, and the estimates in Figure 1 confirm this expectation. **Insert Figure 1 about here** We then conduct our second stage estimations using (1) multivariate OLS with standard errors robust to clustering by firm, and (2) a linear random parameter model with freely correlated coefficients. These results are presented in Tables 3 and 4. In Table 3, we present our results using OLS robust to clustering by firm. These exploratory regressions provide widespread support to the hypothesis that faster firms tend to have higher firm values. The coefficient associated with firm speed is always positive and significant whether we use WACC or EBIDA as the industry discount rate with the corporate governance Blockholding measure (similar results are obtained with S&P Score). Finally, the control variables are also generally significant and with the expected sign: while R&D Intensity enhances firm value, leverage erodes it. Advertising Intensity is the only standard control variable in Tobin’s q regressions that comes out consistently insignificant in our OLS estimations. This can be explained because Marketing plays a more limited role in commodity industries such as oil and gas than in many other industries. Additionally, since Advertising Intensity makes our final sample extremely small, we excluded it from our final model estimation. Finally, note that the inclusion of the Blockholding variable also substantially reduces our sample in more than 30% (from about 222 to 151 observations), which affects overall significance levels. 23 **Insert Table 3 about here** Table 4 reports the linear random parameter regression with freely correlated coefficients of model (2) using WACC industry discount rate and the Blockholding corporate governance measure. All common mean coefficients across firms reported in the second column of Table 4 have the predicted sign and are very significant (at the 1% level). In particular, the firm speed coefficient (πΏ 1 ) is positive, which suggests that possessing speed capabilities boost firms’ market value, as captured by Tobin’s q. Firms with intrinsic speed capabilities, relative to others, can accumulate more quickly the technological knowledge required to bring new oil plants online at low costs. The magnitude of this effect is shown to be considerably large. On average, accelerating a firm’s investments by 5% (or 1 month) below the industry norm due to organizational capabilities increases market value by $214.3 million.13 **Insert Table 4 about here** The mean parameter associated with the Blockholding variable (πΏ 2 ) is positive, a finding consistent with the financial economics literature. Firms with high institutional Blockholding are more efficiently monitored and, thus, better managed, which results in higher firm value (Gompers and Metrick 2001). The other control variables also behave as expected. A firm’s R&D intensity boosts a company’s market value indicating that R&D is an intangible asset. Firms’ leverage is associated with lower values of Tobin’s q suggesting that greater than average leverage raises the cost of capital or is indicative of lower than average past profitability. Note 13 From model (1), we have that πππ,π’,π‘ πππ,π’,π‘ = ππ −πππ,π’,π‘ (1−π . In our sample, for a hypothetical oil firm that owns one −πππ,π’,π‘ ) investment project per industry i at time t, a simultaneous identical acceleration in all of its projects relative to each πΘπ,π‘ industry i affects firm speed by = − ∑π,π’ (1⁄ππ’,π‘ ) /ππ,π‘ . The marginal variation in Tobin’s q due to changes in πππ,π’,π‘ firm speed for an average oil firm is given by the estimated common-mean coefficient πΏ 1 = 0.112 (in Table 4). Finally, firm value varies with Tobin’s q proportionally to a firm’s replacement costs of tangible assets. Using the average asset value of $26.151 BN for firms with financials from Compustat North America in the sample establishes the result. Note that an increase of $214.3 million in market value corresponds to nearly 1% of the asset value of an average oil firm. 24 that we have industry and year dummies in our regressions and they are generally significant. Third, all random parameters in the estimation of equation (2) have very significant estimated standard deviations (at the 1% level), as shown in the last column of Table 4. This offers compelling evidence that there is unobserved firm heterogeneity so that the impact of the independent variables on firm value (Tobin’s q) varies across firms. Critically, for the same proxy value for speed, different firms will experience impact on their respective market value14 Figure 2 illustrates firm specific coefficient estimates for the key variable of interest, firm speed. The centipede plot represents 95% confidence intervals and point estimates for the individual speed parameters of the 51 firms in our sample. These estimates at the 95 confidence interval the possible impact on firm value when a firm accelerates investments. **Insert Figure 2 about here** The centipede plot demonstrates that while speed improves market value for the large majority of firms, the effect shows substantial intra-industry variation. For firms such as China Petroleum and Chemical Corporation (Sinopec), accelerating oil and gas investments by 5% (or 1 month) below the industry norm increases market value by as much as $831 million (i.e., twoand-a-half times more than the expected average value increase from speed). Sinopec is the largest refiner and petrochemical producer in the fastest-growing world economy; thus, delays in project development entail high revenue losses and speed yields substantial benefits. In contrast, a small subset of the companies in our dataset generates negative returns from speed, which has two explanations. For some firms, ineffective corporate governance results in suboptimal project acceleration and speed may be achieved by overinvesting in “pet projects”. This likely occurs in 14 Applying OLS to model (2), we also obtain a positive regression coefficient for speed. The improvement in fit of the RPM versus the corresponding OLS model, measured by a likelihood ratio test, is highly significant (λ = 2 57.998, p < 0.005 for χ16 ). 25 the case of firms with poor corporate governance scores such as the semi-public company Petrobras Brasileiro, which owned Brazil’s oil monopoly until 1997. For other firms with better corporate governance practices such as BP, a negative speed parameter perhaps indicates important technological or organizational problems that hinder a firm’s ability to pursue speed. Indeed, BP experienced unreliable operational efficiency, delays in production at several oil rigs, and growing organizational complexity during the period of analysis. Solving these issues would have enhanced investment speed but would have required costly investments that would ultimately discount the benefits of improved speed capabilities. Finally, the implied covariance terms of the random parameters in Table 5 provide further evidence of how unobserved firm heterogeneity influences the effect of speed on firm value. All but one covariance terms are highly significant. A significant covariance term means that some of the underlying reasons for coefficient heterogeneity are shared by two independent variables. In other words, if differences between firms simultaneously impact on the effects of multiple independent variables on firm value, the marginal effects of these variables are correlated across firms. **Insert Table 5 about here** The correlations of the coefficients conform to our theoretical expectation. We focus on the correlations discussed in the statistical method section; that is, the covariances associated with the coefficient of the main independent variable in the model, firm speed. The speed and the corporate governance (Blockholding) parameters co-vary negatively, as expected indicating that high corporate governance firms benefit less from more monitoring and yet more from project completion speed because the speed is driven by intrinsic capabilities. Also, the parameters associated with firms’ speed capabilities and leverage correlate positively. Firms for which debt 26 has a more negative impact on firm value generally face more severe liquidity constraints so that more debts damage firm value more and drives up costs of capital more so that they benefit less from accelerating investment completion. Lastly, the remaining correlation of interest – between R&D intensity and speed – is positive indicating that firms that create more value from investments in R&D also benefit more from exploiting speed capabilities. This result may reflect firms’ general ability to deploy and capitalize on intangible assets to achieve privileged productmarket positions. ROBUSTNESS CHECKS We conducted numerous robustness checks. We first examined possible issues with our first stage regressions regarding alternative variable definitions, alternative samples, potential omitted variables, and other concerns regarding endogeneity: (i) Using WACC or EBIDA as the industry discount rate produced identical results. (ii) Restricting our sample exclusively to the refinery sub-industry observations (where complexity data is available) also did not change the estimations for the key variables of interest. (iii) The findings were robust to the inclusion of year dummies (together with industry dummies), with the exception of the GDP Rate that turned insignificant. The latter result occurs because the GDP Rate only varies per industry and over time. (iv) Uncertainty in project revenues had no effect on speed. The inclusion of uncertainty, defined as the standard deviation of four years’ worth of the GDP Rate prior to the year under consideration, proved insignificant. This may be due to the maturity of the oil industry since the 1980s, where “demand forecasts reflect a strong consensus, there being a difference between the highest and lowest of less than 10%. This compares with the 100% difference which was prevalent in the 1970s” (Chemical Insight 1987: 2). (v) We directly tested for endogeneity in model (1). The fact that project characteristics (e.g., capacity) are endogenously chosen by firms 27 suggests the possibility that these variables can be contemporaneously correlated with firms’ speed capabilities and, thus, the error term. However, the Hausman test rejected this hypothesis (after estimating equation (1) with instruments for project-specific variables). (vi) We collected OGJ data on outsourcing and controlled for the subcontractors that firms used in each of the different stages of plant development, and our results in model (1) did not change substantially. The findings in our estimation of equation (2) are not qualitatively affected by adopting any of the various modified estimations of firm speed in equation (1) described in this paragraph.15,16 We then explored the robustness of our second stage results, examining alternative variable definitions, econometric specifications, and other statistical issues. As discussed in the results section, we used alternative measures of the industry discount rate (WACC and EBIDA) and corporate governance (Blockholding and S&P Score), and the speed variable always came out positive and proved significant in all but one of the four models. Second, we explored alternative econometric specifications by estimating both OLS with standard errors robust to clustering by firm and random parameter regressions. Our results stay broadly consistent across all econometric specifications, with similar estimates across the common-mean coefficients. Third, our estimation results are robust to an analysis of speed outliers. Only two firms were identified as potential outliers influencing our regressions; their exclusion did not change the main results of the paper. Finally, we explored the possibilities of reverse causality and sample 15 The only noticeable exception was the fact that controlling for subcontracting rendered the corporate governance measure (i.e., Blockholding) insignificant. One possible explanation for this result, consistent with the strategy and financial economics literatures, is that arm’s length market transactions (i.e., subcontracting) likely discipline firms’ actions and reduce agency problems. In other words, the “discipline of the market” seems a substitute mechanism for corporate-governance control in ensuring organizational optimization. 16 We predicated our estimation of model (2) on the assumption that our speed measure is statistically different across firms. We directly checked the robustness of this assumption by testing for the joint significance of firm fixed effects in model (1). We rejected the null hypotheses of nonsignificance at the 0.1% level. 28 selection, and we did not find any evidence of concern.17,18 DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS This paper integrates firms’ investment speed trade-off in a reduced-form model of project development to create an empirical proxy for firm speed, which is comprised of a component driven by intrinsic capabilities and another due to sub-optimality, and offers a comprehensive empirical account of the impact of firm speed on performance. Our analysis measured speed as deviations from industry-average time of execution of large investments in oil and gas facilities worldwide from 1996 to 2005. The data shows substantial variation in investment speed between firms in the oil and gas industry. Our data support the central theme that firms should pursue speed only by exploiting intrinsic speed capabilities, which is value enhancing. Superior intrinsic speed capabilities generally reduce the costs of speed by allowing firms to accumulate and deploy the required physical and human resources needed for project execution at a faster pace. Using oil and gas We carefully analyzed the possibility of reverse causality (Tobin’s q influencing firm speed) in our estimations of equation (2). Contemporaneous reverse causality, or cases where high firm market value at year t causes firms to speed up projects that are completed that same year, is less of a concern in our setting. On average, it takes approximately two years to build a new oil and gas facility (i.e., firms start investments in year t-2). The availability of more financial resources towards the end of a project (in year t) does not change investment speed prior to that date and is unlikely to make firms implement time-consuming and costly changes in the closing stages of a project. These effects are exacerbated by the fact that investments in the oil industry presuppose substantial initial precommitments to specific plant-development plans. Thus, potential endogeneity should not be an issue in the current specification of our model. This conclusion is reinforced by the fact that we lack empirical support even for the empirically more plausible scenario of lagged reverse causality. We ran several multivariate OLS regressions with and without the covariance matrix robust to clustering by firm where firm speed was regressed on lagged Tobin’s q (and controls). We did not obtain any significant statistical results. 18 Our reduced-form econometric model is conditional on firms’ decision to invest in an oil and gas facility in industry i at time t. We examined the implications of this constraint for our empirical estimations. We created a pool of all US firms listed in the Compustat-CRSP Merged database (CCM) as oil companies in 2000. The majority (between 67% and 78%) of oil firms invested in an oil facility from 1996 to 2005. Moreover, the total market capitalization (in 2000 dollars) of firms with at least one project in our OGJ investment dataset was 97.8%. The remaining 2.2% of market capitalization corresponded to oil firms listed in the CCM dataset that did not invest in an oil facility from 1996 to 2005. Hence, most oil companies invested during the period of analysis and those that did not were very small (mostly private) firms. This result was robust whether we used 1996 or 2000 as the base comparison year. Since oil and gas is a mature industry where most investments are made by incumbent companies, these stylized empirical facts establish that our OGJ database constitutes a relatively complete and inclusive company investment sample. Thus, biases due to the estimation of our model conditional on firms’ decision to invest in an oil and gas facility from 1996 to 2005 are perhaps less likely. 17 29 data, we find the magnitude of this effect on firm value is considerable. On average, accelerating a firm’s investments by 5% (or 1 month) below the industry norm due to capabilities is worth $214.3 million in market value. In addition, the effect of speed on Tobin’s q varies substantially among firms. Some oil and gas companies in our sample create as much as two and a half times more value from speed than the industry average, while a small subset of the companies in our dataset generates negative returns from speed. Our random coefficient regression gives insight into the firm level variations in the impact of speed on value, e.g., firms with higher cost of capital benefit less from speed and firms with poorer governance may sub-optimize investment speeds. Our study has several implications for strategy researchers. First, we develop a new proxy for the intrinsic speed capabilities of firms based on a formal analysis of firms’ investment speed tradeoff grounded on the stylized empirical regularities of the oil and gas industry. Our results contribute to the extensive literature in strategy on the importance of speed in firm competition. Second, we adopted a useful empirical methodology, the random parameter model, to account for and explore firm level heterogeneity in the relationship between speed and firm value. This estimation method enhances the inferences that can be drawn from the data using both distributional and firm specific estimates, providing large sample validation for in-depth qualitative case studies of specific companies. For example, our results suggest that China Petroleum Corp and Exxon Mobil generate substantial returns from speed whereas our estimates suggest the opposite for BP: these firm specific estimates suggest interesting candidates for extensive field work, creating a promising link between quantitative and qualitative research. Generalizations and limitations of this paper are as follows. The magnitude of the effect of speed on firm value reported in this paper typifies, perhaps, mature industries with chronic 30 excess capacity, such as oil and gas. In growing markets, the potential foregone profits from delaying investments tend to be greater and, thus, the benefits of speed may be even more noticeable. It is unclear how other structural characteristics of an industry (e.g., the rate of technological innovation, market structure, the degree of outsourcing and subcontracting) or strategic interactions among firms (e.g., preemption, pricing, or innovation games) calibrate the effect of speed on firm performance. This observation may constitute motivation for future work. Other possibilities for future research include examining whether our findings for investment speed in large production facilities also hold true in the context of speed in new product or technology development. Finally, we believe that the positive relationship between intrinsic speed capabilities and firm value stems from many more nuanced reasons than solely the ability to collect revenues sooner. For instance, Hawk, Pacheco-de-Almeida, and Yeung (2012) document that intrinsic speed capabilities may generate value via strategic entry timing into new market opportunities. We believe that the strategic value of intrinsic speed capabilities needs further exploration. 31 REFERENCES Agarwal, R., M. Gort. 2001. First-Mover Advantage and the Speed of Competitive Entry, 18871986. Journal of Law and Economics, XLIV 161-177. Barnett, W. P., M. Hansen. 1996. The Red Queen in Organizational Evolution. Strategic Management Journal, 17 139-157. Barnett, W. P., E. G. Pontikes. 2008. The Red Queen, Success Bias, and Organizational Inertia. Management Science, 54 1237-1251. Barney, J. B. 1986. Strategic Factor Markets: Expectations, Luck, and Business Strategy. Management Science, 32 1231-1241. Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. Journal of Management, 17 99-120. Boehm, B. W. 1981. Software Engineering Economics Prentice Hall Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Brown, S. L., K. M. Eisenhardt. 1998. Competing on the Edge. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA. Bushee, B. J. 2004. Discussion of Disclosure Practices of Foreign Companies Interacting with U.S. Markets. Journal of Accounting Research, 42 509-525. Chemical Insight. 1987. Chung, W., J. Alcácer. 2002. Knowledge Seeking and Location Choice of Foreign Direct Investment in the United States. Management Science, 48 1534-1554. Clark, K. B. 1989. Project Scope and Project Performance: The Effect of Parts Strategy and Supplier Involvement on Product Development. Management Science, 35 1247-1263. Cohen, M. A., J. Eliashberg, T.-H. Ho. 1996. New Product Development: The Performance and Time-to-Market Tradeoff. Management Science, 42 173-186. D'Aveni, R. A. 1994. Hypercompetition. The Free Press, New York, NY. Dierickx, I., K. Cool. 1989. Asset Stock Accumulation and Sustainability Of Competitive Advantage. Management Science, 35 1504-1511. Dowell, G., S. Hart, B. Yeung. 2000. Do Corporate Global Environmental Standards Create or Destroy Market Value? Management Science, 46 1059-1074. Durnev, A., E. H. Kim. 2005. To Steal or Not to Steal: Firm Attributes, Legal Environment, and Valuation. The Journal of Finance, LX 1461-1493. Eisenhardt, K. M. 1989. Making Fast Strategic Decisions in High-Velocity Environments. Academy of Management Journal, 32 543-576. Eisenhardt, K. M., S. L. Brown. 1998. Time Pacing: Competing in Markets that Won't Stand Still. Harvard Business Review, March-April 59-69. Ganapati, M., R. Ding, P. D. Mooley. 2000. Modular Construction of Catalyst-Regen Unit Saves Time, Costs. Oil and Gas Journal, June 19, 2000 48. Ghemawat, P. 1991. Commitment. The Free Press, New York, NY. Gilbert, R. J., M. Lieberman. 1987. Investment and Coordination in Oligopolistic Industries. RAND Journal of Economics, 18 17-33. Gompers, P., J. Ishii, A. Metrick. 2003. Corporate Governance and Equity Prices. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118 107-155. Gompers, P. A., A. Metrick. 2001. Institutional Investors and Equity Prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116 229-259. Gort, M., S. Klepper. 1982. Time Paths in the Diffusion of Product Innovations. The Economic Journal, 92 630-653. 32 Gould, J. P. 1968. Adjustment Costs in the Theory of Investment of the Firm. The Review of Economic Studies, 35 47-55. Graves, S. B. 1989. The Time-Cost Tradeoff in Research and Development: A Review. Engineering Costs and Production Economics, 16 1-9. Greene, W. 2001. Fixed and Random Effects in Nonlinear Models, New York University Working Paper Series: 1-48. New York City. Greene, W. 2004. Interpreting Estimated Parameters and Measuring Individual Heterogeneity in Random Coefficient Models, New York University Working Paper Series: 1-19. New York. Hawk, A., G. Pacheco-de-Almeida, B Yeung. 2012. Fast Mover Advantages: Speed Capabilities and Entry into the Emerging Submarket of Atlantic Basin LNG, forthcoming, Strategic Management Journal. Helfat, C. E., S. Finkelstein, W. Mitchell, M. A. Peteraf, H. Singh, D. J. Teece, S. G. Winter. 2007. Dynamic Capabilities: Understanding Strategic Change in Organizations. Blackwell Publishing Ltd., Oxford, U.K. Henderson, J. E., K. Cool. 2003. Learning to Time Capacity Expansions: An Empirical Analysis of the Worldwide Petrochemical Industry, 1975-95. Strategic Management Journal, 24 393-413. Hendricks, K. B., V. R. Singhal. 1997. Delays in New Product Introductions and the Market Value of the Firm: The Consequences of Being Late to the Market. Management Science, 43. Jensen, M. C., W. H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3 305-360. Jovanovic, B., G. MacDonald. 1994. The Life Cycle of a Competitive Industry. The Journal of Political Economy, 102 322-347. Katila, R., E. L. Chen. 2008. Effects of Search Timing on Product Innovation: The Value of Not Being in Sync. Administrative Science Quarterly, 53 593-625. Khanna, T., J. Kogan, K. Palepu. 2006. Globalization and Similarities in Corporate Governance: A Cross-Country Analysis. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 88 69-90. Layton, D. F., G. Brown. 2000. Heterogeneous Preferences Regarding Global Climate Change. The Review of Economic and Statistics, 82 616-624. Leffler, W. L. 2000. Petroleum Refining in Nontechnical Language. (Third Edition ed.) PennWell Corporation, Tulsa, OK. Lenox, M. J., S. F. Rockart, A. Y. Lewin. 2007. Interdependency, Competition, and Industry Dynamics. Management Science, 53 599-615. Lieberman, M. B. 1987. Excess Capacity as a Barrier to Entry: An Empirical Appraisal. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35 607-627. Lucas, R. E. 1971. Optimal Management of a Research and Development Project. Management Science, 17 679-697. Mansfield, E. 1971. Industrial Research and Technological Innovation. Norton, New York. McFadden, D., K. Train. 2000. Mixed MNL Models for Discrete Response. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 15 447-470. Mitchell, W. 1991. Dual Clocks: Entry Order Influences on Incumbent and Newcomer Market Share and Survival When Specialized Assets Retain Their Value. Strategic Management Journal, 12 85-100. 33 Morck, R., A. Shleifer, R. W. Vishny. 1988. Management Ownership and Market Valuation. Journal of Financial Economics, 20 293-315. Morck, R., B. Yeung. 1991. Why Investors Value Multinationality. Journal of Business, 64 165187. Oil and Gas Journal. 1990. Tengiz holds promise, problems for Soviets. June 18, 1990 20. Pacheco-de-Almeida, G., E. J. Henderson, K. O. Cool. 2008. Resolving the Commitment versus Flexibility Trade-off: The Role of Resource Accumulation Lags. Academy of Management Journal, 51 56 pp. Pacheco-de-Almeida, G., P. Zemsky. 2007. The Timing of Resource Development and Sustainable Competitive Advantage. Management Science, 53 651-666. Revelt, D., K. Train. 1998. Mixed Logit with Repeated Choices: Households' Choices of Appliance Efficiency Level. The Review of Economic and Statistics, 80 647-657. Salomon, R., X. Martin. 2008. Learning, Knowledge Transfer, and Technology Implementation Performance: A Study of ‘Time-to-Build’ in the Global Semiconductor Industry. Management Science, 54 32. Scherer, F. M. 1967. Research and Development Resource Allocation Under Rivalry. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 3 367-391. Scherer, F. M. 1984. Innovation and Growth. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Shleifer, A., R. W. Vishny. 1997. A Survey of Corporate Governance. The Journal of Finance, 52 737-783. Smith, P. G., D. G. Reinertsen. 1998. Developing Products in Half the Time. John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York. Spletter, K. G., W. P. Ruwe, P. J. Killen. 2002. Muse, Stancil & Co.'s Monthly Gulf Coast Ethylene Margins. Oil and Gas Journal 46-49. Stalk, G. 1988. Time - The Next Source of Competitive Advantage. Harvard Business Review, 66 41-51. Stalk, G., T. M. Hout. 1990. Competing Against Time. The Free Press, New York, NY. Stell, J. 2003. E&C contractors face tight margins, more risk. Oil and Gas Journal 20. Teece, D. J. 2007. Explicating Dynamic Capabilities: The Nature and Microfoundations of (Sustainable) Enterprise Performance. Strategic Management Journal. Teece, D. J., G. Pisano, A. Shuen. 1997. Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic Management. Strategic Management Journal, 18 509-533. Train, K. 1998. Recreation Demand Models with Taste Differences over People. Land Economics, 74 230-239. Train, K. 2003. Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, MA. Waldman, P. 1986. Hewlett-Packard, Citing Software Snag, Will Delay New Computer Six Months, Wall Street Journal: 2: Dow Jones, Inc. Waring, G. F. 1996. Industry differences in the persistence of firm-specific returns. American Economic Review, 86 1253-1265. Wiggins, R. R., T. W. Ruefli. 2002. Sustained Competitive Advantage: Temporal Dynamics and the Incidence and Persistence of Superior Economic Performance. Organization Science, 13 82-105. Wiggins, R. R., T. W. Ruefli. 2005. Schumpeter's Ghost: Is Hypercompetition Making the Best of Times Shorter? Strategic Management Journal 887-911. 34 Firm Speed Project Speed (Standardized, Reverse-Coded) 500 Industry Average 450 Faster Slower 400 350 300 Absolute Frequency 250 200 150 100 50 0 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 Standard Deviations in Speed Μ )/ππ’,π‘ Figure 1: Firm speed (Θπ,π‘ ) and standardized, reverse-coded project speed −(ππ,π’,π‘ − ππ’,π‘ Amoco AT Plastics BP Chevron China Petroleum & Chem CNOOC Conoco Inc ConocoPhillips Dow Chemical E.ON Eastman Chemical Elf Aquitaine ENI Exxon Mobil Fina Frontier Oil Holly IMC Global Jilin Chem Indl Lyondell Chemical Mapco Marathon Oil Methanex Mississippi Chemical Mobil Murphy Oil Nova Chemicals Occidental Petroleum Petrobras Brasileiro Petro-Canada PetroCorp PPG Industries Premcor Rohm and Haas RAG AG Shell Sinopec Shanghai Petrochem Solutia Suncor Energy Sunoco Terra Industries Tesoro Texaco Tosco Total Ultramar Diamond Shamrock Union Carbide Union Texas Petro Valero Energy Wellman Westlake Chemical 35 0.6 0.4 0.2 Firm Speed Parameters 0 -0.2 -0.4 Company Figure 2: Firm specific speed coefficients from random parameter estimation of model (2) 36 Table 1a: Descriptive statistics and correlation matrices for first stage regression: complete sample Variable Number of Observations = 2,659 Mean S.D. Minimum Maximum 1. 2. 3. 4. 1. Tf ,i ,t 20.796 14.584 3.033 108.767 1.000 2. EBIDA 0.128 0.011 0.109 0.151 0.086 1.000 3. WACC 0.050 0.012 0.032 0.074 0.018 0.936 1.000 4. GDP Rate 0.041 0.039 -0.131 0.179 0.066 0.294 0.286 1.000 5. Capacity (106 units) 0.307 4.694 0.000 182.5 -0.007 -0.026 -0.013 -0.004 5. 1.000 Table 1b: Descriptive statistics and correlation matrices for second stage regression: Blockholders sample Variable Number of Observations = 151 Mean S.D. Minimum Maximum 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 1. Tobin’s q 1.306 0.504 0.276 3.003 1.000 2. Speed 0.047 0.752 -1.626 1.991 0.124 1.000 3. Blockholding 11.975 13.476 0.000 50.293 -0.125 0.058 1.000 4. R&D Intensity 0.007 0.012 0.000 0.052 0.171 0.087 0.155 1.000 5. Leverage 0.213 0.118 0.012 0.637 -0.371 0.044 0.527 -0.036 1.000 4. 5. Table 1c: Descriptive statistics and correlation matrices for second stage regression: S&P Score sample Variable Number of Observations = 198 Mean S.D. Minimum Maximum 1. 2. 3. 1. Tobin’s q 1.247 0.526 0.447 3.102 1.000 2. Speed 0.072 0.760 -1.281 2.732 0.040 1.000 3. S&P Score 59.005 17.785 18.000 84.000 0.302 -0.113 1.000 4. R&D Intensity 0.007 0.013 0.000 0.069 0.068 0.048 0.237 1.000 5. Leverage 0.183 0.113 0.000 0.517 -0.230 0.058 -0.385 -0.130 1.000 37 Table 2: First stage multivariate OLS regression results Variable Refineries Subsample Complete Sample WACC EBIDA WACC EBIDA Constant 1.924*** (0.140) 1.714*** (0.084) 2.091*** (0.190) 1.905*** (0.100) Capacity (ln) 0.034*** (0.013) 0.016** (0.007) 0.053*** (0.008) 0.021*** (0.004) Complexity (ln) 0.034* (0.019) 0.015 (0.011) β† β† GDP Rate -0.863** (0.429) -0.778*** (0.256) -0.553* (0.331) -0.515*** (0.174) Yes Yes Yes Yes 1,357 1,357 2,659 2,659 10.72*** 9.59*** 17.33*** 10.79*** 0.120 0.109 0.106 0.069 0.109 0.097 0.100 0.062 Industry Dummies Number of Observations F-test for Model R2 2 Adjusted R Table 3: Second stage results using OLS robust to clustering by firm Model 1 Model 3 Model 2 Model 4 WACC EBIDA WACC EBIDA WACC EBIDA WACC E 1.374*** (0.247) 1.312*** (0.244) 1.833*** (0.103) 1.239*** (0.251) 1.369*** (0.247) 1.677*** (0.136) 1.954*** (0.422) 1 (0 0.077** (0.032) 0.083** (0.032) 0.073** (0.033) 0.079** (0.034) 0.085* (0.048) 0 (0 0.003 (0.005) 0 (0 ing nsity 11.357*** (4.008) 12.268*** (3.958) 11.547*** (3.837) 12.544*** (3.774) 10.795*** (3.847) 11.695*** (3.764) 11.631** (5.400) 1 (4 -1.079** (0.512) -0.967* (0.527) -1.107** (0.527) -0.990* (0.546) -1.052* (0.566) -0.928 (0.585) -1.328* (0.689) -1 (0 g Intensity -7.446 (21.727) -7.182 (21.799) -8.962 (18.291) -8.819 (18.083) -6.550 (18.850) -6.687 (18.607) ummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Y Yes Yes Yes Y mies Observations hood R2 222 224 222 224 222 224 151 1 -102.344 -105.163 -99.878 -102.315 -96.293 -98.299 -78.123 -7 0.371 0.380 0.385 0.395 0.405 0.417 0.339 0 0.315 0.325 0.327 0.339 0.319 0.333 0.225 0 55.785*** 2 d Ratio λ OLS, ο£ 2 16 ) le ant holding ntensity Table 4: Second stage results using random parameter model with freely correlated coefficients Elements of Γ Mean Constant Speed Blockholding 1.632*** (0.103) 0.525*** (0.031) 0.112*** (0.018) 0.051*** (0.019) 0.143*** (0.020) 0.004*** (0.002) -0.000 (0.001) -0.017*** (0.002) 0.003* (0.001) 8.268*** -8.378*** 8.156*** -0.181 S.D R&D Intensity Leverage 0.525 (0.03 0.152 (0.02 0.017 (0.00 1.687 11.815 age (1.806) (1.275) (1.554) (1.261) (1.185) -0.943*** (0.179) -1.238*** (0.149) 1.574*** (0.113) -0.585*** (0.102) -0.403*** (0.065) ry Dummies Yes Dummies Yes er of Observations 151 kelihood (1.46 0.135** (0.058) -50.230 Table 5: Implied covariance matrix of random parameters Variable Constant Speed Blockholding R&D Intensity Leverage ‡ Constant β Speed 0.027*** (0.010) β‡ Blockholding -0.000 (0.000) -0.002*** (0.000) β‡ R&D Intensity -4.396*** (0.799) 0.742*** (0.306) -0.137*** (0.034) β‡ Leverage -0.650*** (0.110) 0.162*** (0.043) -0.028*** (0.004) 22.631*** (3.579) β‡ 2.129 (0.12 APPENDIX Appendix I -- Derivation of Optimal Development Time In our model, the benefits of speed for firm j in industry i depend on project revenues. Once a new oil and gas facility f is brought on line (from π‘ = ππ,π’,π‘ to π‘ = ∞), the firm earns, net of all operation costs, revenue flows βπ,π’,π‘ , where βπ,π’,π‘ > 0. Without loss of generality, we assume πΎ that revenue flows are time-invariant so that βπ,π’,π‘ = (βΜ π,π’ ) (where parameter πΎ is proportional to the revenue elasticity of development time) and are sufficiently high to give firms incentive to develop the new oil and gas facility.19 The costs of speed exhibit time compression diseconomies; that is, a firm’s cash outlay for its investment project at each point in time, ππ‘ , is subject to diminishing returns such that each plant’s incremental development only progresses at a rate (ππ‘ )πΌ for some πΌ ∈ (0,1). The benefits and costs of faster project development are discounted at the cost of capital π > 0 and defined as follows. We assume that the total amount of progress or effort required to develop a new productive facility by time ππ,π’,π‘ is a Cobb-Douglas function of the technological knowledge πΎπ,π’,π‘ and equipment πΈπ,π’,π‘ needed to build a plant, as well as of a firm’s speed capability, ππ,π’,π‘ , such π π½0 π½1 that the cumulative development ∫0 π,π’,π‘(ππ‘ )πΌ ππ‘ is equal to π΄(1 − ππ,π’,π‘ ) (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) π½2 where π΄ > 0 and π½0 , π½1 , π½2 ≥ 0. For tractability, we set πΌ = 1/2.20 19 This strong but simplifying assumption about the certain and steady nature of revenue flows is not too extreme as oil and gas is a mature industry during the period of analysis (1996-2005). 20 We measure heterogeneity in speed capabilities by changes in ππ,π’,π‘ – not in πΌ – for three main reasons. First, in our model, firms’ ability to experience lower diminishing returns (πΌ) during an investment project does not necessarily allow them to develop plants more quickly. This analytical property results from the specific functional form assumed for diminishing returns in our paper. In contrast, larger values of ππ,π’,π‘ , denoting superior (in)tangible resources that confer firms a head start or a greater ability in plant development, have the desired effect of accelerating firms’ investments. Second, the alternative approach of letting πΌ vary by firm is econometrically unappealing, as it produces an intrinsically nonlinear model for which there is not an obvious estimation strategy. The decision to parameterize πΌ = 1/2 renders the model substantially more tractable. Finally, most anecdotal evidence in the specialized press appears to attribute speed capabilities to firms’ initial resource endowments, rather than to variance in diminishing returns to investment. Firms’ first choose the investment profile ππ‘ (ππ‘ ≥ 0) that minimizes the net present value of investment subject to the constraint that all effort required to build a new productive facility is exerted by the completion time ππ,π’,π‘ . Investments at each point in time are subject to diminishing returns such that each plant development project only progresses at a rate (ππ‘ )πΌ (0 ≤ πΌ ≤ 1). The total amount of progress or effort required to develop a new productive facility is π½0 π½1 given by π΄(1 − ππ,π’,π‘ ) (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) π½2 (where π΄ > 0; π½0 , π½1 , π½2 ≥ 0). Thus, firms’ investment problem is given by ππ,π’,π‘ πΆ(ππ,π’,π‘ ) = min ∫ ππ‘ ≥0 0 ππ‘ π −ππ‘ ππ‘ π½0 π π½1 π½2 π . π‘. ∫0 π,π’,π‘ (ππ‘ )πΌ ππ‘ = π΄(1 − ππ,π’,π‘ ) (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) . Following Lucas (1971) and Pacheco-de-Almeida and Zemsky (2007), the cost minimizing investment profile for a general πΌ is ππ‘∗ (ππ,π’,π‘ ) = π ππ‘/(1−πΌ) π½0 π½1 π½2 πΌ π΄(1−ππ,π’,π‘ ) (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) π (1−πΌ π πππ,π’,π‘ πΌ/(1−πΌ) −1 1/πΌ ) . The present value of plant investment costs is π given by (ππ,π’,π‘ ) = ∫0 π,π’,π‘ ππ‘∗ (ππ,π’,π‘ )π −ππ‘ ππ‘ , which is equivalent to expression πΆπ,π’,π‘ = π΄2 (1−ππ,π’,π‘ ) 2π½0 (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) 2π½1 π πππ,π’,π‘ −1 (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) 2π½2 π when πΌ = 1/2. This is the cost curve we work with. ∞ Firm revenues are given by π π,π’,π‘ = ∫π π,π’,π‘ βπ,π’,π‘ π −ππ‘ ππ‘ = βπ,π’,π‘ π π −πππ,π’,π‘ . For tractability πΎ reasons, we assume that βπ,π’,π‘ = (βΜ π,π’ ) . Since our model of investment speed is conditional on firms’ decision to invest in a new production facility in industry π’ at time π‘, we further impose πΎ π½0 π½1 π½2 that √(βΜ π,π’ ) > π΄(1 − ππ,π’,π‘ ) (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) π, so that firms have enough incentives to develop the new production facility. Because project costs are empirically unobservable in our oil and gas industry sample, we develop a reduced-form model based on firms’ optimal project development time. Firm profits are given by Ππ,π’,π‘ = π π,π’,π‘ − πΆπ,π’,π‘ . A profit-optimizing firm chooses the project development completion time that maximizes the difference between the benefits and costs of speed. Hence, πΠ ∗ the FOC for the optimal development time ππ,π’,π‘ is πππ,π’,π‘ = 0, or π,π’,π‘ πΎ 2π½0 2π½1 2π½2 −(βΜ π,π’ ) π −πππ,π’,π‘ + π΄2 (1 − ππ,π’,π‘ ) (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) π 2 ln π₯ π where π₯ > 1 yields π₯−1 π₯ = π½ π½ π½ π΄(1−ππ,π’,π‘ ) 0 (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) 1 (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) 2 π √(βΜ π,π’ ) πΎ π πππ,π’,π‘ (π ππ,π’,π‘ −1) 2 = 0. Substituting ππ,π’,π‘ = ∗ , which solves for a unique ππ,π’,π‘ , −1 1 ∗ ππ,π’,π‘ = π ln (1 − π΄(1−ππ,π’,π‘ ) π½0 (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) √(βΜ π,π’ ) π½1 πΎ (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) π½2 π ) . This is equivalent to having ∗ ln πΜπ,π’,π‘ = ln π΄ + π½0 ln(1 − ππ,π’,π‘ ) + π½1 ln πΎπ,π’,π‘ + π½2 ln πΈπ,π’,π‘ + π½3 ln βΜ π,π’ ∗ πΎ ∗ , where πΜπ,π’,π‘ = (1 − π −πππ,π’,π‘ )/π and π½3 = − 2 . In our current model, we allow for suboptimal acceleration of specific projects. This observation-specific error around the optimal development ∗ time is denoted in our model by ππ,π’,π‘ , such that ln πΜπ,π’,π‘ = ln πΜπ,π’,π‘ + ππ,π’,π‘ and πΜπ,π’,π‘ = 1−π −πππ,π’,π‘ π . By construction, (1 − ππ,π’,π‘ ) = π£π,π’,π‘ (1 − ππ’ ), where π£π,π’,π‘ > 0 is unobservable. Thus, the error term of the final model to estimate in (1) is given by ππ,π’,π‘ = ππ,π’,π‘ + π½0 ln π£π,π’,π‘ and the regression intercept is π½0π’ = ln π΄ + π½0 ln(1 − ππ’ ). Figure 3 shows a numerical example of model (1). The cost curve is downward sloping and convex due to time compression diseconomies. The revenue curve is also downward sloping ∗ because revenue discounting increases in development time. Firms’ optimal time (ππ,π’,π‘ ) maximizes profits (Ππ,π’,π‘ ), or the (vertical) difference between revenues and costs in the figure. The unobservable components of the error term (ππ,π’,π‘ , π£π,π’,π‘ ) affect the model differently: ∗ suboptimization implies deviations from ππ,π’,π‘ ; speed capabilities shift the cost curve inwards Development Revenues and Costs Development Revenues and Costs such that, at the optimum, firms develop projects faster. Suboptimization 2 Revenues 1 Costs 0 2 Tf*,i ,t 4 6 8 Development Time 10 12 14 2 Speed Capabilities 1 0 2 Tf*,i ,t 4 6 8 Development Time 10 12 14 Figure 3: Suboptimal acceleration and deceleration (left panel) and heterogeneous capabilities (right panel). Parameter values: π = 0.1, π΄ = 1, πΎπ,π’,π‘ = πΈπ,π’,π‘ = 4, π½0 = π½1 = π½2 = 0.1, πΎ = 1, ππ,π’,π‘ = 0 (left panel) versus ππ,π’,π‘ = 0.90. Appendix II – Derivation of the Effect of Speed on Performance ∗ Model (1) Denote by ππ’,π‘ the optimal plant development time for an average firm in the ∗ industry (with average speed capabilities ππ’ ) and by Π∗π’,π‘ = Ππ’,π‘ (ππ’,π‘ ) the resulting industry ∗ average profits. As in Appendix I, ππ,π’,π‘ denotes the optimal time for a specific project when firms ∗ have speed capabilities ππ,π’,π‘ , where the corresponding profits are Π∗π,π’,π‘ = Ππ,π’,π‘ (ππ,π’,π‘ ). Then, the performance impact of project deviations in development time (ππ,π’,π‘ ) from the industry average ∗ (ππ’,π‘ , as on average oil firms are assumed to optimize) is given by the following identity ∗ Ππ,π’,π‘ = Ππ’,π‘ + (Π∗π,π’,π‘ − Π∗π’,π‘ ) + (Ππ,π’,π‘ − Π∗π,π’,π‘ ) ∗ , where (Ππ,π’,π‘ − Π∗π’,π‘ ) is the change in optimal profits resulting from a change in the level of speed capabilities relative to the industry average, and the term (Ππ,π’,π‘ − Π∗π,π’,π‘ ) measures the change in profits due to suboptimization. ∗ ∗ A first-order approximation to the second term in the above equation is (Ππ,π’,π‘ − Ππ’,π‘ )≈ πΠ∗ π½ π πΎ 0 ∗ πΠπ,π’,π‘ /πππ,π’,π‘ (βππ,π’,π‘ ). We have that πππ,π’,π‘ = 2 (1−π ) ((βΜ π,π’ )2 − ππ) > 0, where π = π,π’,π‘ π½0 π½1 π,π’,π‘ π½2 π΄(1 − ππ,π’,π‘ ) (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) . Since ππ,π’,π‘ = 0 (i.e., there is no suboptimization), βππ,π’,π‘ = ππ,π’,π‘ − ππ’ = (1 − ππ’ )(1 − π£π,π’,π‘ ) and π£π,π’,π‘ = π ππ,π’,π‘/π½0 . Given that π½0 ≥ 0, βππ,π’,π‘ is decreasing in ∗ 1 project speed ππ,π’,π‘ . Therefore, we can re-write (Ππ,π’,π‘ − Π∗π’,π‘ ) ≈ πΏπ,π’,π‘ (− Μ π’,π‘ ππ,π’,π‘ −π ππ’,π‘ 1 ), where πΏπ,π’,π‘ = πΏ 1 + ζ1π,π’,π‘ > 0 . Specifically, πΏ 1 is the common-mean coefficient across all projects and ζ1π,π’,π‘ is a random term that varies with observable and unobservable project-specific characteristics (consistently with πΠ∗π,π’,π‘ /πππ,π’,π‘ ). Project speed ππ,π’,π‘ is reverse coded and standardized relative Μ = ∑π to its industry π’ at time π‘, ππ’,π‘ ππ,π’,π‘ ππ’,π‘ 2 1/2 and ππ’,π‘ = [∑π(ππ,π’,π‘ − ππ’,π‘ ) /(ππ’,π‘ − 1)] (ππ’,π‘ is the total number of projects in industry π’ at time π‘), which allows for a meaningful comparison of speed deviations between identical projects.21 By definition, the third term in the above expression is always negative and decreasing in ∗ the extent of suboptimization. In addition, the FOC for the optimal development time ππ,π’,π‘ in Although model (1) includes industry dummies, πΜ π’,π‘ may not be zero because of time effects (or interactions between product, geography, and time effects), which are not part of our model specification. Even when πΜ π’,π‘ = 0, the overall distribution of project development times may vary substantially across industries (and time periods) and, thus, the same absolute speed deviation can have very different impacts on performance in distinct industries. 21 πΠ appendix I, πππ,π’,π‘ = 0, suggests that identical suboptimal deviations may have different effects on π,π’,π‘ profits depending on project-specific characteristics. If we assume that symmetric suboptimal deviations (i.e., suboptimal accelerations and decelerations of equivalent absolute magnitudes) ∗ 2 have an identical impact on profits, we can re-write (Ππ,π’,π‘ − Ππ,π’,π‘ ) ≈ πΏπ,π’,π‘ (−|ππ,π’,π‘ |), where 2 πΏπ,π’,π‘ = πΏ 2 + ζ2π,π’,π‘ > 0. In particular, πΏ 2 is the common-mean coefficient across all projects and οΊ f2,i ,t is a random term that varies with observable and unobservable project-specific characteristics (consistently with πΠπ,π’,π‘ /πππ,π’,π‘ ).22 Therefore, the above identity can be proxied by 1 0 Ππ,π’,π‘ = πΏπ’,π‘ + πΏπ,π’,π‘ (− Μ ππ,π’,π‘ − ππ’,π‘ 2 ) + πΏπ,π’,π‘ (−|ππ,π’,π‘ |) + ππ,π’,π‘ ππ’,π‘ 0 , where πΏπ’,π‘ are industry (product, geography) and time dummies plus a random constant term, and ππ,π’,π‘ is a mean-zero i.i.d. stochastic error term. Consistent with our theory, the coefficient 1 πΏπ,π’,π‘ captures the effect of firms’ speed capabilities on performance because optimization is controlled for in the model. Our model cannot be directly estimated because we do not empirically observe profits and timing optimization at the project (i.e., oil plant) level in our oil and gas industry sample. However, performance data and reliable proxies for organizational (sub)optimization exist at the firm level since most oil companies are publicly traded. Therefore, we average over the ππ,π‘ 22 In the context of our model, the assumption that suboptimal accelerations and decelerations of equivalent absolute magnitudes have an identical impact on project profits is only reasonable for small to moderate levels of suboptimization. For severe suboptimization, acceleration erodes profits more rapidly than deceleration (e.g., at the limit, a 100% deviation from the optimal development time reduces profits to lim Ππ,π’,π‘ = −∞ with acceleration, ππ,π’,π‘ →0 whereas we have that profits with deceleration are lim ∗ ππ,π’,π‘ →2ππ,i,π‘ Ππ,π’,π‘ > 0). This asymmetric effect of severe suboptimization on performance may be accommodated by the random project term ζ2π,π’,π‘ . In particular, for equal 2 levels of severe suboptimization, projects that are accelerated should have a higher coefficient πΏπ,π’,π‘ than projects that are decelerated. projects of firm π completed at time π‘ across all industries to derive the firm-level random parameter model (2), where Ππ,π‘ = ∑π,π Ππ,π’,π‘ /ππ,π‘ , Θπ,π‘ = − (∑π,π’ Μ π’,π‘ ππ,π’,π‘ −π ππ’,π‘ ) /ππ,π‘ , and Λπ,π‘ = π₯ −(∑π,π|ππ,π’,π‘ |)/ππ,π‘ . Note that this transformation assumes that each random coefficient πΏπ,π’,π‘ (π₯ = 1,2) is time-invariant and independently distributed of its corresponding explanatory π₯ π₯ variable, so that πΏππ₯ = πΏπ,π‘ = ∑π,π’ πΏπ,π’,π‘ /ππ,π‘ , ∀π‘ . The latter assumption is reasonable in the context of our theoretical model for two reasons. First, the effect of speed capabilities on project profits 2 depends ambiguously on the level of firms’ speed capabilities (analytically, π 2 Π∗π,π’,π‘ /π(ππ,π’,π‘ ) = 2π½0 π (1−ππ,π’,π‘ ) 2 πΎ (√(βΜ π,π’ ) (1 + π½0 ) − ππ(1 + 2π½0 )) , which may be positive or negative). Second, the effect of suboptimization on profits should not depend on the level of suboptimization because it is unlikely that any one oil firm in our sample systematically pursued severe suboptimization across all of its projects from 1996 to 2005. 18 Appendix III – Additional Discussion of Random Parameter Model The RPM regression allows for unidentified or unobserved differences between firms to influence the correlation between the model coefficients. Below, we focus on the correlations between the parameters associated with (a) firms’ speed capabilities and leverage and (b) firms’ speed capabilities and organizational optimization. Unobserved firm heterogeneity in discount rates (due to, for instance, differences in firms’ financial leverage) affects the incentives to and the returns from speed. Specifically, π½0 π½1 π΄(1 − ππ,π’,π‘ ) (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) (πΈπ,π’,π‘ ) π½2 ∗ πππ,π’,π‘ ππ = (−π ∗ ππf,i,π‘ /π) ππ −ππ∗f,i,π‘ ππ > 0 as ππ −ππ∗f,i,π‘ ππ =− π √(βΜ f,i ) < 0 (where = ) and, thus, firms take a longer time to develop investment projects with higher discount rates. Also, π2 Π∗π,π’,π‘ the returns from speed capabilities decrease in firms’ discount rate, as given by the following cross-partial derivative (ππ π,π’,π‘ ππ) 2π½ π 2 0 − (1−π π,π’,π‘ ) = < 0. The reason for both results is that long-term project revenues are more heavily discounted than shorter-term project development costs with higher discount rates. Since firms’ with greater leverage typically have larger discount rates and, thus, decreasing returns from additional debt, the random parameters associated with firms’ speed capabilities and leverage should co-vary positively in random parameter model (2). 19 The random parameters πΏπ1 and πΏπ2 are expected to co-vary negatively by default. Increments to organizational optimization improve firm value less (πΏπ2 is lower) the closer firms are to the optimum (by definition). But with superior levels of organizational optimization, enhancements in a firm’s speed capabilities should result in greater performance improvements (πΏπ1 is higher). Note, however, that this negative baseline correlation could hypothetically be mitigated or reversed by other patterns of unobserved firm heterogeneity. An example follows. In the unlikely event that different oil firms pursued projects that systematically differed in complexity and revenue impact, the parameters πΏπ1 and πΏπ2 would co-vary positively (note that complexity and variation in project revenue potential per location are unobserved in our sample). Specifically, suboptimization and inferior speed capabilities should erode value more for firms pursuing projects with larger revenue potential and greater complexity, whereas smaller and simpler projects should have less impact on firms’ financial performance. This inference is also supported by our model. Assume that πΎ √(βΜ π,π’ ) = η(ππ), where η > 1 is constant across projects. This assumption allows us to compare the effects of suboptimization and speed capabilities on performance with simultaneous heterogeneity in project complexity (πΎπ,π’,π‘ ) and revenue potential (βΜ π,π’ ).23 We have π2 Π∗π,π’,π‘ (πππ,π’,π‘ ππΎπ,π’,π‘ =4 ) π½0 π½1 π 2 (η−1)π (1−ππ,π’,π‘ )πΎπ,π’,π‘ π2 Ππ,π’,π‘ > 0. Also, (ππ π,π’,π‘ ππΎπ,π’,π‘ 2π½1 πΠπ,π’,π‘ , π,π’,π‘ πππ,π’,π‘ =πΎ ) ∗ which is positive if and only if ππ,π’,π‘ < ππ,π’,π‘ (negative otherwise). Hence, superior speed capabilities and timing optimization should have a greater impact on performance in 1 projects that are technologically more complex and have higher revenue potential. This means that the random coefficients πΏπ,π’,π‘ and 23 We can only compare the effect of suboptimization (i.e., deviations from the optimal development time) across different projects if the optimal development time is identical for all projects, which holds if η is project-invariant. 20 2 πΏπ,π’,π‘ should co-vary positively. Therefore, if in our dataset different firms were to pursue projects that systematically differed in complexity and revenue impact, the parameters πΏπ1 and πΏπ2 should also co-vary positively in random parameter model (2). While this has shown not to be the case in our setting, this is a concrete example of the advantages of using a random parameter model specification to capture unobserved firm heterogeneity. 21