FORUM 2 CON BLOCKS (A2 pro args) 1 TABLE OF CONTENTS A2: Businesses will migrate A2 Protecting against corruption with injected competition A2 Tourism A2: New revenue A2: Pub subs necessary A2: Stadium Subsides work A2: Subs. Create jobs A2: Boosts the Economy A/2 Economic Sense in Subsidies A2: Multiplier Effect A2: Disaster Relief/Katrina A2 Comparison of two different worlds A2: Civic Pride A/2 Neighborhoods benefitted A2: Stadiums increase sex trafficking A2 Stadiums Decrease Violence A2: Gentrification ·A2 No Monetary Cost A2: Environment A2: Property value/ Eminent D A2 Charities A2 Ballet 2 A2: Businesses will migrate 1.There isn't evidence or any reason on why businesses would want to migrate because of sports John Siegfried and Andrew Zimbalist, “The Economics of Sports Facilities and Their Communities”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2000, Pg. 98 http://www.uwlax.edu/faculty/anderson/micro-principles/stadiums.pdf The part of the contention that is not plausible is the notion that businesses will relocate to the city because it becomes “big league.” Sound businesses move in search of a more qualified or less expensive labor force, a convenient location for inputs or sales, a good infrastructure, a sound fiscal environment with amenable tax policy, attractive government services, and appealing cultural opportunities. The latter may include the quality of the local theater, opera, symphony, parks, art museums, hospitals, public schools, universities or sports teams. If the first half dozen or so items are equivalent between two cities, then the business may look at cultural amenities and within them may consider sports. It does not seem plausible that the presence or absence of sports teams would be a decisive location factor for more than a few companies. There is no systematic evidence that business relocations follow sports teams. 2. Not true Robert A Baade, “Stadiums, Professional Sports, and Economic Development: Assessing the Reality”, Heartland Institute, April 4, 1994 3 http://heartland.org/sites/all/modules/custom/heartland_migration/files/pdfs/3075.pdf “found no connection between professional sports and manufacturing activity in approximately 90 percent of the tests conducted for a number of cities in the United States. It is likely that other factors, such as the tax environment and the existence of a skilled labor force, determine business location to a far greater extent than the presence of professional sports. “ 4 A2 Protecting against corruption with injected competition 1. Unlikely this would work John Siegfried and Andrew Zimbalist, “The Economics of Sports Facilities and Their Communities”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2000, Pg. 98 http://www.uwlax.edu/faculty/anderson/micro-principles/stadiums.pdf “ New entry would introduce competition to the monopoly sports leagues, but it is unlikely. Many have tried, but few have succeeded (Quirk and Fort, 1992, chs. 8–9). The successes came primarily in the 1960s and 1970s, after a long period during which franchise expansion in the major sports leagues failed to keep pace with population growth, and in the midst of rapidly increasing demand for sports entertainment fueled by the coming of sports interest age of the post-World War II baby boomers and the expansion of access to television. Those were days before astronomical broadcast rights contracts and stadium subsidies had driven players’ salaries beyond the realm of normal incomes, and before the leagues realized that they could restrict the number of franchises so much as to attract an entire new league. Today it would be difficult, if not impossible, for a new league to successfully enter any of the four major team sports, and individual teams cannot enter without the cooperation of incumbents because they would have no one to play.” 5 A2 Tourism 1.Tourism won't increase. Brad R. Humpherys, Dennis Coates, “Professional Sports Facilities, Franchises Economic Development”, UMBC Economics Department, 2013 and Urban Impact analysis studies also claim that a new sports facility will attract new visitors to a city, leading to additional economic benefits. Visitors attracted by a new sports facility may occupy hotel rooms and eat meals that would have been purchased by visitors who came to to the city for other reasons, and the direct spending on sport made by these visitors would have gone to other entertainment establishments. Porter (1999) and Porter and Fletcher (2002) report little or no increase in hotel occupancy rates, retail sales, or airport traffic in cities that hosted Super Bowls and Olympic Games in the U.S. in the past ten years. 6 A2: New revenue 1. Theoretically true but not in reality Joseph L Bast, “Sports Stadium Madness Why It Started ò How To Stop It”, The Heartland Institute, Feb 23 1998, pg 9 A stadium would indeed generate “new money” for a metropolitan area if it attracted a significant percent of its fans from outside the immediate area. This is generally not the case for baseball and basketball, where “the number and frequency of games means that most of the market for ticket sales is metropolitan.” Football games, because there are fewer of them and they are scheduled on 22 weekends, draw fans from greater distances. However, the small number of football games—just eight regular season home games— means the total number of fans attending football games is much smaller than the number attending baseball or basketball games. !!!!!!2. A Study by Robert Baade examined the impact of stadiums on the local economy of 30 major cities. Robert A Baade, “Stadiums, Professional Sports, and Economic Development: Assessing the Reality”, Heartland Institute, April 4, 1994 http://heartland.org/sites/all/modules/custom/heartland_migration/files/pdfs/3075.pdf Of the 30 MSAs where there was a change in the number of stadiums or arenas ten years old or less, 27 MSAs showed no significant relationship between the presence of a 7 stadium and real, trend-adjusted, per capita personal income growth. In all three of the remaining cases (St. Louis, San Francisco/Oakland, and Washington D.C.), the presence of a sports stadium was significantly negative) 3, No new money Aaron Gordon, “America Has A Stadium Problem”, Pacific Standard, July 17 2013, Most fans do not spend additional money as a result of a new stadium; they redirect money they would have spent elsewhere on movies, dining, bowling, tarot-card reading, or other businesses. And for every out-of-state fan who comes into the city on game day and buys a bucket of Bud Light Platinum, another non-fan decides not to visit and purchases his latte at the coffee shop next door. All in all, building a stadium is a poor use of a few hundred million dollars. 8 A2: Pub subs necessary 1. Most people prefer to watch sports on TV Teena Hammond, “Stadiums race to digitize: How sports teams are scrambling to keep Millennials coming to games”, Tech Republic, 2013 Teams have faced the reality that it's a lot cheaper, and a lot easier, for a fan to watch the big game in their family room. So the teams have to make it more appealing than ever before to lure fans to the stadium. A recent Cisco study showed that 57% of fans prefer to watch the game at home. 2. Sports orgs would survive without public subs. Journal of Economic Perspectives The Economics of Sports Facilities and Their Communities P101 John Siegfried and Andrew Zimbalist http://www.uwlax.edu/faculty/anderson/micro-principles/stadiums.pdf The struggle over surplus created by professional sports teams is largely an income distribution issue. The transfer of tax revenue to teams by providing them with free stadiums consists primarily of a transfer from taxpayers to players and owners. If all public subsidies to sports teams were eliminated, the existing teams could and would survive. Players’ salaries would decline, perhaps substantially, and teams owners would earn lower profits and capital gains. 9 NEIL DEMAUSE, NPR, (August 05, 2011) “The Nation: Stop The Subsidy-Sucking Sports Stadiums”: http://www.npr.org/2011/08/05/139018592/the-nation-stop-the-subsidy-suckingsports-stadiums Actually losing a team, though, is extremely rare. Most team owners prefer to keep plugging for new stadiums in their hometowns even after their bluff has been called. Florida Marlins president David Samson first declared in 2004 that a new stadium bill "has to happen in the next week. And if not, we'll move on." He repeated similar threats for four years, until the city of Miami and Miami-Dade County finally agreed to kick in more than $478 million for a new stadium with a retractable roof.” 10 A2: Stadium Subsides work 1. Stadiums do not support subsidies Dennis Coates and Brad R. Humphreys, “Do Economists Reach a Conclusion on Sub- sidies for Sports Franchises, Stadiums, and Mega-Events?” Econ Journal Watch, 2008. Pg. 300 “ Within the promotional literature, proponents of stadium subsidies argue that subsidies are warranted because of the local economic development benefits of building a stadium or arena, including the “big league city” benefits. They do not support subsidies based on the consumer surplus derived by game attendance nor from consumer external benefits from such activities as talking about the teams or following them through the print or broadcast media.” 11 A2: Subs. Create jobs (IN CASE 1ST CARD) 1. Not true, Jonah Chodosh, “Take Me Out of the Ball Game: The Efficacy of Public Subsidies in the Success of Professional Sports Stadiums”, Claremont McKenna College, 2011, Pg.6 “Public subsidies for stadiums don’t seem to do as promised, as the “spin-off development” from construction doesn’t display the wishful trickle-down returns. Most jobs are transferred, rather than created, and income and wealth effects are menial, misinterpreted, and misleading” (IN CASE 3RD) (TURN) 3. Job loss Dennis Coates and Bra2. The jobs that are created pay very little and the influx of money going towards new stadiums. Aaron Gordon, “America Has A Stadium Problem”, Pacific Standard, July 17 2013, Economists have long known stadiums to be poor public investments. Most of the jobs created by stadium-building projects are either temporary, low-paying, or out-of-state contracting jobs—none of which contribute greatly to the local economy. (Athletes can easily circumvent most taxes in the state in which they play.) d R. Humphreys (CATO Institute). “Caught Stealing: Debunking the Economic Case for DC Baseball.” 12 The presence of pro sports teams had a statistically significant negative impact on the retail and services sectors of the local economy. The average effect on employment in the services sector of a city’s economy was a net loss of 1,924 jobs as a result of the presence of a professional sports team. [WARRANT: FRANCHISE RELOCATION AND LOWER WAGES] 13 A2: Boosts the Economy 1. No economic help Andrew Zimbalist and Roger G. Noll, The Brookings Institution, Summer 1997, Sports, Jobs, & Taxes: Are New Stadiums Worth the Cost? http://www.brookings.edu/research/articles/1997/06/summer-taxes-noll In our forthcoming Brookings book, Sports, Jobs, and Taxes, we and 15 collaborators examine the local economic development argument from all angles: case studies of the effect of specific facilities, as well as comparisons among cities and even neighborhoods that have and have not sunk hundreds of millions of dollars into sports development. In every case, the conclusions are the same. A new sports facility has an extremely small (perhaps even negative) effect on overall economic activity and employment. No recent facility appears to have earned anything approaching a reasonable return on investment. No recent facility has been selffinancing in terms of its impact on net tax revenues. Regardless of whether the unit of analysis is a local neighborhood, a city, or an entire metropolitan area, the economic benefits of sports facilities are de minimus. 2. Quantifies Dennis Coates, professor of economics at the University of Maryland, Baltimore County. Tuesday, April 29, 2008, “A Closer Look at Stadium Subsidies”, The American: The Online Magazine of the American Enterprise Institute. http://www.american.com/archive/2008/april-0408/a-closer-look-at-stadium-subsidies Interestingly, Humphreys and I found that the overall sports environment—which, as mentioned earlier, includes the presence of franchises in multiple sports, the arrival or departure of teams, and stadium construction—in a given area reduced per capita personal income by about $10. In other words, every man, woman, and child in the metropolitan area was poorer by $10 as a result of the sports environment. This suggests that the public-good benefits are worth just enough to pay for the subsidies. Sports economists and policy analysts are using a variety of methods to get more precise estimates of the public-good benefits. In the future, we should know better whether these benefits are sufficient—in combination with private consumption benefits—to cover the public financing of professional sports stadiums. 14 15 A/2 Economic Sense in Subsidies Principles of Economics, 7th Edition 2015 N. Gregory Mankiw Harvard University “85% of economists agree that Local and state governments should eliminate subsidies to professional sports franchises.” 16 A2: Multiplier Effect 1. No real impact According to The North American Association of Sports Economists, http://college.holycross.edu/RePEc/spe/SzymanskiKavetsos_WellBeing.pdf In addition, Siegfried and Zimbalist (2000) note that the multiplier for sports related expenditures may be lower than that of other types of expenditures. This is because sports related expenditures are more likely to leak out of the local economy than non-sports ones (e.g. construction workers may be less likely to live in the local area, and therefore are not expected to spend their income locally) (Matheson and Baade, 2004). 2. Baade concludes multiplier effect fails Community.seattletimes.nwsource.com,. Mariners Stadium -- Study Shows Public Funding Takes From Poor, Gives To Rich | Seattle Times Newspaper'. N. p., 2014. Web. 25 Jun. 2014. What about the multiplier effect? Growth at Boeing and Microsoft creates jobs elsewhere in the economy. Baade and Sanderson say, forget it. "A dollar spent on professional sports rarely constitutes a dollar's worth of new spending within a community. To a large degree, citizens who spend money on sports are simply substituting one leisure option for another." The pie chart and companion article also give the lie to claims that money for the Mariners will not interfere with funding for our schools. Just under 20 percent of public funds will come from the state sales tax, accounting for an estimated $137 million over the next 20 years. This is money that would otherwise have gone into the general fund to finance education, a cleaner environment or possibly even a tax cut.” 17 A2: Disaster Relief/Katrina United Academics/Elke Weesjes/ Surviving Sandy: Staying Put in Far Rockaway/January 31, 2013 “For New Yorkers, this fear of public shelters was likely influenced not only by the lingering memories of Katrina-Superdome horror stories but also by the experiences of people familiar with homeless shelters in New York. Like many other residents of Far Rockaway—where poverty is widespread—Anderson knows a number of people whose circumstances forced them to make use of the city’s shelters. Their negative experiences exacerbated her own fear of shelters, as did her memories of Katrina coverage: “The governor in New Jersey said that if people decided to stay that they [emergency services] weren’t going to get them. People like him have to understand that it isn’t easy to pack up and go somewhere else. There is a real fear of the unknown. We knew there were shelters and that we could go there, but I know what happened after Katrina in the stadium—rapes, muggings, theft; I am not going to walk into that.” 18 A2 Comparison of two different worlds My opponent calls for the comparison of a world with and a world without public subsidies. However, the links and impacts drawn from this become null and void, as the resolution asks for a comparison between benefits and drawbacks, not the conditions of one real-life situation and one hypothetical situation. As Public Forum is a debate in the present tense, I suggest we adhere to what the topic is asking us to engage in discourse about. 19 A2: Civic Pride Dennis Coates and Brad R. Humphreys October 27, 2004. “Caught Stealing: Debunking the Economic Case for D.C. Baseball”, Cato Institute. http://www.cato.org/sites/cato.org/files/pubs/pdf/bp89.pdf A baseball team in D.C. might produce intangible benefits. Residents might have an enhanced sense of community pride and another opportunity to engage in a shared experience of civic expression. Perhaps some people will think that D.C.’s image as a “world-class city” will be further burnished. Rooting for the team will provide satisfaction to many local baseball fans. Yet those intangible benefits largely accrue to people interested in being fans of the baseball team and showing their support by purchasing tickets to games and team paraphernalia. That is hardly a reason for the city government to subsidize construction of a ballpark, or for the baseball team to avoid paying the cost to build it. District policymakers should not be mesmerized by the faulty impact studies that claim a baseball team and new stadium can be an engine of economic growth. 20 A/2 Neighborhoods benefitted 1. Not true Dennis Coates and Brad R. Humphreys. Professional Sports Facilities, Franchises and Urban Economic Development. 2003. However, a growing body of evidence indicates that professional sports facilities, and the franchises they are home to, may not be engines of economic growth in urban neighborhoods. Econometric studies of the determination of income and employment in US cities find no evidence of positive economic benefits associated with past sports facility construction and some studies find that professional sports facilities and teams have a However, a growing body of evidence indicates that professional sports facilities, and the franchises they are home to, may not be engines of economic growth in urban neighborhoods. Econometric studies of the determination of income and employment in US cities find no evidence of positive economic benefits associated with past sports facility construction and some studies find that professional sports facilities and teams have an impact on homes. 21 A2: Stadiums increase sex trafficking 1, Media isn't true Global Alliance Against Traffic in Women Gaatw.org,. 'Super Bowl? Or Super Hyperbole?'. N. p., 2011. Web. 28 Jun. 2014. “GAATW’s 2011 report, What’s the Cost of a Rumour? A guide to sorting out the myths and the facts about sporting events and trafficking, critically analysed this manufactured media hype about the role of Although this always generates a lot of media attention, action by anti-prostitution groups and law enforcement, and funding for anti-trafficking activities by state actors and NGOs, there is no evidence to support the claim.” international sporting events in creating a “demand” for trafficked women and children. 2. Spotlight effect 22 A2 Stadiums Decrease Violence 1.Violence Increase Daniel I. Rees and Kevin T. Schnepel. “College Football Games and Crime”. Journal of Sports Economics 2009. http://www.sagepub.com/lippmanccl2e/study/articles/Rees.pdf The results of this exercise are reported in Table 4. The estimated negative binomial coefficients of Away Game Win it and Away Game Loss it are never statistically signif-icant at conventional levels, a pattern of results that lead us to focus on home games, where there is evidence that losses lead to larger increases in the number of offenses than wins. For instance, home game losses are associated with a 12% increase in assaults, but home game wins are associated with only an 8% increase in assaults. To take another example, home game losses are associated with a 24% increase in DUIs, but home game wins are associated with only a 10% increase in DUIs. However, the results presented in Table 4 do not provide definitive evidence that the outcome of the game matters. In fact, in four of the five cases we cannot reject the hypothesis that estimated negative binomial coefficient of Home Game Lossit is equal to the estimated coefficient of Home Game Win it . Losses at home are associ-ated with more arrests for DUI than wins at the .10 level. 23 A2: Gentrification Why is Gentrification a Problem? - Stephen Sheppard, Williams College, 2011 http://web.williams.edu/Economics/ArtsEcon/library/pdfs/WhyIsGentrificationAProbREF ORM.pdf “The risk of displacement from gentrification was capable of changing the incentives that residents have to engage in any of the variety of activities that can improve a community. The risk of displacement that is characteristic of gentrification imposes a social cost on the neighborhood. This cost is borne by the community as a whole and not by only those persons who are poor or those who are displaced.” No Social Mixing - Are Residents Who Are Displaced by Gentrification Better or Worse Off After Relocating? [Alice M. Anigacz, Macalester College,], 2010 http://digitalcommons.macalester.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1026&context=economics_ho nors_projects “Interviews with long-term residents suggest that there is no or very little social mixing, so that residents cannot benefit from the positive neighborhood effects thatupper-class gentrifiers bring Dennis Coates, The American, April 28,2009, A Closer Look at Stadium Subsidies http://www.american.com/archive/2008/april-04-08/a-closer-look-at-stadium-subsidies “Of course, even if the benefits of stadiums and arenas cover the subsidies, the subsidies still may not be sound policy. First, there may be enormous variation in the distribution of the consumption and public-good benefits. It is clear that not all citizens in a community benefit equally because the tax revenues used for the subsidies are often generated from lotteries and sales taxes whose burden falls disproportionately on the poor, while the consumption benefits go mostly to relatively wealthy sports fans, the net benefits are distributed regressively. Second, we should consider the net from the presence of professional sports franchises in their city. Indeed benefits to the community of alternative uses of the funds spent subsidizing sports facilities. Good policy means using the money where the net benefit is greatest, not simply where the net benefit is positive. That’s something state and local governments should keep in mind before pledging millions of dollars to fund the next new stadium project. And it’s something Congress should remember when evaluating the future of U.S. tax policy. 24 ·A2 No Monetary Cost 1.Subsidies Paid for by New Taxes which Disproportionately Impact the Poor Dennis Coates, The American, April 28,2009, A Closer Look at Stadium Subsidies http://www.american.com/archive/2008/april-04-08/a-closer-look-at-stadium-subsidies It is not quite correct to argue that local governments could use the tax revenues they spend on stadiums in “better” ways, such as on schools or health programs. Typically, the funding for stadiums does not come directly out of an existing government budget but rather from a new source of revenue, like special taxes on tickets or add-ons to the local sales tax. The municipality likely would not impose these taxes for any purpose other than subsidizing the stadium, so other governmental services are not necessarily being shortchanged. (Of course, the increased taxes do reduce the disposable income of local consumers, so the stadium subsidy does impose opportunity costs on citizens, despite having no such effect on the government’s budget.) “Of course, even if the benefits of stadiums and arenas cover the subsidies, the subsidies still may not be sound policy. First, there may be enormous variation in the distribution of the consumption and public-good benefits. It is clear that not all citizens in a community benefit equally from the presence of professional sports franchises in their city. Indeed, because the tax revenues used for the subsidies are often generated from lotteries and sales taxes whose burden falls disproportionately on the poor, while the consumption benefits go mostly to relatively wealthy sports fans, the net benefits are distributed regressively. Second, we should consider the net benefits to the community of alternative uses of the funds spent subsidizing sports facilities. Good policy means using the money where the net benefit is greatest, not simply where the net benefit is positive. That’s something state and local governments should keep in mind before pledging millions of dollars to fund the next new stadium project. And it’s something Congress should remember when evaluating the future of U.S. tax policy.” 25 A2: Environment 1. Idea in which more stadiums though green will still produce more energy than less stadiums 2. econ outweighs 3. private stadiums incentivised to protect the environment to save money. Less energy consumption = $$$$ 3.Not impactful For Eagles, a Winning Mix of Wind, Biodiesel and Solar: Ken Belson, Nov. 2010, NY Times, http://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/18/sports/football/18stadium.html?pagewanted=all&_r=0 As large as they are, sports stadiums consume just a sliver of the nation’s energy and produce a fraction of its waste. But they are seen and used by millions of Americans every day, which [Green energy efforts] has helped leagues counter the perception that sports teams are wasteful enterprises and in fact can convey socially responsible messages to fans of all political and economic stripes. 26 A2: Property value/ Eminent D 20% underappraisal – Eminent Domain is a bad ploy for underwater mortgages [Steven Greenhut], 2012 http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012-06-28/eminent-domain-is-bad-ploy-for-underwater-mortgages.html The “fair market value” probably wouldn’t be based on an expected sales price of the home, but on a wholesale value that would be at least 20 percent lower than that, said Mark Dowling, the chief executive officer of the Inland Valleys Association of Realtors. (The value would probably be based on the fair market value of the mortgage -- the home price minus many transaction costs -and thus far lower than the fair market value of the home itself.) 27 A2 Charities Paula Lavigne, Athlete charities often lack standards, 2013, ESPN http://espn.go.com/espn/otl/story/_/id/9109024/top-athletes-charities-often-measurecharity-experts-say-efficient-effective-use-money. That mystery was heightened by an eye-opening report on Sunday's "Outside the Lines," which found that 74 percent of 115 athlete charities investigated fell short of acceptable nonprofit standards used by the top three charity watchdogs. Paula Lavigne, Athlete charities often lack standards, 2013, ESPN http://espn.go.com/espn/otl/story/_/id/9109024/top-athletes-charities-often-measurecharity-experts-say-efficient-effective-use-money. Some specific examples of what "Outside the Lines" found after conducting interviews and examining documents: NBA forward Lamar Odom's charity that promised money for cancer research has not given a dime in grant money to any cancer entity in its eight-year history. Phone numbers listed for NFL receiver Randy Moss' charities ring to a private residence in the Canadian province of Manitoba. New York Yankees third baseman Alex Rodriguez's two foundations stopped filing tax returns about five years ago, leaving almost $300,000 from a fundraiser unaccounted for. 2: Idea in which you're sprinkling money back to the poor 28 A2 Ballet 1) No reason to look at ballet over all other sports Turn: Ballet is sexist, don’t subsidize ballet Lewis Segal, The Times' dance critic, “The Shape of Things to Come” The LA Times, April 1, 2001 Ballet forces females to accept what society wants them to look like. It tells them that in order achieve perfection, you must deform your body and natural figure that in it of itself is sexist and dangerous Ballet perpetuates female stereotypes [Modern Dance Pioneer Isadora Duncan warned] "Ballet condemns itself by enforcing the deformation of the beautiful woman's body," modern dance pioneer Isadora Duncan warned nearly a century ago, describing a situation she found to be "the result of the training necessary to the ballet." At the heart of this training is something one might call natural selection, or anatomy-is-destiny. This principle holds that ballet isn't just a matter of a woman mastering difficult steps, but of being able to define an idealized silhouette, that flowing, unbroken, sculptural arrangement of hyper-extended limbs and torso called ballet line. In other words, if you happen to be born with the "wrong" body, all the classes in the world won't make you look right in a tutu-the uniform for classical conquest and symbol of the sylph sisterhood. Alas, the small, compact Fredrika Keefers just don't fit the mold. 2. Ballet is dangerous 29 Jennifer Dunning, “Eating Disorders Haunt Ballerinas”, New York Times, July 16 1997 http://www.nytimes.com/1997/07/16/arts/eating-disorders-haunt-ballerinas.html ''The problem is much more common in middle- and upper-class women, particularly white women and young women under 25,'' Dr. Warren said. ''Dance is one of the worst areas. The average incidence of eating disorders in the white middle-class population is 1 in 100. In classical ballet, it is one in five.'' Most are female students and the youngest female professionals, particularly those with less physical facility and less-than-perfect bodies. Older women tend to suffer from less serious eating problems, like yo-yo dieting and the age-old dancers' regimen of diet soda and cigarettes,which affect about 46 percent of professional ballet dancers, according to Dr. Hamilton. 30