I-deals and organizational commitment: Introducing the role of I-deal uniqueness Brigitte Kroon ª*, Charissa Freese ª, Susanne P.D. de Kort ª Work in progress: Please do not quote (ª) Tilburg University, School of Social and Behavioral Sciences, Department Human Resource Studies (*) corresponding author: b.kroon@uvt.nl 1. Introduction Due to societal developments such as increased individualization, reduced life-time employment careers, and worker accountability for their own careers, employees increasingly negotiate their own employment conditions to tailor them to their personal needs and aspirations (Rousseau, 2001). Employers are not averse to these developments, as they realize that creating personalized employment arrangement might be the key to create committed employees (Rousseau, 2005). By tailoring employment conditions to employee needs, employees are expected to experience reciprocal obligations towards their employer, resulting in higher levels of organizational commitment. Idiosyncratic deals, or I-deals in short, can be considered the ultimate form of customizing employment relations (Kroon & Freese, 2012). As assumed in literature, employees will show positive organizational behavior and attitudes when they successfully negotiate an I-deal (Rousseau, 2005). Empirical research on the effects of I-deals on commitment, however, is limited and inconsistent (Rosen, Slater, Chang & Johnson, 2013). While prior studies focused on the internal organizational uniqueness of the I-deal, we argue that ‘non-standard’ evaluations expand beyond the borders of the own organization. Due to employees’ increased job mobility and knowledge of possibilities in the external labor market (Ng, Sorensen, Eby & Feldman, 2007), employees expand the non-standard evaluation of employment conditions beyond organizational borders. Subsequently, we argue that the effects of I-deals on commitment may vary considerably due to differences in the perceived external uniqueness of the Ideal. To examine this effect, we developed the construct of I-deal uniqueness. The purpose of this study, then, is to examine how the uniqueness of the I-deal outside the organization influences organizational commitment. Moreover, we also study the relative contribution of the I-deal in the complete employment relationship, where it concerns the relationship with organizational commitment. We therefore investigate the perceived uniqueness of the total employment package and the interaction effect of uniqueness of I-deals and the total employment contract in explaining organizational commitment. This study contributes to the existing knowledge on I-deals in multiple ways. To date, only a few researchers tested the influence of I-deals on commitment and found that certain types of I-deals influence affective, normative and continuance commitment (Hornung et al., 2008; Rosen et al., 2011). This research enhances the understanding of the effect of I-deals on organizational commitment, and may validate previous research. Secondly, it contributes to the literature on I-deals by introducing and operationalizing the construct of I-deal uniqueness. In doing so, it is the first study to examine the role of I-deal uniqueness in creating organizational commitment. Finally it separates the explanatory effects of I-deals from effects of the complete employment contract on organizational commitment from the effects of the total employment contract. 2. Theory 2.1 Idiosyncratic deals I-deals are “voluntary, personalized agreements of a nonstandard nature that individual workers negotiate with their employers regarding terms that benefit them both” (Rousseau, 2005, p. 8). The element of mutual benefits differentiates I-deals from other personalizes arrangements such as favoritism or cronyism (Rousseau, 2005). An I-deal may be negotiated on different subjects: development, flexibility, taskload (Ng & Feldman, 2010, Rouseau & Kim, 2006) and financial incentives (Rosen, et al., 2011). I-deals are also heterogeneous in scope. Some employees may have only one I-deal, while others have a largely non-standard employment package. Furthermore, I-deals can differ in timing (e.g. ex ante or ex post negotiation) and initiation (e.g. by the employer or the employee). Due to factors like liberalization of labor laws, increased individualization and labor market pressures, employers have adopted I-deals as a strategy to attract and retain valued employees and create loyalty and effort (Hornung, Rousseau & Glaser, 2008; Ng & Feldman, 2010). We argue that the potential of I-deals to impact on commitment depends on the extent to which employees perceive their deal as genuinely unique as compared to the employment benefits they could have received elsewhere. In this case, the reference point of evaluating the I-deal is not the HR practices of the employing organization, but the state of affairs with regard to employment benefits in the whole field of potential employers. 2.2 Organizational commitment Meyer and Allen (1991) proposed a three-component measure of organizational commitment: affective commitment, normative commitment and continuance commitment. All three components reflect the psychological states of employees, which characterize the type of employee’s attachment to the organization. However, the nature of these psychological states differs. Affective commitment refers to “the employee’s emotional attachment to, identification with, and involvement in the organization” (Meyer & Allen, 1991, p. 67). It is related to acceptance of organizational values, the willingness to exert effort and a desire to stay with the organization because employees want to. Normative commitment can be viewed as an obligation to stay, employees feel they ought to because they believe it is morally right to stay. Finally, continuance commitment is associated with a conscious awareness of the costs leaving the organization and difficulties in finding a new job. Employees stay within the organization because they need to (Meyer & Allen, 1991). Because of their different nature, the three components of organizational commitment have different implications for workplace behaviors like turnover, absenteeism and citizenship. Both affective and normative commitment are positively related to performance and work behaviors like OCB and attendance, while continuance commitment does not correlate with OCB and correlates negatively with job performance and stress (Meyer, Stanley, Herscovitch & Topolnytsky, 2002). These results suggest that affective commitment and normative commitment benefit the organization, while continuance commitment does not serve the organization. This implies that creating affective and normative commitment through I-deals should be fostered, while I-deals solely creating continuance commitment should be minimized. This leads to our first hypothesis that I-deals have an effect on organizational commitment. Hypothesis 1. I-dealers have higher levels of organizational commitment (affective, continuance and normantive) than employees who do not have I-deals. 2.3 I-deals and organizational commitment I-deals relate to organizational commitment through instrumental as well as socio-emotional processes. The instrumental value of I-deals lies in the actual improvement of the fit between personal needs of employees with the working conditions offered by the employer. Employees become committed to the organization because they see a beneficial or equitable exchange between their contributions to the organization and the I-deal they receive (Cohen, 2007). Continuance commitment follows from the employees’ awareness of the costs involved in the potential loss of the I-deal when the employee leaves the organization to work for another organization. Positioned in the Employee-Organization framework on push and pull forces for staying and leaving (Hom, 2012), this I-deal is categorized as a “pull to stay” force. Following Meyer, Becker and Vandenberghe (2004) it can be argued that employees who remain because they fear forfeiting these kinds of I-deals if they leave (e.g. a form of continuance commitment) do not necessarily feel affectively committed to the organization. By offering financial I-deals that are focused on benefits, compensations, and remunerations, and flexibility I-deals (focused on working at home and flexible working hours) employees become committed to the organization because of the threat of losing these valued outcomes, especially when lacking job alternatives. In other words, we assume that financial and flexibility I-deals contribute to continuance commitment, as employees want to maintain their benefits and rewards. Although this reasoning seems valid, empirical research on remuneration Ideals and commitment is scarce and evidence is rather weak. Powell and Meyer (2004) found that arrangements such as pay, benefits and promotion opportunities and lack of alternatives were positively related to continuance commitment. A study by Rosen et al. (2011) showed that financial Ideals were only weakly related to continuance commitment. This leads to our second and third hypotheses. Hypothesis 2: Financial I-deals are related to continuance commitment. Hypothesis 3: Flexibility I-deals are related to continuance commitment. The relationship between I-deals and commitment can also be explained by socio-emotional processes. Social exchange theory predicts that when the organization offers additional inducements such as I-deals, this will evoke affective reciprocal reactions (Cohen, 2007). By granting I-deals, organizations show an additional preparedness to invest in the employees’ needs that carries beyond the instrumental value of the I-deal. I-deals signal trust in the employee and appreciation of an employees’ value to the organization (Hornung et al., 2008). These relational aspects of the I-deal induce a need by the employee to restore the balance with the organization by contributing to the well-being of the organization to maintain equity in a mutually beneficial relationship (Meyer & Allen, 1991), which is met by showing positive affective reactions, such as a strong desire to stay with that employer (affective commitment). Furthermore, the recognition of organizational investments (granting I-deals) may cause an imbalance in the employee/organization relationship (Meyer & Allen, 1991). Consequently, employees will feel morally obligated to reciprocate with a moral feeling of obligation to continue employment (normative commitment) (Cohen, 2007). Development I-deals like career development, work content or training are related to these positive work experiences. By granting development I-deals, organizations “provide individuals a special contribution, often involving symbolic and social-emotional elements, [like] trust, appreciation, [and] personalization” (Hornung et al., 2008, p. 656). Development I-deals therefore contribute to affective and normative commitment in multiple ways: through the feeling of being a special individual who receives rare and valued resources, and through the moral obligation to compensate organizational investments (Cohen, 2007; Ng & Feldman, 2010). Empirical evidence on the relationship between development Ideals and affective and normative commitment is more profound, albeit still in a descendant stage. Ng and Feldman (2010) found a positive relationship between contract idiosyncrasy (level of pay, advancement opportunities, skill training, career development opportunities, job security, and support for personal problems) and affective commitment. An essential limitation of this study however is the absence of separate measures for different types of I-deals and their isolated effect on different types of commitment. Rosen et al. (2013) found that I-deals that involved arrangements in the area of job content (tasks, responsibilities) contributed to higher affective commitment. And Liu, Lee, Hui, Kwan and Wu (2013) found that development I-deals and flexibility I-deals enhanced affective commitment, through perceived organizational support. Development I-deals address affective and normative commitment through the process of social exchange (trust, fulfillment, special meaning), while financial and flexibility I-deals relate to continuance commitment, because of the potential loss of valuable outcomes. Based on this reasoning, the following hypotheses are formulated: Hypothesis 4: Development I-deals are related to normative and affective commitment. 2.3 I-deal uniqueness In this section, the employee’s evaluation of the value of the I-deals is put central by focussing on the I-deals uniqueness. By definition, the frame of reference of I-deals considers the extent to which employment conditions are unique compared to similar co-workers within the same firm. I-deal uniqueness, however, concerns the degree to which employees think these voluntary, personalized agreements are likely to be offered by other companies. Thus, while both concepts address the nonstandard nature of employment conditions, I-deals have a within-firm focus whereas I-deal uniqueness has a between-firm focus. Furthermore, I-deal uniqueness reflects a higher level of distinctiveness in employment conditions. The employees’ employment benefits are considered to be special both within and beyond the borders of the own organization. Consequently, the impact of the instrumental and social-emotional processes underlying the relationship between I-deals and commitment, and therefore the intensity of changes in employee commitment, will depend on the level of external uniqueness. Hypothesis 5. The more I-dealers perceive their I-deal as externally unique, the higher their level of organizational commitment (affective, continuance and normative). Because it might well be that organizations offering I-deals are more advanced in their HR practices and therefore a more attractive employer, we also assess the contribution of the uniqueness of the Ideals versus the complete employment benefit package of the employee. Would it be possible for the employee to find the same benefits elsewhere? Hypothesis 6. The more employees perceive their total employment contract benefits as externally unique, the higher the level of organizational commitment And finally, we investigate the relative contribution of the uniqueness of I-deals in explaining organizational commitment as compared to the uniqueness of the complete employment benefits package. We assume that both having an I-deal and a unique employment benefits package will result in higher levels of organizational commitment. These employees are at the top of the pyramid of employment relationships. They have a wonderful employment benefits package and on top of that an I-deal. This will create strong bonds between the employee and the organization. We therefore hypothesize that: Hypothesis 7. The relationship between employment benefit uniqueness and organizational commitment is moderated by I-deals, such that it is stronger for people who have I-deals. 3. Method 3.1 Data collection procedure In order to identify employees who successfully negotiated I-deals, department managers in a variety of organizations were approached to participate in a study on employee evaluations of the employment terms and conditions. Requirements for participation in the study included a minimal organization size of 50 employees, and a minimal department size of 7 employees. When the manager agreed to participate, all employees in this department were given a hardcopy questionnaire, which was collected by the research team to ensure confidentiality. This procedure resulted in a total of 572 employee questionnaires of 71 organizations. Of these employees, 97 employees indicated that they have had negotiated one or more I-deals (17%). 3.2 Sample The initial sample contained organization units where none of the respondents reported to have successfully negotiated an I-deal. Given that the distribution between people with and without Ideals was skewed towards the latter, and to increase the comparability of working contexts of respondents, we removed all respondents of units where no I-deals were reported from the sample. This resulted in a final sample of 572 employees. The organization units were in different industries (Health care, 26%; financial institutions, 17%). The average age of the respondents was 40.5 years (SD = 11.82). The sample contained slightly more women than men (56%). About half of the sample completed higher education (49%) and most respondents had a permanent contract (83%). Table 1 shows the types and distribution of I-deals in the sample, compared to demographic characteristics (gender, type of contract, level of education, fulltime/parttime). Most I-deals concern flexibility (working at home, on different hours, additional days of/sabbatical) (n=60), followed by development I-deals (training, extra tasks, careerstep) (n=39) and financial I-deals (bonuses, salary raise) (n=36). People with financial I-deals differed significantly form people without I-deals in terms of educational level. Flexibility I-deals were significantly more present when people reported having a permanent contract. ==== Insert table 1 about here ==== 3.3 Measures 3.3.1 I-deals In the current paper, we wanted to get an objective indication of the presence of I-deals. Since most respondents would be unaware about the construct I-deal, we developed a series of questions to sensitize respondents about their awareness of I-deals, before asking whether they had an I-deal themselves. First, a definition was provided about standard terms and conditions of employment: “Terms and conditions of employment that apply to all employees. Often, these are described in a personnel manual, company handbook or in a CLA”. Respondents had to indicate whether they knew such policies were available in their organization: “Does your organization have a personnel handbook containing formal rules for terms and conditions of employment?”, and “Does a CLA apply to your terms and conditions of employment?” Possible responses were: No, Probably not, Probably, Yes. Next, respondents were asked to report whether they had an I-deal after reading the following instruction: “Sometimes people agree to deviate from standard terms and conditions of employment, because this benefits the employee as well as the organization better than the standard conditions. These deviations are called I-deals. I-deals are exceptions to standard terms and conditions of employment that employees negotiate themselves with their employer, and that can vary from one employee to another”. Another sensitizing question lead respondents to think about I-deals in their organization: “Do you know whether in your organization exceptions to the standard terms and conditions of employment are allowed occasionally?”. Possible responses were: No, Probably not, Probably, Yes. After these sensitizing questions, two questions lead the respondent to judge whether they had an Ideal themselves. The first question was: “Did you ever ask your employer to make an exception to the standard terms and conditions of employment in your organization, to adjust to your personal circumstances?” ( No / Yes). If positive, a follow-up question concerned the presence of an I-deal: “Did you succeed in negotiating a personalized, non-standard agreement about terms and conditions of employment (an I-deal)?”( No / Yes). Employees who responded positively to this last question were subsequently asked to answer ten questions about the type of I-deal they negotiated with their employer: “About WHICH terms and conditions of employment did you succeed to negotiate an I-deal (personalized agreement)?”. Nine questions with checkboxes related to previously published categories of I-deals: Financial I-deals (Bonusses / allowances / extra salary; Salary development ); Development I-deals (Chances for promotion; Training and education; Extra tasks / responsibilities); Flexibility I-deals (Working outside the office; Flexible working hours; Longer holidays/additional days off/ sabbatical leave) (Rosen et al., 2013); and I-deals concerning support with personal problems (Ng & Feldman, 2010). The final question was open ended: Other, namely ….. The latter two types of I-deals (personal support / other) were ticked only 13 and 7 times respectively and were therefore excluded from the analyses. Answers were recoded per I-deal type, such that when one or more types were present, the respondent’s score to that I-deal type equals 1. Hence, three dummy variables were created for the presence of I-deals: Financial I-deals (0-1), Development I-deals (0-1) and Flexibility I-deals (0-1). Zero indicates absence of an I-deal type. Respondents without I-deals score zero on each type. 3.3.2 I-deal external uniqueness Given the possibility that respondents have more than one I-deal, the questionnaire included a sensitizing question about which I-deal was most important to them. After that, two questions were asked about the perceived external uniqueness of that I-deal. These were: “This I-deal is a reason to stay with this organization”, and “I can also get this I-deal in another organization”. Responses were scored on a five point Likert scale ranging from totally disagree to totally agree. Items correlated r = .51. 3.3.3 Organizational commitment Organizational commitment was measured with the 13-item Dutch version of Meyer, Allen and Smith’s (1993) Organizational Commitment Questionnaire (Jak & Evers, 2010). CFA confirmed a three factor solution best fitted the data. These were: Affective commitment (α = .897), Normative commitment (α = .865) and Continuance commitment (α = .611). 3.3.4 Control variables Gender (men = 0, women = 1), age, having children at home, educational level, organizational tenure, departmental tenure and contract hours were included as control variables. 4. Results 4.1. Descriptives and correlations Table 2 shows all descriptives and correlations. 4.2 Hypotheses test Hypotheses were tested using multiple linear regressions. The first hypothesis states that I-dealers have higher levels of organizational commitment than employees who do not have I-deals. Table 3 shows the relative contribution that the presence of each type of I-deal (financial, development and flexibility) has on affective, normative and continuance commitment after entering the control variables. Having an i-deal in itself is not related to higher levels of organizational commitment. Hypothesis 1 is rejected. Consequently, Hypothesis 2 (Financial I-deals are related to continuance commitment, Table 4) and Hypothesis 3 (Flexibility I-deals are related to continuance commitment, Table 5) were also rejected. Only development I-deals were related to affective commitment (Table 6). Hypothesis 4 is partially accepted; the relationship was not found for normative commitment. Hypothesis 5 stated that the more I-dealers perceive their I-deal as externally unique, the higher their level of organizational commitment. This hypothesis was only confirmed for development ideals (Table 7). Hypothesis 6 however, the more employees perceive their total employment package as externally unique, the higher their organizational commitment is confirmed (Table 7). And finally, hypothesis 7, was also accepted. The effect of a unique employment contract on commitment is higher when employees have i-deals (Table 7/8). 5. Discussion Our findings provide support for our hypothesis that I-deals lead to commitment only when employees perceive that such arrangements are difficult to obtain in other organizations. In this section, we discuss the limitations of the current study, as well as the implications for both research and practice. 5.1 Limitations There are several limitations in the present study that should be considered. First, the effect sizes of ideal uniqueness on organizational commitment are relatively small (ΔR² = .04-.08). This does not mean that ideal uniqueness is not important, but it does emphasize the relatively small effect of ideals on organizational commitment. Furthermore, because the number of employees in the sample with an I-deal was relatively low, results can only be viewed as indicative. More research is needed to validate the results of this study. Approximately one fifth to one third of Dutch employees report to have successfully negotiated an Ideal Nauta, Oeij, Huiskamp & Goudswaard, 2007; Kroon & Freese, 2012). The number of reported Ideals also depends on the strictness of the application of the I-deal definition in the questionnaire. A major methodological disadvantage of measuring effects of I-deals is that sample sizes automatically decrease to thirty or even twenty percent of the original data set. Studying the impact of different kinds of I-deals reduce the sample size even further. Second, since all variables are self-reported in nature and come from one single source, common method variance possibly affected the observed relationships. To eliminate this source of bias, procedures to protect respondents’ anonymity and reducing evaluation apprehension were used. In future research, the use of other-report measures like supervisor-rated commitment could be used. Third, due to the cross-sectional nature of this study, it was not possible to rule out reversed causality. Due to a positive attitude towards their employer, employees with a high level of commitment might consider their I-deal as more unique than employees with lower levels of commitment. Lastly, since data were collected at two different times and with two different sampling approaches, interpreting and generalizing the results to other organizational setting may be limited. Nonetheless, the diversified sample of sectors, occupations and job levels provides enough justification for generalizing the data in Dutch settings. Moreover, results did not reveal a significant influence of group differences on the proposed relationships. The solo effect of i-deal on commitment is limited to affective commitment. I-deals lead to affective commitment when employees perceive that such arrangements are difficult to obtain in other organizations • The uniqueness of the total employment package seems more important than the uniqueness of the i-deal in creating commitment. • However, this effect of employment contract uniqueness is stronger when employees have ideals. Using i-deals to create a higher level of (affective) commitment is only successful if the content of the i-deal is considered as genuinely unique. However, offering a unique package of employment benefits is a more profound strategic employer branding strategy in creating commitment I-deals have an additional value in the creation of commitment for organizations that offer unique employee benefits. Need for additional theory on i-deal uniqueness 5.2 Implications for future research How do employees create their perception of I-deal uniqueness? - Individual differences (pro self, pro social) - Influence of CBA or company specific policies - How is the comparison group determined? - Other potential influences??? What is the role of the psychological contract? What about the non-standard evaluation of other employment conditions, besides I-deals? 5.3 Implications for practice having an I-deal does not create commitment, having a unique I-deal does. Therefore, make sure you benchmark consider the ‘side-effects’ of I-deals. Create slightly higher commitment through unique Ideals should not lead to a significant diminishment of commitment of co-workers consider your policy on employment conditions carefully. Which elements do you standardize? What are flexible elements in your policy? How do you communicate about I-deals? References Hornung, S., Rousseau, D.M., & Glaser, J. (2008). Creating flexible work arrangements through idiosyncratic deals. Journal of Applied Psychology, 93, 655-664. doi: 10.1037/0021 -010.93.3.655 Kroon, B., & Freese, C. (2012). Dragen I-deals bij aan behoud en motivatie van medewerkers? Tijdschrift voor HRM, 2, 43-58 Liu, J., Lee, C., Hui, C., Kwan, H.K., & Wu, L.-Z. (2013). Idiosyncratic deals and employee outcomes: the mediating roles of social exchange and self-enhancement and the moderating role of individualism. Journal of 10.1037/a0032571 Ng, Sorensen, Eby & Feldman, 2007 Applied Psychology. Advance online publication. doi: Ng, T.W.H., & Feldman, D.C. (2010). Idiosyncratic deals and organizational commitment. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 76, 419-427. doi: 10.1016/j.jvb.2009.10.006 Rosen, C.C., Slater, D.J., Chang, C.H.D., & Johnson, R.E. (2013). Let’s make a deal: development and validation of the ex post I-deals scale. Journal of Management, 39, 709-742 doi: 10.1177/ 0149206310394865 Rousseau, D.M. (2001). The idiosyncratic deal: flexibility versus fairness? Organizational Dynamics, 29, 260-273. doi: 10.1016/S0090-2616(01)00032-8 Rousseau, D.M. (2005). I-deals: idiosyncratic deals employees bargain for themselves. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe Rousseau, D. M., & Kim, T. G. 2006. When workers bargain for themselves: Idiosyncratic deals and the nature of the employment relationship. Paper presented at British Academy of Management, Belfast. TABLES Table 1: Distribution of I-deals in the sample Total Gender¹ Educational level¹ (N = 572) Male Female Low/middle High Requested an I-deal 107 43 (251) 62 (315) 17,1% Obtained an I-deal 97 40 (252) 55 (317) 15,9% Remuneration I-deal 36 19,7% 17,4% 19 (252) 17 (317) 7,5% Development I-deal 39 5,4% 18 (252) 20 (317) 7,1% Flexibility I-deal 60 6,3% 20 (252) 38 (317) 7,9% 12,0% Contract type¹ Contract hours¹ Permanent Temporal Fulltime Parttime 50 (287) 57 (277) 92 (474) 14 (91) 58 (308) 45 (237) 17,4% 20,6% 19,4% 15,4% 18,9% 19,0% 45 (289) 52 (278) 85 (477) 11 (91) 52 (308) 40 (239) 15,6% 18,7% 17,8% 12,1% 16,9% 16,7% 12 (289) 24 (278) 31 (477) 5 (91) 20 (308) 13 (239) 4,2% 8,6%* 6,5% 5,5% 6,5% 5,4% 16 (289) 23 (278) 33 (477) 5 (91) 23 (308) 14 (239) 5,5% 8,3% 6,9% 5,5% 7,5% 5,9% 25 (289) 35 (278) 55 (477) 5 (91) 31 (308) 28 (239) 8,7% 12,6% 11,5% 5,5% † 10,1% 11,7% Level of significance group differences: †p<.10 *p<.05 ¹ Crosstabs ( χ²); ² Number of respondents “yes” (total number of respondents per category) Note: Low/middle educational level; intermediate vocational, basic or elementary education, high educational level; higher vocational or academic. Flexibility I-deals; flexibility in working hours and work place fulltime contract = 36 hours per week or more Table 2: descriptive statistics and correlations 1. Affective commitment 2. Normative commitment 3. Continuance commitment 4. Ideals yes a. Development I-deals b. Remuneration I-deals c. Flexibility I-deals 5. I-deal uniqueness 6. Psy contr uniqueness 7. Men/Women 8. Age 9. Parttime/ fulltime 10. Permanent/ flex 11. Children living at home N 562 564 564 M 3.36 3.22 2.23 93 39 36 60 93 558 569 562 547 568 562 16,3% 6,8% 6,3% 10,5% 3,13 2,91 56% 40.45 44% 16% 45% sd 0.71 0.82 0.77 0,83 0,76 11,82 1 2 .27** .22** .25** .08* .07* .00 .06 .30** ,28** -.11** .04 -.08* -.12** .02 .06 .05 .00 .06 .22* ,28** -.06 -.09* -.07* .01 -.06 3 4 4a 4b 4c 5 .01 .00 -.04 .04 .22* ,09* .02 .13** .03 -.12** .12** .76** .69** .75** .10 .12* .00 .01 -.01 -.07 -.02 .50** .36** .07 ,10* -.02 -.01 -.03 -.02 .02 .26** -.15 ,08* -.04 -.04 -.02 -.02 -.02 .20* .09* .07 .00 .03 -.07* .00 .20* .17 .01 .21* .09 -.08 Table 3: regressions of all kinds of I-deals on organizational commitment (N=572) Affective Commitment 1 2 B β B -.14* -.10 -.07 .00 .03 .00 Model Gender Age I-deal (noyes) Psy contract uniqueness R² ΔR² Table β -.05 .06 Model Age Gender .08 -.01 -.01 .06 .03 .25 .26*** .27 .26*** .10 .10* R² ΔR² .08*** .07*** Regression for .01* commitment, Normative Commitment 1 2 B β B β -.01 -.10* -.01 -.08† -.10 -.07 -.02 -.02 Empl contract uniqueness Remuneration I-deal (no/yes) Psy * Rem Ideal Continuance Commitment 1 2 B β B β .05 .03 .08 .05 .01 .13** .01 .14** .07 ,01* 4: Normative Commitment 1 2 B β B β -.10 -.07 -.02 -.01 -.01 -.10* -.01 -.07 3 B -.01 -.02 β -.08* -.01 .07*** .06*** interactions .02* with Age Gender I-deal 3 B .01 .09 β .13** .05 .27 .26*** .24 .24*** .11 .10* .09 .08† -.09 -.03 -1.38 -.44* -.12 -.04 -1.14 -.34† .41 .43* .32 .31† .01* .08*** .07*** Affective Commitment 1 B β .00 .03 -.14 -.10* Psy contract uniqueness Development I-deal (no/yes) Psy * Dev Ideal R² ΔR² financial Continuance Commitment 1 2 B Β B β .01 .13** .01 .14** .05 .03 .08 .05 .09*** .01* .02* .03** .01* Table6: Regression for commitment, interactions with development I-deal Model .03** .01 .01* 2 B .00 -.07 β .06 -.05 3 B .00 -.06 β .06 -.05 .25 .26*** .23 .24*** .12 .04 -1.21 -.43* .42 .48* .08*** .07*** .09*** .01* .03* .01† Table 7: regressions for organizational commitment considering i-deal uniqueness (N=93 = People with Ideals only) Model Gender Age Affective Commitment 1 2 B β B .01 .12 .01 .08 .05 .15 i-deal uniqueness Empl contract uniqueness R² ΔR² .01 β .10 .10 Normative Commitment 1 2 B β B β -.01 -.07 -.01 -.09 .02 .01 .15 .09 Continuance Commitment 1 2 B β B β .02 .23* .02 .22* .33 .20† .38 .23* .19 .20† .08 .08 .13 .13 .33 .30* .35 .32** .20 .17* .12** .11** .01 .11** .10** .07* .12* .05