STRATEGIC ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN FAMILY BUSINESS G.T. Lumpkin,1 Lloyd Steier,2 and Mike Wright34* 1Department of Entrepreneurship and Emerging Enterprises, Whitman School of Management, Syracuse University, Syracuse, New York 2Center for Entrepreneurship and Family Enterprise, University of Alberta School of Business, University of Alberta, Edmonton, Alberta, Canada 3Centre for Management Buy-out Research, Imperial College Business School, London, U.K. 4Department of Management, Innovation and Entrepreneurship, Ghent University, Ghent, Belgium Keywords: family business; strategic entrepreneurship; familiness; succession; governance *Correspondence to: Mike Wright, Centre for Management Buy-out Research, Imperial College Business School, Exhibition Road, London SW7, U.K. E-mail: mike.wright@imperial.ac.uk The purpose of this special issue is to promote research on the role of family in nurturing entrepreneurial ventures as well as on the importance of strategic entrepreneurship in maintaining the strength and viability of established and multigenerational family firms. Two related research questions are at the heart of this inquiry: (1) In what ways does the influence of family matter to strategic entrepreneurship?; and (2) How can strategic entrepreneurship contribute to understanding and strengthening family firms? We begin this introductory paper by providing a brief overview of the contributions of each of the papers in this issue. We then develop a framework for addressing the role of family firms in strategic entrepreneurship that highlights the input-process-output nature of strategic entrepreneurship in family business and the contexts in which they occur. We conclude by outlining a research agenda for future research in this area along the themes relating to this framework. Copyright © 2011 Strategic Management Society. 1 INTRODUCTION Human beings are essentially social creatures who throughout history have created social structures that shape their interactions. These structures have various manifestations that are oftentimes overlapping, for example, the state, the church, the family, and business organizations. Even though family represents a primary institution (one that greatly impacts the creation, survival, and success of firms worldwide), management scholars have traditionally devoted relatively little attention to this phenomenon. Recently, two distinct developments have emerged that help address this deficiency. First, in the ‘last 15 years or so’ (Gomez-Mejia et al., 2011: 654) research on family firms has grown tremendously. Second, research on strategic entrepreneurship (SE) also began in earnest ‘early in the 21st century’ (Hitt et al., 2011: 57) and offers a new lens with the potential to shed new light on the success of family business. This special issue focuses on the intersection between strategic entrepreneurship and family business. Family is manifest in both the creation and organization of most of the world’s firms (La Porta et al., 1999; Gomez-Mejia et al., 2007). Within the U.S., recent research on the sociology of entrepreneurship (Ruef, 2010) further debunks the ‘myth’ of the solo actor entrepreneur and notes that most entrepreneurial activity is essentially a ‘group’ effort with family groups— spouses, cohabiting partners, and kin—constituting an essential mechanism of the venturecreation process. The importance of family business to global economies is paramount. The impact is so pervasive in part because family influences every level of analysis. Research finds that: families play a vital role in the venture-creation process by providing or withholding funding and emotional support (Sharma, 2004); the dominant coalitions of most family businesses powerfully influence firm-level strategic orientations (Chrisman, Chua, and Sharma, 2005); and since family firms represent the majority of workforce employment and GDP 2 (Astrachan and Shanker, 2003), there are significant policy implications in both developed and developing nations. Considering the magnitude of their contribution, it could be argued that research aimed at understanding business generally requires an appreciation of family business. However, while more than 90 percent of small and medium enterprises (SMEs) are family businesses (Astrachan and Shanker, 2003) and even one-third of Fortune 500 firms in the U.S. are family influenced (Anderson and Reeb, 2003), general management research has hitherto been studying family firms in their samples often without acknowledging the unique family dynamics and influence that are at work. The development of strategic entrepreneurship research has overlapped with growth in family business research and is emerging rapidly as a topic critical for wealth creation and economic strength. It is, therefore, important to explore the role of strategic entrepreneurship within the context of family firms. So far, few researchers have investigated the role of strategic entrepreneurship in family businesses. Generally speaking, entrepreneurship scholars have tended to underestimate the contribution of family systems to entrepreneurial success, and many existing family business scholars have focused on wealth preservation rather than wealthcreating activities such as opportunity recognition, innovation, strategy, and growth. The aim of this essay and the purpose of this special issue is to promote research on the role of family in nurturing entrepreneurial ventures as well as on the importance of strategic entrepreneurship in maintaining the strength and viability of established and multigenerational family firms. Two related research questions are at the heart of this inquiry: (1) In what ways does the influence of family matter to strategic entrepreneurship?; and (2) How can strategic entrepreneurship contribute to understanding and strengthening family firms? 3 To address these research questions, we begin by providing a brief overview of the contribution of each paper to the special issue. We then build upon a model of the strategic entrepreneurship process set forth in a recent article by Hitt et al. (2011) to create a novel framework for addressing the role of family businesses in strategic entrepreneurship. We also use this framework to identify how each paper that appears in this special issue informs our research questions. We end with suggestions for a future research agenda aimed at understanding the role of strategic entrepreneurship in familial contexts. PAPERS IN THIS SPECIAL ISSUE Following a general call, 17 submissions were received. Papers were reviewed according to standard SEJ procedures and Table 1 summarizes the papers in the special issue that successfully negotiated this process. Each paper investigates a specific aspect of strategic entrepreneurship and family business. Different theoretical perspectives are used in the papers including the resource-based view (RBV), agency theory and informational asymmetries, entrepreneurial orientation, stagnation theory, and institutional theory. Several papers integrate different theoretical perspectives. For example, Chirico et al. (2011) integrate entrepreneurial orientation and resource orchestration perspectives, Singal and Singal (2011) integrate agency and institutional perspectives, and Nordqvist et al. (2011) bring together information asymmetry and stagnation perspectives. The papers adopt a range of empirical approaches generating rich data sets, ranging from longitudinal qualitative case studies (Sieger et al., 2011), to cross-sectional mail surveys (Chirico et al., 2011) to large-scale panel data sets (Nordqvist et al., 2011; Singal and Singal, 2011). Different analytical techniques are also adopted, including theory building from cases, OLS regression, hazard models, and panel data estimation. INSERT TABLE 1 ABOUT HERE 4 A FRAMEWORK FOR FAMILY BUSINESS AND STRATEGIC ENTREPRENEURSHIP In developing our conceptual framework, we first highlight the input-process-output nature of strategic entrepreneurship. Of course, our framework is consistent with the ‘systems’ logic of most input-output models in that it assumes the various causal factors are interconnected. Family firms create value in much the same way as other firms, but both the inputs to the value-adding activities and the benefits that flow from value-creation processes may differ significantly in family firms. Further, we believe families also impact the process itself due to the ways they accumulate and leverage resources and because of the strong emphasis that many families place on building socioemotional wealth in addition to financial viability. Finally, the strategic entrepreneurship process is strongly influenced by contextual factors that tend to be unique to family firms. Figure 1 depicts the framework that we used to organize our analysis. INSERT FIGURE 1 ABOUT HERE Inputs Consistent with most ‘systems’ models of economic interaction, our model includes inputs as a key category. Next we identify and discuss three key inputs: individual resources, family resources, and organizational resources. Individual resources How might individual differences influence the strategic entrepreneurship of family firms? On the one hand, the skills and capabilities that any given individual might bring to an entrepreneurial venture are not likely to differ depending on whether it is a family business or a nonfamily business. On the other hand, the background experiences and prior knowledge of individuals who have: (1) grown up in a family business; (2) worked for a family business; or (3) 5 been the prior owner of a family business could enhance or detract from their ability to be a valuable resource. Individuals who have been associated with family businesses since childhood can bestow either advantages or disadvantages as employees of family firms. They have the potential to provide a unique form of human capital in the form of firm-specific tacit knowledge gained from extensive exposure to the family business (Sirmon and Hitt, 2003). Such individuals may also have a strong commitment to the family business and close ties with family members who are key decision makers (Horton, 1986). By contrast, family members may be ill-equipped to take on responsibilities as decision makers or even employees of a family business (Barach et al., 1988). While family firms may care more about the survival of their businesses than is the case of nonfamily firms, survival rates are relatively low and generally no better than in nonfamily firms (Ward, 2004). Poorly qualified successors and those who lack the motivation but choose to work in the family firm anyway disadvantage family firms that are attempting to encourage intrafamily succession (De Massis, Chua, and Chrisman, 2008; Handler and Kram, 1988). Nonfamily members who work for family firms potentially provide a similarly ‘mixed blessing.’ Nonfamily members bring an outside perspective that is potentially valuable. This may be especially important in small family businesses that have few nonfamily members in senior decision-making roles. Family business research into professionalization of management has often highlighted the introduction of nonfamily members into the management team and board of directors (Hall and Nordqvist, 2008). Studies have also found that some individuals prefer working in family firms even if they are not family members because of the overall closeness, conviviality and ‘feeling of family’ of the work environment (Tagiuri and Davis, 1996; Vallejo, 2009). However, those same conditions could create problem for nonfamily employees who 6 witness family closeness but do not feel a part of it. Favoritism in compensation or key decisionmaking roles for family members may be demoralizing to nonfamily members: this could be manifest in shirking or sabotage. Family resources Family-owned and operated businesses often enjoy competitive advantages because of what the family itself has to offer to the business (Sharma, 2004). This can take many forms, beginning with the synergies that accrue to family firms where individuals have the type of trusting relationships and tacit knowledge identified in the previous section. Such conditions give family firms a comparative advantage relative to nonfamily firms where turnover is relatively higher, trust takes longer to establish, and task-specific knowledge has to be learned on the job (Chrisman et al., 2005). Access to family resources and longer time horizons for payoffs on investments can also strength a family business’ ability to compete (Sirmon and Hitt, 2003). Drawing on the resource-based view of the firm, Habbershon, Williams, and MacMillian (2003) suggested the term ‘familiness’ to represent the potential advantages that emerge when a family system and its individual family members interact with the family business to produce a unique bundle of resources. In other words, the involvement and commitment of the family are able to bestow distinct advantages on family firms. The types of resources that contribute to this virtuous mix include the entrepreneurial spirit of founders, the firm’s reputation, its management practices, and the trust and communication among family members, to name a few (Chrisman, Chua, and Steier, 2005). Drawing on social capital theory, Pearson, Carr, and Shaw (2008) have advanced the notion of familiness by identifying the behavioral and social resources that are unique to families. Quantitative (e.g., Ensley and Pearson, 2005) and qualitative (e.g., Tokarcyk et al., 2007) studies of familiness are demonstrating its importance as a family business resource. 7 The input from family systems to strategic entrepreneurship processes may not always be positive. Research clearly indicates that the family and the relationships within it can be an impediment relative to nonfamily firms, rather than a valuable resource (e.g., Chrisman et al. 2005). The complex set of social, cultural, and economic conditions that may yield distinct advantages for one family business may result in dysfunctional or ‘constrictive familiness’ in other settings (Chrisman, Chua, and Steier, 2005). Sibling rivalries, conflicts over ownership and control, and difficulties transferring the management reins from one generation to another are among the factors that can rob a family firm of the advantages it might otherwise enjoy (e.g., Miller, Steier, and Le Breton Miller, 2003). These potential problems and the dangers of nepotism have inspired writers since Weber (1904/5) to favor the professionalization of management and discount the advantages that families might be able to bestow on organizations. Hence, the extent to which the family is a positive or negative resource remains a rich research question. Organizational resources In many types of organizations, trust—the ‘willingness of a party to be vulnerable to the actions of another party’ (Mayer, Davis, and Schoorman (1995: 712)—represents an essential ingredient of economic exchange. Family-based organizations are in a unique position to provide a climate of trust as a key resource and source of competitive advantage. Family firms that incorporate trust into their governance mechanisms (Eddleston et al., 2010) can confer organizational benefits relative to nonfamily firms if it leads to greater reduction in coordination costs. Trust, however, can be taken too far in family businesses if it becomes a substitute for professional management. It is incumbent on family firms to strive for levels of ‘optimal trust,’ as there are situations where too much trust can disadvantage an organization (Eddleston et al., 2010). 8 For many firms, strategic advantage ‘resides in the social capital (or relational wealth) they are able to nourish and maintain’ (Steier, 2001: 259). Social capital represents the goodwill and resources made available to an actor via reciprocal, trusting relationships (Arregle et al., 2007). From a resource-based view of the firm, social capital is a particular source of strategic advantage when it is valuable, rare, costly to imitate, and without substitutes (Barney, 1991). Family firms represent unique repositories of personal and organizational social capital (Steier, 2001) that are hard to duplicate in nonfamily firms. Furthermore, family firms demonstrate unusual capabilities of transferring this resource; for example, from incumbent leaders to successors (Steier, 2001) and/or from family social capital to organizational social capital (Arregle et al., 2007). In other words, family represents a unique social grouping wherein strategic advantages residing in relationships can be passed from one member to another and/or between groups. Processes Processes constitute a second key category within our framework. Here we identify three key processes important to strategic entrepreneurship in family firms: orchestrating resources, creating economic value, and creating socioemotional wealth. Orchestrating resources The concept of resource orchestration is highlighted in recent research that suggests effective strategic entrepreneurship requires organizational leaders to acquire, organize, and deploy resources for optimal advantage (Ndofor, Sirmon, and He, 2011; Sirmon, Hitt, and Ireland, 2007; Chirico et al., 2011). Such activities highlight the value of using resources to both explore and exploit entrepreneurial opportunities. Not only must organizations develop processes aimed at 9 effectively bundling and leveraging resources, but to be successful, advantageous configurations of resources need to be managed dynamically in response to changing conditions. Among the process-related approaches to entrepreneurship that have emerged from the strategy literature, entrepreneurial orientation (EO) is one of the most frequently studied (Rauch et al., 2009). EO reflects the organizational processes, methods, and styles that enable firms to identify and create venture opportunities (Lumpkin and Dess, 1996). Family business researchers have found EO to be a useful framework for investigating entrepreneurship in family businesses (e.g., Naldi et al., 2007; Nordqvist, Habbershon, and Melin, 2008). Salvato (2004) used the EO framework to demonstrate that entrepreneurship manifests itself differently in three different types of family firms—founder-centered, sibling/cousin, and open family firms. Zahra (2005) examined how various family business characteristics and ownership structures (e.g., CEO tenure, extent of family ownership) impact risk taking, which is one of the key dimensions of EO. Kellermanns and colleagues (2008), using a modified measure of EO, found that firm size and number of generations in the firm were significantly positively associated with entrepreneurial behavior and that entrepreneurial behavior was a significant predictor of employee growth (Kellermanns et al., 2008). Several studies have shown that to fully appreciate the role of entrepreneurial orientation in understanding firm performance, EO must be evaluated in multivariate configurations with other variables such as environmental factors and organizational resources (e.g., Wiklund and Shepherd, 2005). This was the conclusion of Chirico et al. (2011) who examined the impact of entrepreneurial orientation and other forces on family firm performance. Their paper constitutes a test of the resource orchestration concept, which suggests that resources must be effectively leveraged to contribute to competitive advantages and superior performance (Sirmon et al., 10 2007). In the Chirico et al. (2011) study, generational involvement is the resource that needs to be leveraged and leveraging consists of using EO processes to mobilize and participative strategy making to coordinate. Their findings indicate that EO, when combined with increasing generational involvement, contributed negatively to firm performance. But when participative strategy making was used to coordinate generational involvement at the same time that EO provided the mobilizing vision, performance was strong. Hence, the findings support the view that a configuration of multiple variables was required to explain the phenomenon. While entrepreneurial behavior is critically important to a firm’s survivability and growth (Lumpkin and Dess, 1996), there are also certain ‘configurations’ of strategy and structure (Miller, 1986) that confer advantage. Miller (1986), drawing on insights from Porter’s (1980) study of competitive strategies, highlights four broad dimensions of competitive strategy: differentiation, focus, cost leadership, and asset parsimony. Miller further (1986) discusses how successful integration of strategy and structure can be achieved by offering illustrative examples such as, simple niche marketers, mechanistic cost leaders and innovating adhocracies. Each of these strategic approaches requires organizational processes and well-adapted resource configurations to be effective. Miller and Le Breton-Miller (2005) also examined successful family firms and noted that certain elements of their internal processes enabled them to gain competitive advantages relative to their nonfamily counterparts. They described these advantages along four axes, referring to them as the four C’s—continuity (unusually long time horizons and farsighted goals), community (unusual care of employees, including an engaging culture), connection (a focus on enduring relationships outside the firm), and command (the ability to make quick and bold decisions). In family firms, these four C’s are uniquely configured to support more generic 11 strategies such as quality, cost, or innovation. The ability to leverage these capabilities gives family firms strategic advantages. The four C’s function as resources that family firms are able to configure to their advantage. For all firms, appropriate resources are necessary but insufficient to achieve a competitive advantage (Sirmon and Hitt, 2003). Resources must also be bundled and managed in specific ways to achieve optimum advantage. For Sirmon and Hitt (2003: 353) family firms enjoy ‘special niches’ in the competitive landscape and—relative to their nonfamily counterparts—enjoy higher levels of ‘social capital, patient capital, and survivability capital…’ Earlier we discussed social capital as part of organizational resources. Patient capital is often a unique feature of family firms because they typically have longer time horizons and are not as accountable for short-term deliverables as their nonfamily counterparts. Similarly, the duality of family and business relationships (Sirmon and Hitt, 2003: 343) often translates into a repository of ‘survivability capital’ wherein family members contribute personal resources such as ‘free labor, loaned labor, additional investments, or monetary loans.’ The combination of these unique resources makes family firms much more durable organizations than nonfamily firms. An important aspect of the durability of family businesses is their ability to orchestrate resources over time to maintain entrepreneurship. In this issue, Sieger et al. (2011) shed light on this point in the context of the role of different resources in facilitating portfolio entrepreneurship behavior. They show that portfolio entrepreneurship declines for industry-specific human capital, stays constant for industry-specific reputation and industry-specific social capital, and increases for meta-industry human capital, meta-industry reputation, and meta-industry social capital. Creating economic value Ireland, Hitt, and Sirmon (2003) identified the combination of advantage seeking and opportunity seeking as the central idea behind strategic entrepreneurship. These processes enable 12 organizations to identify value-adding innovations, technological capabilities, economic conditions, or market disequilibria that can be explored and exploited to create economic value by forming a new venture or extending the competitive success of an existing organization (Hitt et al., 2011). Family firms, because of the unique advantages they bring to the value-creation process, may be in a relatively stronger position to build and appropriate economic value than nonfamily firms. For example, Chirico and Salvato (2008) suggest that family businesses may have advantages in knowledge integration associated with organizational adaptation because the family setting kindles denser social interactions and a stronger willingness to integrate knowledge compared to nonfamily firms. Another example, as noted briefly earlier, relates to family firms’ ability to leverage resources more efficiently because of their long-term orientation. Zellweger (2007) posited that family firms can create just as much shareholder value by investing in lower-return projects as their nonfamily counterparts because their use of patient capital enables them to postpone gains. Such advantages are likely to be associated with greater long-term economic value creation by family firms. Despite the advantages patient capital or richer knowledge integration may bestow, the family-based governance processes associated with those and other family business activities may be an impediment to value creation. Strong control of family resources by a dominant coalition may obstruct investments generally; relationship conflict may hamper knowledge integration (Chirico and Salvato, 2008). Different ownership regimes have also been found to advantage family firms in some cases but limit their competitive capabilities in other cases. Owner-managed family businesses and those with high concentrations of ownership are thought to escape many of the agency-related problems associated with the separation of management and ownership (Schulze et al., 2001). Once ownership becomes more dispersed into forms such 13 as sibling partnerships and cousin consortiums (Ward and Dolan, 1998), control systems become less effective and may disadvantage family-owned businesses (Schulze, Lubatkin, and Dino, 2003). Recent research into ownership concentration by business groups has identified few advantages for family-based groups, despite long-held beliefs that family bonds are durable and powerful, especially in emerging markets (Khanna and Rivkin, 2006). The findings from the study by Singal and Singal (2011) provide some further insights into this by showing that firms with concentrated ownership outperform firms with dispersed ownership; however, controlling for ownership there is no significant difference between familycontrolled firms and firms controlled by foreign corporations or the state. This study relates to the Indian context and it would be interesting to examine whether the findings also apply in other contexts. For now, the preponderance of evidence seems to suggest that family ownership does not afford value-creating advantages, except possibly among closely held and managed family firms. Creating socioemotional wealth Prior research indicates that even though family businesses consistently prioritize financial concerns, they also report that nonfinancial objectives are highly important (e.g., McCann, LeonGuerrero, and Haley, 2001). Thus, there is a good chance that the organizational processes family firms engage in are not focused exclusively on economic wealth creation, but also include socioemotional wealth creation (Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007). Creating socioemotional wealth is described as the type of activities that a family business might engage in to ‘meet the family’s affective needs, such as identity, the ability to exercise family influence, and the perpetuation of the family dynasty’ (Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007: 106). As such, the processes involved in creating socioemotional wealth include doing what is required to achieve the types of nonpecuniary goals 14 that family firms are likely to strive toward—creating family harmony (Chrisman et al., forthcoming), maintaining a positive community image and respect (Dyer and Whetten, 2006), passing the business on to successive generations (Chua, Chrisman, and Sharma, 1999), integrating family values into the business system (Handler, 1990), expressing altruism toward family member employees (Schulze et al., 2003), and achieving family independence and security (Tagiuri and Davis, 1992). Family business researchers have built upon strategy and entrepreneurship research to investigate a range of nonfinancial outcome variables. For example, Sorenson (2000) asked family business owner-managers to assess four family outcomes, including family independence and satisfaction, tight-knit family, respect in community, and child and business development. In a study of outcome and dependent variables across 12 years of family business research, Yu et al. (forthcoming) identified a wide array of outcome variables that had appeared in family business research, including satisfaction, commitment, and family values. Clearly, family businesses are motivated not only to financial wealth creation but also to socioemotional wealth creation. An important question for strategic entrepreneurship researchers is whether efforts to achieve these socioemotional goals complement or compete with processes to attain an organization’s financial goals. Socioemotional goals may provide a richer context in which to move toward financial goals because the concern for the family firm extends beyond the business itself to the family. However, many family business owners may have either a ‘family-first’ or ‘business-first’ attitude so that decisions made in favor of one often jeopardize the other (Schuman, Stutz, and Ward, 2010). For example, a business-first attitude that is too strong could result in asking too much of family members and damaging family relationships. By contrast, a 15 family-first decision-making process could keep peace in the family but result in poor business decisions that affect the reputation or viability of the business. How socioemotional goals affect the opportunity-seeking and advantage-seeking behaviors of family firms is a fruitful area for future research. Zellweger and Nason (2008) provide an interesting initial study adopting a stakeholder theory approach to examine the potential relationships between performance outcomes satisfying different stakeholders in family firms. Outputs Our framework also suggests four key outputs relevant—and somewhat unique—to family firms. These include: individual benefits, family benefits, organizational benefits, and societal benefits. Individual benefits The payoffs for individuals working in family firms can be numerous. For family firm members, there is the opportunity to participate in the creation of family wealth, not just as a beneficiary of the family fortune by virtue of inheritance, but also as a senior decision maker responsible for protecting, managing, and leveraging the family’s wealth. There is also the satisfaction of working within a family system which, under the right circumstances, can be highly fulfilling (Sharma, Chrisman, and Chua, 2003). For younger family members, a family business can provide an opportunity for unique work or professional experiences that may not be available to others. Even for nonfamily members, there are benefits to involvement with a family business, especially where the business offers financial stability and a favorable work environment. Working for a family business can be emotionally, cognitively, and financially satisfying. However, some of the same factors that can benefit individuals might, under different circumstances, manifest detrimentally. Nonfamily members run the risk of feeling marginalized or treated unfairly in family businesses. A struggling family business, as opposed to one that is 16 thriving, may make unreasonable demands on family members by asking them to work for poor wages or inhibiting their freedom to pursue other goals. In family businesses where conflict is high and trust is low, work can become drudgery, especially for family members who are surrounded by troubling relationships. Family benefits The benefits to a family that owns and operates a family enterprise may depend on how successful the business is. Family firms with informed strategies, efficient operations, and thoughtful leadership can create substantial wealth for a family, both economic and socioemotional. Even a family business that is only modestly successful financially may provide benefits to a family that values qualities such as trust, loyalty, and interdependence (Lumpkin, Martin, and Vaughn, 2008). Other values, such as those associated with a strong parental influence, may also benefit family firms. Ensley and Pearson (2005: 279) found that parental top management teams (TMTs) financially outperformed firms with nonfamily TMTs and had ‘a stronger belief in their abilities, a greater sense of belonging to the team, greater consensus on the strategic direction of the firms, and less detrimental conflict.’ The family may also benefit from prestige and reputation in the local community. These benefits may extend to the wider family beyond members who are immediately involved in the running of the business. Similarly, when the time comes for succession, there may be important family benefits from ensuring that the succession is seen to maintain the family’s reputation. Even where succession involves transferring the family business outside family ownership, there may be benefits to the family in ensuring that the firm is sold to a friendly buyer, for example through a management buyout (Howorth, Westhead, and Wright , 2004) who will ensure the continuity and development of the business in the locality. Such a sale may mean that family 17 owners need to ensure that they develop a second tier management team who can take over the business and have the capabilities to identify and exploit future entrepreneurial opportunities. Although there may be private benefits, there are also potential downsides to the family per se through being closely associated with the family business (Dyck and Zingales, 2004). The negative impact on the family locally from unwanted publicity or notoriety may help constrain the extent to which family businesses engage in nonethical business practices. There are positive benefits in the fulfillment of seeing the next generation build on and extend a family legacy, but handled badly, negative effects may arise that involve tearing the family apart through lawsuits or litigation; these may have a detrimental effect on the entrepreneurial development of the business, as management is distracted from recognizing opportunities and threats and adapting resources accordingly. Organizational benefits Strategic entrepreneurship is fundamentally concerned with a quest to make organizations more effective. As organizations ‘dominate’ our socioeconomic landscape (Baum and Rowley, 2002) it is paramount to understand the implications of different forms of organizing because of how they provide the contexts within which strategic decisions are made (Bradach and Eccles, 1989; Williamson, 1975, 1985). Throughout the world, familial capitalism presents alternatives to market and hierarchical forms of organization and is closely linked to entrepreneurial activity (Steier, 2009b). Familial-owned, controlled, and/or managed firms confer certain benefits versus their nonfamily counterparts. We note that there are an infinite number of organizational permutations and contexts relative to family-influenced firms; and the benefits they confer are embedded within a variety of theoretical perspectives. Next we offer a number of examples of 18 these perspectives, including stewardship, agency, altruism, corporate brand identity, and resource-based views. Altruism, defined as the selfless regard for the well-being of others provides useful explanations for human behavior beyond economic self-interest (Simon, 1993). Altruistic behavior is particularly manifest in family firms (Schulze, et al., 2003) and may well provide benefits to organizations that prioritize socioemotional wealth creation. Family members often assume the role of stewards who, by investing in the firm over the long term, create enduring value for stakeholders. Stewardship theory can be used to address the organizational benefits associated with nonpecuniary goals. Agency theory, by contrast, is typically linked to financial benefits. Traditional agency theory posits that when the same people own and manage a firm there will be no agency costs (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Of course family firms, by virtue of combining ownership and management, are in unique positions to enjoy reduced agency costs (Gomez-Mejia, Nuñez-Nickel, and Gutierrez, 2001; Schulze et al., 2001). Le Breton-Miller, Miller, and Lester (2011) explore these two competing governance perspectives relative to family firms—stewardship and agency—and report that, depending on the circumstances, either of these features provide benefits. Identity theory suggests that family firms have the option of ‘intertwining’ family and firm when seeking strategic advantage. Micelotta and Raynard (2011: 199) highlight three strategic variations or choices relative to corporate brand identity: ‘family preservation, family enrichment, and family subordination.’ For example, family businesses can use their family identity as a marketing device to gain organizational benefits; this may be especially important if their trading partners are also family businesses. A ‘family company’ brand may, however, be 19 beneficial in some industries (consumer products, local, etc.), but detrimental in others (high tech, accounting, medical, etc.). Family firms enjoy certain resources and advantages that are rare and hard to imitate. While organizations may benefit through accessing financial, human and social resources from the family, from a resource-based view perspective, it is those family-specific resources that are rare and inimitable that will make the distinctive contribution. For example, Sirmon et al. (2008: 993) examine firms’ strategic responses to the threat of imitation and find that those firms that are best able to create hybrid governance structures—those that ‘integrate the best of family and nonfamily firms’—are often best suited to meet the threat of imitation. There may also be a darker side to organizational effects, where resource flows go from the organization to the family through the funding of particular lifestyles by means of large dividends and lack of investment All of these theoretical perspectives highlight the potential of familial-based ways of organizing an enterprise to confer certain advantages to it; they also further demonstrate the complexity of organizing these complex resources. We trust that the field of strategic entrepreneurship, including the articles in this special issue, will usefully contribute to further understanding how complex familial resources might usefully be assembled. Societal benefits Family firms have a profound influence on economic development and societal wealth creation throughout the world (Morck and Steier, 2005). This influence is a most interesting empirical phenomenon. For example, family firms have been represented as both ‘pariahs’ and ‘paragons’ of economic development (Carney and Gedajlovic, 2002; Steier, 2009a). Thurow (1989) makes a similar distinction and represents them as falling within two broad categories: ‘oligarchs’ that are driven largely by selfish interests and tend to be exploitive; and, ‘establishments’ that care 20 greatly about the larger society and see the best interests of this larger society as closely aligned with their own. As an organizational form, family firms are remarkably resilient (Morck and Steier, 2005) and oftentimes demonstrate an extraordinary capacity to change should the broader context demand it (Khanna and Palepu, 2005). Of course, the societal benefits of familial capitalism are not just limited to large firms. Family involvement is manifest in the creation and evolution of small firms everywhere. Here again the creative mobilization of familial resources represents an important dimension of the entrepreneurial process. A fundamental concern of the fields of strategic management and entrepreneurship is the search for rents (Mahoney and Pandian, 1992). Rents are the return in excess of the resource owner’s opportunity costs. Within societal contexts, we believe it is important to broaden the dialogue from a singular focus on profit to include a discussion of the type of profit or rent. Firms can be seen as exacting four different kinds of rents: monopolistic, political, Ricardian, and entrepreneurial (Schumpeterian). Oligarchs typically rely on monopolistic and/or political rents that are not in the best interests of the broader society whereas Ricardian and—in particular—entrepreneurial rents offer much greater benefits to society. For family firms (even those that were essentially entrepreneurial at the time of creation), it is particularly seductive to seek political and/or monopolistic rents (Morck and Yeung, 2004). In other words, entrepreneurs who accumulate certain means of production are often in positions of power where they can organize those means to exploit others. For policy makers and researchers alike, it is important to identify those conditions and actions that promote entrepreneurial activity. Importantly, the papers in this special issue illuminate entrepreneurial activity in various parts of the world. Context 21 Most strategic management literature includes context as an important aspect of firm survival and success. Our framework includes four key contextual dimensions relevant to strategic entrepreneurship in family firms: institutional environment/family as an institution; local conditions/national culture and geography; ownership regimes/multigenerational involvement and succession; and temporal considerations/planning horizons and business life cycles. Institutional environment/family as an institution The initial call for papers for this special issue noted that ‘family was manifest in both the creation and organization of most of the world’s firms.’ Indeed, the submissions—and eventually the papers selected for publication—further reflect the global importance of family businesses. This special issue contains data sets and/or cases based on family firms located in various parts of the world: Switzerland, Ireland, France, Chile, Guatemala, Sweden, and India. While each paper addresses strategic entrepreneurship themes, collectively their varied geographic focus suggests that institutional context merits further attention. Indeed, institutional environments shape entrepreneurial activity. Similar to the emerging field of transnational entrepreneurship (Drori, Honig, and Wright, 2009: 1010), there is a need ‘to understand how varied institutional contexts and differences shape the ways’ in which family firms operate and facilitate productive entrepreneurship. Institutional context greatly influences manifestations of entrepreneurship at the individual and country level (Morck and Steier, 2005). Relatedly, the varieties of capitalism (VOC) literature (Orru, 1997; Hall and Soskice, 2001; Steier, 2009a) suggests that institutional context varies considerably across countries. Indeed, family businesses throughout the world operate within ‘a variegated collection of economic systems’ (Morck and Steier, 2005: 1). Although family firms can be found everywhere, they have distinctly different manifestations 22 and roles (La Porta et al., 1999). In other words, strategic entrepreneurship in family firms is greatly influenced by the institutional context (Orru, 1997; Steier, 2009b). According to commonly used VOC categorizations (Orru, 1997), the papers in this particular issue represent family business activity in distinctly different contexts: north, central, and southern Europe; south Asia; and South America. Much of the existing literature on entrepreneurship and family firms assumes a homogeneity largely influenced by AngloAmerican views of capitalism (Steier, 2009b). We view the varied geographic focus of the articles in this special issue as contributing to understanding the richer mosaic of strategic entrepreneurship in family firms throughout the world. However, collectively they also signal the need for comparative frameworks that further incorporate institutional context as a key variable. Entrepreneurs have a key role in economic development (Baumol, 1990). However, they do not necessarily have a bias toward productive innovation—their bias is toward profit. Similarly, some family firms are biased toward rent seeking (Morck and Yeung, 2004) as opposed to true value creation. Societal- and country-level institutions play important roles in determining the allocation of entrepreneurial effort (Baumol, 1990); hence, incorporating institutional contexts and effects greatly enhances the explanatory power of strategic entrepreneurship and family business. Local conditions/national culture and geography Despite increased globalization of markets and production, differences between countries remain ‘larger than generally acknowledged’ and it remains important to understand the nuances associated with this heterogeneity (Ghemawat, 2007: 9). Strategic entrepreneurship at the family level continues to be influenced by factors such as local conditions, national culture, and geography (Chrisman, Chua, and Steier, 2002). Next, we briefly discuss these factors. 23 At the local level, powerful social contexts such as household and/or ethnicity affect the venture-creation process (Rodriguez, Tuggle, and Hackett, 2009). Households are usefully viewed as opportunity platforms or incubators, wherein venture creation is influenced by factors such as the financial, social, and health context of the household (Steier, 2009a). In other words, some households preoccupied with certain demands, such as financial concerns or the care of a sick relative, will have a lower propensity to found a new venture whereas certain other households with relatively few resources embrace entrepreneurship as a way of changing economic circumstances. A large number of entrepreneurs often attribute their success to supportive family members. Familial responsibilities and or culture further circumscribe the venture-creation process; for example, Khavul, Bruton, and Wood (2009) examine the creation of small firms in East Africa and highlight the influence of strong family and community ties. The national welfare mix also affects the venture-creation process at the local level (Steier, 2009b) and there is a great deal of variation throughout the world as to whether the state, the market, or the family unit is left to perform essential welfare functions such as care of the elderly or children. Each of these generic models—state, market, family—shape entrepreneurial activity in different ways. Two additional boundaries useful for examining entrepreneurial activity in familial contexts include national culture and geography (Chrisman et al., 2002). National culture has long been closely linked to economic success (Landes, 1998) and is particularly relevant within the realm of entrepreneurship (Shane, Venkataraman, and MacMillan, 1995). Similarly, geographic regions have a profound influence on economic activity and continue to provide useful boundaries for conducting entrepreneurship research (Audretsch, 2001). Saxenian (1994) suggests that there is a strong correlation between regional culture and regional advantage. 24 The studies in this special issue exhibit considerable variety in terms of local conditions, national cultural, and region. However, they devote relatively little attention to these dimensions. We believe that, in regard to future research relative to strategic entrepreneurship in family firms, there are considerable opportunities to incorporate this variation in theory building. We return to this point later. Ownership regimes/multigenerational involvement and succession Family businesses may be characterized by heterogeneous ownership and governance regimes that influence the objectives, strategic entrepreneurship processes, and performance of the firm. Family businesses may involve ownership and management by founders and/or subsequent generations. The ownership distribution may be tightly held or become more diffuse with future generations, many of whose members may not be part of the management of the firm but who exert other influences on its direction (Gersick et al., 1997; Westhead and Howorth, 2007). The configuration of the ownership may also be influential in determining entrepreneurial activities, for example whether relationships between family members are husband-wife, siblings, cousins, extended families, etc. Family businesses may be privately owned, but in some jurisdictions large numbers of listed corporations have significant residual family ownership and control, as well as an ethos of family values. Privately held family businesses may be more likely to pursue stewardship objectives and construct boards comprising individuals whose perspectives are consistent with this. Publicly held family businesses may be more obliged to introduce boards with independent directors in order to comply with corporate governance regulations. Yet, while publicly listed family businesses may be subject to scrutiny by analysts and demands of institutional investors, family values may endure even where there are no longer any original family members on the 25 board. The extent to which listed family firms are exposed to takeover pressures may also affect approaches to strategic entrepreneurship. For example, firms may become more risk averse and looking for shorter-term payoffs under the threat of takeover. While there has been extensive research on succession in family businesses, this has mainly focused on the challenges relating to the transfer of the firm to the next generation (De Massis et al., 2008), including whether the next generation continue to be involved or set out to develop their own independent firms. Multigenerational involvement raises important contextual issues that may influence strategic entrepreneurship both in terms of the introduction of subsequent generations alongside founders and with respect to the continuing role of the founder when the business has ostensibly been passed on to the next generation (Salvato, Chirico, and Sharma, 2010). On the one hand, founder generations may offer mentoring support and established networks and transfer tacit knowledge and ownership of the business to the next generation at a substantial discount. On the other hand, continued founder involvement may reinforce path dependencies that the next generation may seek to shift as they perceive new opportunities in the context of changing market conditions. Further, as ownership moves to the next generation yet only a subset of family members continue to be involved in the business, conflicts may emerge with those family members who are no longer involved but retain an ownership stake; this may constrain strategic entrepreneurship. Yet, transfers to outside owners, either through a management buyout or corporate acquisition, are quite frequent and raise issues concerning both the rationale for such transfers (Howorth et al., 2004) and the effects on strategic entrepreneurship and family values. The paper by Nordqvist et al. (2011) sheds some light on this issue, to which we return later. Temporal considerations/planning horizons and business life cycles 26 Business forecasting and planning are traditional functions of strategic managers who are charged with overseeing the long range vision of an organization. However, as the practice and field of strategy have evolved over the last 40 years, the time horizon for planning has shrunk and the importance of planning has diminished. Dynamic markets, hypercompetition, and rapidly evolving technologies are among the forces that have demanded decision makers to shelve strategic plans in favor of a bias for action and opportunity–driven adaptability (D’Aveni, 1994; Bettis and Hitt, 1995). For publicly traded firms, quarterly performance expectations often demand that strategic managers focus on short-term results at the expense of long range considerations. Family businesses have not been insulated from the pressure to rapidly adapt and be effective in the short run. But unlike many nonfamily firms, most family businesses approach strategic decision making with a long-term orientation (Zahra, Hayton, and Salvato, 2004). Family firm owners that aspire to maintain sufficient control of a business to pass it on to the next generation weigh long range consequences differently. Hence, the long-term viability of family firms is an important driver in strategic decision making (Zellweger, 2007). This perspective affects many organizational decisions. For example, a willingness to consider long run outcomes may lead family firms to invest ‘patient capital’ in resources they do not anticipate liquidating (Sirmon and Hitt, 2003). Research indicates that family firms often outperform nonfamily firms on a range of performance measures (Anderson and Reeb, 2003). Based on an in-depth study of 40 highperforming family-controlled businesses, Miller and Le Breton-Miller (2005) concluded that one of the major reasons the strongest family firms tended to financially outperform nonfamily firms was because of their long-term orientation. Whether a long-term orientation benefits or impedes 27 the performance of entrepreneurial family firms, however, remains unclear. In an analysis of how short-term versus long-term considerations might affect the entrepreneurial orientation of family firms, Lumpkin, Brigham, and Moss (2010: 255) concluded that ‘innovativeness, proactiveness, and autonomy are more likely to thrive in a climate where long-term values are favored; risk taking and competitive aggressiveness, by contrast, are less likely to be highlighted in companies that manage for the long run.’ Hence, the long time horizon most family businesses exhibit will generally, but not always, favor entrepreneurial action. This is especially interesting in light of the findings by Nordqvist et al. (2011). On the one hand, they concluded that family firms are most likely merely acting rationally when they transfer ownership of relatively more risky businesses to external owners. On the other hand, their study finds that firms transferred to external owners have higher long-term performance despite the fact that the firms are sold under conditions of greater uncertainty and likely face riskier futures. This suggests that the appetite for some types of entrepreneurial behavior, such as risk taking, may be lower in family firms that are trying to ensure their long-term survival. A further issue in assessing whether temporal considerations will encourage or prevent a family firm from being more entrepreneurial is whether it is a first-, second-, or later-generation business. Interaction between inputs and environmental factors The business environment plays an important role in shaping and influencing family business outcomes. However, the environmental forces that influence family firms are not appreciably different from those affecting all other firms. Hence, strategic entrepreneurship researchers can, in general, turn to prior studies for insights about the role of environmental factors on the strategic entrepreneurship process (Hitt et al., 2001). 28 Other environmental factors may, however, constitute important inputs for family businesses. For example, family firms are more common than nonfamily firms in regions that are relatively less economically developed (Chang et al., 2008). This represents an opportunity for family firms to thrive in part because of their unique ability to marshal private resources and in part because of their relationship to local authorities. On the one hand, family firms are often willing to operate independently of governmental support or sanction; on the other hand, family firms may be linked with local power brokers in ways that favor their business activities but may be detrimental to economic development because of corrupt practices (cf. Morck and Yeung, 2004). Hence, regional economic conditions and local governance practices may play an important role in whether or not family businesses prosper, especially in emerging economies. DISCUSSION OF FUTURE RESEARCH AGENDA Although considerable progress has been made in research on family businesses, major research avenues remain to be explored on the interface between strategic entrepreneurship and family business. In this section, we elaborate a potential future research agenda that builds upon the framework developed in previous sections. The principal research questions are summarized in Table 2. INSERT TABLE 2 ABOUT HERE Inputs Attention to the microfoundations of strategic entrepreneurship in family businesses emphasizes the need to understand the behavior of individuals and families within family businesses. On the one hand, there is a need to examine whether and how the cognitive characteristics of family business entrepreneurs differ from entrepreneurs in nonfamily businesses. This analysis needs to encompass both entrepreneurial individuals and teams within family businesses. A major 29 challenge for family businesses may arise in the transition from first to subsequent generations, in that important cognitive attributes may be lost if founders leave the business. An important issue concerns the extent to which founders of family businesses can or are able to do things that will enable their children to perform better when they take over the family business. For example, to what extent do parents act as role models, imbue value systems, and employ offspring in the family business? To what extent is this process limiting because it involves the inculcation of biases that are detrimental to future performance? Further qualitative analysis is needed on whether and how families introduce and nurture the requirements for entrepreneurial activity in conjunction with the specifics of the family’s business. Extending this point further, this analysis could consider whether this process leads to differences between offspring of family business owners who take up the family firm and those that go on to create their own business. The context of a family business may affect how learning occurs within the business and how learning from outside the business is incorporated as inputs into the future development of the firm. For example, family values and management styles may make it difficult to incorporate information and knowledge relating to new market developments that do not accord with the established modus operandi. This may be true of all organizations to some extent, and further analysis is needed to examine whether and how family businesses differ in their learning from nonfamily firms. Like entrepreneurs in general (Ucbasaran, Westhead, and Wright, 2009), family firms may engage in multiple ventures that are sequential or concurrent. Yet, the extent to which family support may encourage or impede both the extent and nature of subsequent entrepreneurial activity is little understood. Further, habitual entrepreneurs may learn different 30 lessons from prior entrepreneurial experience depending on whether it was successful or not (Ucbasaran et al., 2010). It is unclear whether and how family pressures influence learning from prior experience. For example, if prior failure is perceived as having a detrimental impact on the family’s wider reputation and wealth, there may be pressure either to adopt more risk-averse strategies or to exit from future entrepreneurship. Family businesses with more diffuse nonmanagerial owners may be more susceptible to these pressures than other family businesses or ventures owned by nonfamily habitual entrepreneurs. Does the glue of the family lead to more support for subsequent entrepreneurial efforts compared to teams that are not family related? Or are some families able to institutionalize learning (good and bad) from previous entrepreneurial ventures, which can be leveraged by future family member start-ups? There is some recognition of the importance of initial resource endowments for the subsequent development of ventures. For example, Clarysse, Bruneel, and Wright (2011) have analyzed the differences in technological resources endowments for university and corporate spin-offs. Research on imprinting has also considered the impact of initial conditions that effectively set in train the development of subsequent path dependencies. Detailed analysis is required of the dimensions of the initial founding conditions that are unique to family firms and how these affect subsequent development trajectories. Relatedly, the initial allocation of familybased resources may also influence subsequent development. For example, the initial provision of financial, human, social, or organizational resources may create difficult to reverse original configurations of family involvement and ownership that owe more to obligations to family members than to the effective running of the business. What aspects of these obligations and commitments create the greatest challenges for family businesses? Processes 31 As with entrepreneurship and management research more generally (Barney, Ketchen, and Wright, 2011), we know relatively little about the processes involved in the creation and development of strategic entrepreneurship in family businesses. How do resource accumulation, configuration, and coordination differ in family businesses compared to nonfamily businesses? How do family businesses sustain the processes of entrepreneurial activity over time through the development of serial family business entrepreneurs? Are family businesses particularly susceptible to ingrained path dependencies in their processes that make it difficult to change when environmental conditions change? Qualitative analysis is needed to compare how some family businesses successfully make this shift while others do not. An interesting initial study in this direction is provided by Salvato et al. (2010). Businesses face major challenges in moving from one phase of development to another (e.g., Vohora, Wright, and Lockett, 2004). We know little, however, about the processes that family businesses adopt to transform their enterprises strategically as they grow, professionalize, and introduce external capital and nonfamily managers. Further, insights are lacking concerning the specific barriers in this development process faced by family businesses compared to nonfamily firms. The influence of family on the process of firm development may be particularly important in respect to two activities that involve less routine actions. Both innovation and internationalization present risks for all firms. Further research is required to examine to what extent family values, diffuse ownership, and governance facilitate or impede these processes. For example, if family businesses are able to take a longer-term perspective, perhaps they can engage in greater experimentation in how they undertake innovation and internationalization. Outputs 32 We noted that there is a need to examine the cognitive composition of entrepreneurial teams as inputs into the strategic entrepreneurship process in family businesses. There is also a need to consider the impact of the loss of tacit knowledge and the ability to identify and exploit opportunities when family businesses are transferred to the next generation. Such a loss may lead to a decline in performance and even failure. Recognition of the heterogeneity of family business types also calls for examination of their differential impacts on performance. Poor performance following the exit of founders and their tacit knowledge and entrepreneurial cognition may lead to reacquisition by the founder at a significantly lower price. Studies are warranted that examine the extent of this phenomenon. Additional issues relate to whether the founder is able to rescue the business and whether this leads to short-term or longerterm recovery. Further analysis is warranted concerning whether the founder is ‘part of the solution or part of the problem.’ In other words, to what extent is the founder able and willing to put in place successor management who will be able to continue the business into the future when the founder really is no longer able to run the firm? This issue may have implications both for the continued wealth generation of the family and for the returns that investors may be seeking when they reinvest in exited family founders. In contrast to some earlier perspectives, recent developments have recognized that family firms may be entrepreneurial; however empirical work on the innovativeness of family businesses compared to nonfamily businesses remains limited. Family objectives concerned with ensuring longevity may mean that the firm becomes risk averse, which may create challenges in a sector where continued innovation is important. Moreover, the heterogeneity of innovation needs to be recognized and analysis undertaken not just in terms of whether family businesses are more or less innovative, but whether they undertake different types of innovation. 33 Alternatively, there may be a selection effect in that family entrepreneurs with more innovative cognition enter into ventures in innovative sectors. While family businesses may possess an initial set of innovative capabilities, questions arise concerning whether these firms possess, develop, or can acquire the expertise they need to continue to be innovative. For example, challenges may arise in recruiting nonfamily members with the requisite expertise if such individuals perceive they will be disadvantaged in career progress in relation to family members. Alternatively, family firms may encourage younger generations to gain expertise in other environments that can enable them to be more innovative when they return to the family business. Both quantitative and qualitative research is needed in this area. Quantitative analysis may help establish whether family firms are less innovative than nonfamily firms in similar sectors. Qualitative research is needed that examines the processes of innovation in family firms and how family objectives and structures influence the timing and nature of innovation. Qualitative research may be able to untangle the richness of processes related to the resistance and conflicts that may arise when some individuals challenge entrenched founders with innovative proposals that may, on the one hand, be risky but, on the other hand, be vital to ensure the longevity of the business. Context We have commented on the role of different institutional contexts in the study of family businesses. Additional research is needed that considers how familial capitalism and entrepreneurship differ across contexts. Such research needs to recognize the heterogeneity of contexts and how these influence family business. While emphasis tends to be placed on institutional context, Zahra and Wright (2011) have suggested four dimensions of contexts. 34 First, spatial context concerns the geographical distribution, concentration, and mobility of family business. Strategic entrepreneurship may vary across international contexts due to differences in the role of family businesses, family business groups, and extended kinship ties. Family human, social, and organizational capital may play important roles in family businesses involved in developing transnational activities, that is, operating in more than one country. For example, family relationships may substitute for cumbersome and incomplete coordination structures and processes across different contexts. Families whose members have previously emigrated to a particular country may provide local knowledge and other resources that can help establish international or transnational activities. Second, temporal context relates to the evolution of family businesses over time and the implications of changes across this life cycle for their continued success. Analysis is needed of how contextual factors may influence the nature and timing of family firm succession and survival. Tax incentives to encourage succession, including sale to outsiders, may change over time or may differ between institutional contexts. The effectiveness of these measures may be moderated in different contexts by cultural resistance to ‘outsiders,’ sale to lifelong competitors, or lack of acceptance of the family firm as a tradable asset. If succession is affected through sale of the family business to outsiders, questions arise as to what extent the family values or ethos are so well entrenched that they continue in some form. Analysis of these challenges could incorporate and add to recent developments in the arena of shifting from established path dependencies. Contextual factors may also influence the extent to which family entrepreneurs and subsequent generations return to entrepreneurship following exit that is occasioned by firm failure. 35 The temporal dimension also concerns variations in time orientations across groups and societies. These variations may have implications for the way in which family businesses in, say, certain emerging economies respond to attempts to integrate these economies into the global marketplace. Third, social context refers to the relationships that develop among multiple groups who influence the emergence, survival, and growth of family businesses. These relationships may differ across institutional contexts and influence the boundaries of family businesses. For example, in contexts where extended families are important, the boundaries of family businesses may be more extensive than elsewhere. Further social context also concerns the complementarities and substitutabilities between family businesses and other forms of organizations. As such, the networks of family firms may play an important role in influencing industry configurations. Finally, the institutional dimension captures the effect of different institutional contexts, including informal cultural aspects and formal regional institutions. CONCLUSION In this special issue, one of our primary objectives was to promote research and understanding of strategic entrepreneurship in familial contexts throughout the world. We trust that we have achieved this objective in a number of ways. First, we include four diverse articles from varied international contexts that utilize multiple methods of inquiry. Second, in addition to offering summaries of and comments one these articles, this introductory article develops a conceptual framework of strategic entrepreneurship in family firms that highlights the input-process-output nature of the process. Third, we discuss opportunities for further research. 36 As family business continues to be the subject of increased scholarly attention, we believe that strategic entrepreneurship offers a unique and useful lens from which to view this organizational phenomenon. We recognize that we offer only a small sampling of what is a very complex area of study. Finally, we strongly encourage others to continue this line of inquiry. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS All authors contributed equally to this article. The authors thank Rob Nason and Nanette Warman for helpful comments on an earlier draft. 37 REFERENCES Anderson RC, Reeb DM. 2003. Founding-family ownership and firm performance: evidence from the S&P 500. The Journal of Finance 58: 1301-1328. Arregle J-L, Hitt MA, Sirmon DG, Very P. 2007. The development of organizational social capital: attributes of family firms. Journal of Management Studies 44: 73-95.Astrachan JH, Shanker MC. 2003. Family businesses’ contribution to the U. S. economy: A closer look. Family Business Review 16(3): 211-220. Audretsch DB. 2001. The role of small firms in U.S. biotechnology clusters. Small Business Economics 17(1/2): 3-15. Barach JA, Gantisky J, Carson JA, Doochin BA. 1988. Entry of the next generation: strategic challenge for family business. Journal of Small Business Management 26(2): 49-56. Barney JB. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management 17(1): 99-120. Barney JB, Ketchen DJ Jr, Wright M. 2011. The future of resource-based theory: revitalization or decline? Journal of Management 37(5): 1299-1315. Baum JAC, Rowley TJ. 2002. Companion to organizations: an introduction. In The Blackwell Companion to Organizations, Baum JAC (ed). Wiley-Blackwell: Oxford, U.K.; 1-34. Baumol WJ. 1990. Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Political Economy 98(5): 893-921. Bettis RA, Hitt MA. 1995. The new competitive landscape. Strategic Management Journal, Special Issue 16: 7-20. Bradach JL, Eccles RG. 1989. Price, authority, and trust: from ideal types to plural forms. Annual Review of Sociology 15: 97-118. 38 Carney M, Gedajlovic E. 2002. The co-evolution of institutional environments and organizational strategies: the rise of family business groups in the ASEAN region. Organization Studies 23(1): 1-29. Chang EPC, Chrisman JJ, Chua JH, Kellermanns FW. 2008. Regional economy as a determinant of the prevalence of family firms in the United States: a preliminary report. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 32(3): 559-573. Chirico F, Salvato C. 2008. Knowledge integration and organizational dynamic adaptation in family firms. Family Business Review 21(2): 169-181. Chirico F, Sirmon D, Sciascia S, Mazzola P. 2011. Resource orchestration in family firms: investigating how entrepreneurial orientation, generational involvement, and participative strategy affect performance. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 5(4). Chrisman JJ, Chua JH, Pearson AW, Barnett T. Family involvement, family influence, and family centered non-economic goals in small firms. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice. Forthcoming. Chrisman JJ, Chua JH, Sharma P. 2005. Trends and directions in the development of a strategic management theory of the family firm. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 29(5): 555-576. Chrisman JJ, Chua JH, Steier LP. 2002. The influence of national culture and family involvement on entrepreneurial perceptions and performance at the state level. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 26(4): 113-130. Chrisman JJ, Chua JH, Steier LP. 2005. Sources and consequences of distinctive familiness: an introduction. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 29(3): 237-247. 39 Chua JH, Chrisman JJ, Sharma P. 1999. Defining the family business by behavior. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 23(4): 19-39. Clarysse B, Bruneel J, Wright M. 2011. Explaining growth paths of young technology-based firms: restructuring resource portfolios in different competitive environments. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 5(2): 137-157. D’Aveni R. 1994. Hypercompetition. Free Press: New York. De Massis A, Chua JH, Chrisman JJ. 2008. Factors preventing intra-family succession. Family Business Review 21(2): 183-199. Drori I, Honig B, Wright M. 2009. Transnational entrepreneurship: an emergent field of study. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 33(5): 1001-1022. Dyck A, Zingales L. 2004. Private benefits of control: an international comparison. Journal of Finance 59(2): 537-600. Dyer WG, Whetten DA. 2006. Family firms and social responsibility: preliminary evidence from the S&P 500. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 30: 785-802. Eddleston KA, Chrisman JJ, Steier LP, Chua JH. 2010. Governance and trust in family firms: an introduction. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 34(6): 1043-1056. Ensley MD, Pearson AW. 2005. An exploratory comparison of the behavioral dynamics of top management teams in family and nonfamily new ventures: cohesion, potency, and consensus. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 29: 267-284. Gersick KE, Davis JA, Hampton MM, Lansberg I. 1997. Generation to Generation: Life Cycles of the Family Business. Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA. Ghemawat P. 2007. Redefining Global Strategy: Crossing Borders in a World Where Differences Still Matter. Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA. 40 Gomez-Mejia L, Cruz C, Berrone P, De Castro J. 2011.The bind that ties: socioemotional wealth preservation in family firms. Academy of Management Annals 5(1): 653-707. Gomez-Mejia LR, Haynes K, Nuñez-Nickel M, Jacobson K, Moyano-Fuentes J. 2007. Socioemotional wealth and business risks in family controlled firms: evidence from Spanish olive oil mills. Administrative Science Quarterly 52: 106-137. Gomez-Mejia LR, Nuñez-Nickel M, Gutierrez I. 2001. The role of family ties in agency contracts. Academy of Management Journal 44: 81-95. Habbershon TG, Williams ML, MacMillian IC. 2003. A unified systems perspective of family firm performance. Journal of Business Venturing 18: 451-466. Hall A, Nordqvist M. 2008. Professional management in family businesses: toward an extended understanding. Family Business Review 21(1): 51-69. Hall PA, Soskice D. 2001. An introduction to varieties of capitalism. In Varieties of Capitalism: Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Hall PA, Soskice D (eds). Oxford University Press: Oxford, U.K.; 1-68. Handler WC. 1990. Succession in family firms: a mutual role adjustment between entrepreneur and next generation family members. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 15(1): 3751. Handler WC, Kram KE. 1988. Succession in family firms: the problem of resistance. Family Business Review 1: 261-381. Hitt MA, Ireland RD, Camp SM, Sexton DL. 2001. Strategic entrepreneurship: entrepreneurial strategies for wealth creation. Strategic Management Journal 22(6/7): 479-491. 41 Hitt MA, Ireland RD, Sirmon DG, Trahms CA. 2011. Strategic entrepreneurship: creating value for individuals, organizations, and society. The Academy of Management Perspectives 25(2): 57-76. Horton TP. 1986. Managing in a family way. Management Review 75(2): 3. Howorth C, Westhead P, Wright M. 2004. Buyouts, information asymmetry and the family management dyad. Journal of Business Venturing 19(4): 509-534. Ireland RD, Hitt MA, Sirmon DG. 2003. Strategic entrepreneurship: The construct and its dimensions. Journal of Management 29(6): 963-989. Jensen MC, Meckling WH. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3(4): 305-360. Kellermanns FW, Eddleston K, Barnett T, Pearson A. 2008. Family member characteristics and involvement: effect on entrepreneurial behavior in the family firm. Family Business Review 21(1): 1-14. Khanna T, Palepu KG. 2005. The evolution of concentrated ownership in India: broad patterns and a history of the Indian software industry. In A History of Corporate Governance Around the World: Family Business Groups to Professional Managers, Morck RK (ed). University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL; 283-324. Khanna T, Rivkin JW. 2006. Interorganizational ties and business group boundaries: evidence from an emerging economy. Organization Science 17(3): 333-352. Khavul S, Bruton GD, Wood E. 2009. Informal family business in Africa. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 33(6): 1219-1238. Landes DS. 1998. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some are so Rich and Some are so Poor. W.W. Norton: New York. 42 La Porta R, López-de-Silanes L, Shleifer A, Vishny R. 1999. Corporate ownership around the world. Journal of Finance 54(2): 471-520. Le Breton-Miller I, Miller D, Lester R. 2011. Stewardship or agency? A social embeddedness reconciliation of conduct and performance in public family businesses. Organization Science 22(3): 704-721. Lumpkin GT, Brigham KH, Moss TW. 2010. Long-term orientation: implications for the entrepreneurial orientation and performance of family businesses. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development 22(3): 241-264. Lumpkin GT, Dess GG. 1996. Clarifying the entrepreneurial orientation construct and linking it to performance. Academy of Management Review 21(1): 135-172. Lumpkin GT, Martin WL, Vaughn M. 2008. Family orientation: individual-level influences on family firm outcomes. Family Business Review 21(2): 127-138. Mahoney JT, Pandian JR. 1992. The resource-based view within the conversation of strategic management. Strategic Management Journal 15(5): 363-380. Mayer RC, Davis JH, Schoorman FD. 1995. An integration model of organizational trust. Academy of Management Review 20(3): 709-735. McCann JE, Leon-Guerrero AY, Haley JD. 2001. Strategic goals and practices of innovative family businesses. Journal of Small Business Management 39(1): 50-59. Micelotta ER, Raynard M. 2011. Concealing or revealing the family? Corporate brand identity strategies in family firms. Family Business Review 24: 197-216 Miller D. 1986. Configurations of strategy and structure: towards a synthesis. Strategic Management Journal 7(3): 233-249. 43 Miller D, Le Breton-Miller I. 2005. Managing for the Long Run. Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA. Miller D, Steier L, Le Breton-Miller I. 2003. Lost in time: intergenerational succession, change, and failure in family business. Journal of Business Venturing 18(4): 513-531. Morck R, Yeung B. 2004. Family control and the rent-seeking society. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 28: 391-409. Morck RK, Steier L. 2005. The global history of corporate governance: an introduction. In A History of Corporate Governance Around the World: Family Business Groups to Professional Managers, Morck RK (ed). University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL; 1-64. Naldi L, Nordqvist M, Sjoberg K, Wiklund J. 2007. Entrepreneurial orientation, risk taking, and performance in family firms. Family Business Review 20(1): 33-47. Ndofor HA, Sirmon DG, He X. 2011. Firm resources, competitive actions and performance: Investigating a mediated model with evidence from the In-vitro diagnostics industry. Strategic Management Journal 32(6): 640-657. Nordqvist M, Habbershon TG, Melin L. 2008. Transgenerational entrepreneurship: exploring entrepreneurial orientation in family firms. In Sustainable Growth and Performance: Frontiers in European Entrepreneurship Research, Landström H, Smallbone D, Crijns H, Laveren E (eds). Edward Elgar: London, U.K. Nordqvist M, Wennberg K, Wiklund J, Hellerstedt K. 2011. Implications of intra-family and external ownership transfer of family firms: short-term and long-term performance differences. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 5(4). 44 Orru M. 1997. The institutional analysis of capitalist economies. In The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, Orru M, Biggart NW, Hamilton GG (eds). SAGE Publications: Thousand Oaks, CA; 297-310. Pearson AW, Carr JC, Shaw JC. 2008. Toward a theory of familiness: a social capital perspective. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 32(6): 949-969. Porter M. 1980. Corporate Strategy. Free Press: New York. Rauch A, Wiklund J, Lumpkin GT, Frese M. 2009. Entrepreneurial orientation and business performance: an assessment of past research and suggestions for the future. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 33(3): 761-781. Rodriguez P, Tuggle CS, Hackett SM. 2009. Examining ethnic entrepreneurship: an exploratory study of how ‘family capital’ impacts new venture start-up rates across ethnic groups. Family Business Review 22: 259-272. Ruef M. 2010. The Entrepreneurial Group: Social Identities, Relations, and Collective Action. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ. Salvato C. 2004. Predictors of entrepreneurship in family firms. Journal of Private Equity 7(3): 68-76. Salvato C, Chirico F, Sharma P. 2010. A farewell to the business: championing exit and continuity in entrepreneurial family firms. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development 22(3/4): 321-348. Saxenian A. 1994. Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA. 45 Schulze WS, Lubatkin MH, Dino RN. 2003. Exploring the agency consequences of ownership dispersion among the directors of private family firms. Academy of Management Journal 46(2): 179-194. Schulze WS, Lubatkin MH, Dino RN, Buchholtz AK. 2001. Agency relationships in family firms: theory and evidence. Organization Science 12: 99-116. Schuman A, Stutz S, Ward JL. 2010. Family Business as Paradox. Palgrave Macmillan: New York. Shane S, Venkataraman S, MacMillan I. 1995. Cultural differences in innovation championing strategies. Journal of Management 21(5): 931-952. Sharma P. 2004. An overview of the field of family business studies: current status and directions for the future. Family Business Review 17(1): 1-36. Sharma P, Chrisman JJ, Chua JH. 2003. Predictors of satisfaction with the succession process in family firms. Journal of Business Venturing 18(5): 667-687. Sieger P, Zellweger T, Nason R, Clinton E. 2011. Portfolio entrepreneurship in family firms: a resource-based perspective. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 5(4). Simon HA. 1993. Altruism and economics. American Economic Review 83: 156-161. Singal M, Singal V. 2011. Concentrated ownership and firm performance: does family-control matter? Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 5(4). Sirmon DG, Arregle J-L, Hitt MA, Webb JW. 2008. The role of family influence in firms' strategic responses to threat of imitation. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 32(6): 979-998. Sirmon DG, Hitt MA. 2003. Managing resources: linking unique resources, management, and wealth creation in family firms. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 27(4): 339-358. 46 Sirmon DG, Hitt MA, Ireland RD. 2007. Managing firm resources in dynamic environments to create value: looking inside the black box. Academy of Management Review 32(1): 273292. Sorenson RL. 2000. The contribution of leadership style and practices to family and business success. Family Business Review 13(3): 183-200. Steier L. 2001. Next-generation entrepreneurs and succession: an exploratory study of modes and means of managing social capital. Family Business Review 14: 259-276. Steier L. 2009a. Familial capitalism in global institutional contexts: implications for corporate governance and entrepreneurship in East Asia. Asia Pacific Journal of Management 26(3): 513-535. Steier L. 2009b. Where do new firms come from? Households, family capital, ethnicity, and the welfare mix. Family Business Review 22(3): 273-278. Tagiuri R, Davis JA. 1992. On the goals of successful family companies. Family Business Review 5(1): 43-62. Tagiuri R, Davis J. 1996. Bivalent attributes of the family firm. Family Business Review 9(2): 199-208. Thurow LC. 1989. An establishment or an oligarchy. National Tax Journal 42(4): 405-411. Tokarcyk J, Hansen E, Green M, Down J. 2007. A resource-based view and market orientation theory examination of the role of ‘familiness’ in family business success. Family Business Review 20(1): 17-31. Ucbasaran D, Westhead P, Wright M. 2009. The extent and nature of opportunity identification by experienced entrepreneurs. Journal of Business Venturing 24(2): 99-115. 47 Ucbasaran D, Westhead P, Wright M, Flores M. 2010. The nature of entrepreneurial experience, business failure, and comparative optimism. Journal of Business Venturing 25: 541-555. Vallejo M. 2009. The effects of commitment of non-family employees of family firms from the perspective of stewardship theory. Journal of Business Ethics 87(3): 379-390. Vohora A, Wright M, Lockett A. 2004. Critical junctures in spin-outs from universities. Research Policy 33: 147-175. Ward J, Dolan C. 1998. Defining and describing family business ownership configurations. Family Business Review 11(4): 305-310. Ward JL. 2004. Perpetuating the Family Business: 50 Lessons Learned from Long-Lasting, Successful Families in Business. Palgrave Macmillan: New York. Weber M. 1904/05. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, translated by Talcott Parsons, 1930/2001. Routledge Classics: London, U.K. Westhead P, Howorth C. 2007. 'Types' of private family firms: an exploratory conceptual and empirical analysis. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development 19(5): 405-431. Wiklund J, Shepherd D. 2005. Entrepreneurial orientation and small business performance: a configurational approach. Journal of Business Venturing 20: 71-91. Williamson OE. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Anti-Trust Implications. Free Press: New York. Williamson OE. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Free Press: New York. Yu A, Lumpkin GT, Sorenson RL, Brigham KH. The landscape of family business outcomes: a summary and numerical taxonomy of dependent variables. Family Business Review. Forthcoming. 48 Zahra SA. 2005. Entrepreneurial risk taking in family firms. Family Business Review 18: 2340. Zahra SA, Hayton JC, Salvato C. 2004. Entrepreneurship in family vs. non-family firms: a resource-based analysis of the effect of organizational culture. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 28: 363-381. Zahra SA, Wright M. Entrepreneurship’s next act. Academy of Management Perspectives. Forthcoming. Zellweger T. 2007. Time horizon, cost of equity capital, and generic investment strategies of firms. Family Business Review 20: 1-15. Zellweger T, Nason R. 2008. A stakeholder perspective to family firm performance. Family Business Review 21(3): 203-216. 49 CONTEXT Institutional environment/ family as an institution Local conditions/ national culture and geography Interaction between inputs and environmental factors Ownership regimes/ multigenerational involvement and succession INPUTS Temporal considerations/ planning horizons and business life cycles OUTPUTS PROCESSES Individual resources Orchestrating resources Individual benefits Family resources Creating economic value Family benefits Organizational resources Creating socioemotional wealth Organizational benefits Societal benefits Figure 1. A framework for family business and strategic entrepreneurship 50 Table 1. Summary of papers in the special section Authors Research questions Theoretical perspective Data and methods Key findings Nordqvist, Wennberg, Wiklund, and Hellerstedt What is the impact of different types of ownership transfer in family firms? Information asymmetries; stagnation perspective of family business. 2,647 Swedish family firms in existence 1997-2007 that went through an ownership change; Difference-indifference, OLS, and Cox proportional hazard duration model estimation. Firms transferred within the family have more stable short-term prospects in terms of sales growth and survival; firms transferred externally show more long-term prospects in terms of generating higher profits; choice of ownership transfer mode may be economically rational when families divest firms with more uncertain outcomes. Chirico, Sirmon, Sciascia and Mazzola What configuration of factors is needed to increase performance through entrepreneurship in family businesses? Resource orchestration; entrepreneurial orientation. Mail survey of the two highest executives in 199 Swiss family firms; OLS. Realizing the benefits from entrepreneurship in family firms is complicated and affected by the configuration of high levels of entrepreneurial orientation, generational involvement, and participative strategy; only with all three factors present will the benefits of entrepreneurship be fully realized. Sieger, Zellweger, Nason, and What is the process through which portfolio entrepreneurship RBV Four in-depth longitudinal cases from Europe and Latin America Six resource categories relevant to the portfolio entrepreneurship 51 Clinton develops in family businesses? Singal and Singal Does family control of the firm confer performance advantages over and above those conferred by concentrated ownership? Agency theory; institutional theory. involving 26 respondents; translevel analysis; theory building. process; the importance of these categories varies over time (portfolio entrepreneurship declines or industryspecific human capital; stays constant for industry-specific reputation and industry-specific social capital; increases for metaindustry human capital, meta-industry reputation, and metaindustry social capital). Panel data of Indian corporate sector built from five separate data sets including stock returns, financial indicators, stock holdings, director details, and company characteristics, 20012009; 4,382 firms including 3,257 family, 113 stateowned, 303 subsidiaries of MNEs and 709 with dispersed ownership. Firms with concentrated ownership outperform firms with dispersed ownership; controlling for ownership, there is no significant difference between family-controlled firms and firms controlled by foreign corporations or the state. 52 Table 2. Themes for a research agenda Inputs How do the cognitive characteristics of family business entrepreneurs differ from nonfamily business entrepreneurs? Process How does resource accumulation, configuration, and coordination differ in family businesses compared to nonfamily businesses? What is the contribution of family systems and/or households to the venture-creation process and how does this differ from nonfamily firms? How does the human capital and cognitive composition of founder family business teams differ from teams in second generation family businesses? How does the human capital and cognitive composition of family business teams differ from teams in nonfamily ventures? How do the cognitive dimensions of family firm entrepreneurs influence the microprocesses of family firm creation and development? To what extent are attempts at portfolio or serial entrepreneurship either within the family firm or as further independent ventures facilitated or constrained by family influence? What processes do family businesses adopt to transform their enterprises strategically as they grow, professionalize, and introduce external capital and nonfamily managers? What specific barriers are faced by family businesses compared to nonfamily firms? To what extent does learning How do family businesses manage Outputs What is the nature of conflicts between benefits for individual family members and family? How are these resolved? Context How do the boundaries of family businesses differ across institutional contexts? To what extent do individual family members exit the firm to achieve benefits that meet their objectives? How does strategic entrepreneurship vary in international contexts due to differences in the role of family businesses, family business groups, and extended kin ties? What is the impact of the loss of the tacit knowledge of the founder when family firms are transferred to the next generation or sold? What is the role of family human and social capital in family firms involved in transnational activities? How do these vary between emerging and developed economy contexts? How does familial capitalism and entrepreneurship differ across institutional contexts? What are the dimensions of these contexts in terms of spatial, temporal, social, and cultural aspects? What is the impact of different forms of external succession on former family firm performance? To what extent does family How do institutional factors 53 from prior entrepreneurial experience (success or failure) differ between family business entrepreneurs and nonfamily business entrepreneurs? the tensions between maintaining family control versus the need to exit to maintain entrepreneurial strength, survival, and success? reconciliation emerge after splits and how does this affect entrepreneurial activity? influence the nature and timing of family firm succession and survival? What is the role of tax incentives for succession versus resistance to ‘outsiders’ and acceptance of the family firm as a tradable asset in different contexts? To what extent are industry configurations influenced by networks of family firms? Does family support encourage or impede subsequent entrepreneurial activity? To what extent and how do family businesses maintain the entrepreneurial spirit of the founding generation? To what extent does the allocation of family-based resources contribute to initial entrepreneurial endeavors? To what extent do family values contribute to or impede innovation? How do family firms in high-tech sectors differ from nonfamily firms in terms of their innovativeness, growth, and financial strategies? To what extent are conflicts and tensions between family, individual, and organizational benefits reflected in different forms of organization and modes of growth? What founding conditions are unique to family firms and how do these affect subsequent development trajectories? To what extent do family businesses differ in their approach to the nature and timing of internationalization? To what extent do family values continue in family businesses that are sold? Where family businesses are acquired by external entrepreneurs, do new family values emerge? What challenges arise in shifting from the path dependence of original family ethos? What are the different forms of What happens to subsequent family business and how are these generations when founder families related to differential societal exit from entrepreneurship? benefits? What are the downside aspects of the inputs provided by families? How do family businesses sustain the processes of entrepreneurial activity over time (serial family business entrepreneurs)? To what extent and why are family businesses reacquired by the family following external exit? How do environmental factors interact with individual, family, and organizational resources to affect their value as inputs? 54