First draft Centre-Left Minority Coalition Government in Denmark: Back to Normalcy? Palle Svensson, Department of Political Science, Aarhus University, DK 8000 Aarhus C, Denmark pal@ps.au.dk Paper prepared for the Workshop on Minority and Coalition Government, Australian National University, Canberra, October 2-3, 2012 Abstract Minority coalition governments are common in Denmark, in fact, they have become the prevalent form of government. The paper deals with the question whether the result of the 2011 election and a centreleft minority coalition government marks a return back to normalcy with minority government without permanent support and with the Social Liberals as a pivotal party or whether social changes, new cleavage lines and new issues have changed the traditional links between political competition and policy making. The paper concludes that the formation of the centre-left government of the Social Democrats, the Social Liberals and the Socialist People’s Party in October 2011 and the first months of its governing does to some extent represent a return to normal Danish politics, but that the life of the new government is far from safe. 2 Introduction After the September 15, 2011 Folketing election the Liberal-Conservative minority coalition government under the leadership of the Liberal Prime Minister Lars Løkke Rasmussen resigned and after more than two weeks negotiations a centre-left minority coalition government under the leadership of the Social Democrat Helle Thorning-Schmidt was formed on October 3. The new government was a coalition of three parties: The Social Democrats, The Social Liberals and The Socialist People’s Party. As shown in Table 1, the three parties won 77 of 179 seats in the one chamber Danish parliament, the Folketing. As the new government was recommended by the left wing party, The Unity List/Red Green Alliance, the parliamentary basis of the new government comprised 89 seats, that is more than half of the 175 seats normally considered as relevant, as four North Atlantic seats are usually disregarded when forming a new government. However, after the September 2011 election the two members from Greenland and one of the two members from the Faroe Islands actually supported the new government, leaving no doubt about the Folketing acceptance of the new government. The figures in Table 1, nevertheless, reveal that the new government was not formed as a result of an election victory. The three governmental parties obtained the same number of seats as in the 2007 election. In fact, both the Social Democrats and the Socialists were losing electoral support whereas the Social Liberals was gaining stronger support. The new government was based from the outside on the increased strength of the left wing Unity List/Red Green Alliance, but inside the government the Social Liberals took a strong position, because it was a winning party and because it as a centre party had alternative partners to the right. The Social Liberals had campaigned for a change of government, mainly in order to stop the influence of the Danish People’s Party that had acted as a permanent support party for the Liberal-Conservative government since 2001, but the Social Liberals had at the 3 same time compromised with the Liberal-Conservative government on vital issues, such as a reform of the early retirement benefits. The public debate had for years up to the 2011 election been dominated by two bloc policies, a “red” bloc versus a “blue” bloc. The Social Democrats and the Socialist People’s Party presented policy programs as alternatives to the bourgeois government, more or less taking the support of the Social Liberals (to the right) and the Unity List (to the left) for granted. It came as a surprise when the Social Liberals in 2011 a few months before the election compromised with the bourgeois government on reforms of the early retirement scheme and the unemployment benefits (shortening the period from four years to two years). The bargaining strength of the Social Liberals in the formation of the centre-left government was clearly demonstrated with the publication of the government coalition agreement. With flowers and big smiles the party leaders of the Social Democrats and the Socialist People’s Party abandoned electoral promises such a defending the early retirement scheme and the period of unemployment benefits, introducing a millionaire tax and tackling irresponsible banks. With a few exceptions the government program “A Denmark that stands together” was interpreted as virtually implementing the Social Liberal’s policies. Table 1. The 2007 and 2011 Elections Minority coalition governments are common in Denmark, in fact, they have become the prevalent form of government. According to Müller, Bergman & Strøm (2008: 8) 13 minority coalition governments out of 32 governments were formed from 1945 to 1999, making Denmark the country with the highest record of minority coalition governments. After 1982 all Danish governments have been coalitions and only a single one – for a short period (from 1993 to 1994) – had majority status. The Liberal- 4 Conservative governments formed in 2001, 2005 and 2007 were also minority coalitions. In sum, about half of all Danish governments since the World War have been minority coalitions. Table 2: Danish Governments 1945-2011 However, minority governments – and among these minority coalitions – defer among each other. Whereas some minority governments have to find a majority from one issue to the next and may have to govern by shifting majorities, other minority governments enjoy a permanent external support. To apply the terminology suggested by Kaare Strøm (1990: 62) “any government is classified as externally supported that enjoys the parliamentary support of any party not represented in the cabinet if its support: (1) was negotiated prior to the formation of the government, and (2) takes the form of an explicit, comprehensive, and more than short-term commitment to the policies as well as the survival of the government.” If the external support makes the difference between minority and majority status, Strøm talks about formal minority governments. The reminding minority governments where the external support from other parties is less explicit and permanent, Strøm calls substantive minority governments. Clearly, this distinction is not a precise either-or, but rather a more-or-less, as minority governments may be placed along a continuum from (1) pure formal minority governments with a permanent majority with parties outside the government, that is negotiated beforehand, explicit and long-lasting, over (2) permanent support that may not be formalized or explicit and declared, but nevertheless stable and long-lasting, to (3) regular, but not comprehensive support from parties securing a majority, to (4) real substantive minority governments that have to find shifting majorities from one issue to the next. Thus, the Danish People’s Party in relation to the bourgeois LiberalConservative government was a support party of type 2, as its support was permanent and 5 demonstrated by annual agreements with the government on the finance bill, but neither negotiated before the formation of the government nor formalized in any way. In Denmark the Social Liberals have traditionally taken the role as a pivotal party deciding whether the centre-left under Social Democratic leadership or the centre-right under Liberal or Conservative leadership should form the government. This has commonly been described as “co-operative democracy” (“samarbejdende folkestyre”) and policy-making across the centre of Danish politics. Sometimes the Social Liberals participated in centre-left governments (such as recently from 1993 to 2001) or have acted as a permanent support party for Social Democratic formal minority governments (such as in the 1970s) or have participated in centre-right governments (such as from 1969 to 1971 under their own leadership or from 1988 to 1990 under Conservative leadership) or have acted – at least to some extent (see Damgaard & Svensson, 1989 on alternative majorities) – as a supporting party for bourgeois minority governments (such as from 1982 to 1988). It has even been argued that the Danish political parties had gradually realized that majority governments or minority governments with permanent support had become an exception. What in the Danish context are called “the four old parties” (Social Democrats, Social Liberals, Liberals and Conservatives) had modified their views of what it means to be a "responsible party." It had become less a question of which parties to cooperate with and in what way, but rather a question of having the necessary policy measures passed in parliament (Green-Pedersen, 2001: 66). A remarkable change in this developing pattern occurred in 2001 (by some even called “a systemic change”) when the Liberals and Conservatives obtained a majority with the right-wing Danish People’s Party, making the Social Liberals redundant for government formation and policy-making. The Danish People’s Party in reality took the role as a permanent external support party for the Liberal-Conservative government, even if no agreement was negotiated beforehand and made explicit. The question is whether the result of the 2011 election and the centre-left minority coalition 6 government with the Social Liberals in a dominating position marks a return back to normalcy with minority government without permanent support and with the Social Liberals as a pivotal party or whether social changes, new cleavage lines and new issues have changed the traditional links between political competition and policy making? The paper discusses this question by reviewing some recent research results and updating some of them by an analysis of the legislation during the 2011-12 session under the leadership of the new centre-left minority coalition government. Social Changes and a New Political Cleavage As a consequence of social changes and social movements during the 1970s and 1980s, the social base of Danish political parties has changed. No Green party has been successfully established in Demark but powerful environment movements and rights for women have influenced the existing parties. Numerous studies have analysed a decline of class voting (Andersen & Andersen, 2003) and a new tendency towards issue voting (Borre, 1995; 2007). It has been argued that new issues such as immigration has formed the basis for New Politics supplementing Old Politics. While Old political issues are mainly economic, New political issues are mainly non-economic. Ole Borre (1995) has looked into the extent to which theses about New Politics hold true for Denmark at the 1990 Folketing election. He found that the Danish case confirmed the main thesis that on a number of non-economic issues New Politics tended to form a distinct attitudinal dimension that was separated from the economic Old Politics dimension He also confirmed the overriding importance of education in the formation of the New Politics position. The well educated tended to take positions on the New Left and the less educated, on the New Right. Among those with secondary or higher education, especially the new middle class of modern welfare societies constitutes the core of the New Left. 7 However, Borre argued that the Danish case did not confirm the thesis that the New Politics dimension, defined in terms of attitudes, was necessarily connected with the rise of new parties or with splits in the established major parties. The positions of party groups on New Politics attitudes by 1990, in conjunction with the parliamentary development of the preceding decade, point toward a different conclusion: a competitive multiparty system … can be expected to accommodate the New Politics issues and even to take an active part in crystallizing positions on these issues. In particular, small and medium-sized parties that are not obliged to represent a national or religious minority may “mutate” into New Politics parties without necessarily giving up their roles in Old Politics (Borre, 1995: 203). For sure, this conclusion was correct with regard to the 1990 election as the average voters of the Socialist People’s Party and the Social Liberals took positions on the left wing of the New Politics dimension and the average voters of the Progress Party took position on the right wing of this dimension. Nevertheless, a few years later, in 1995, the Progress Party split and a new party, The Danish People’s Party, was formed by members of the Progress Party. During the following elections in 1998, 2001, 2005 and 2007 the DPP was successful in mobilizing voters on the right wing of the New Politics dimension. Whereas it has been argued that New Politics issues (Miller & Levitin, 1976) and post-material values (Dalton, 2002; Inglehart, 1997) have come to the forefront of the voters’ minds on election day without structural links, Rune Stubager (2006; 2010) has in detail studied the relationship between education and New Politics Issues or what he terms “authoritarian–libertarian” values.1 1 I agree to his empirical results, but object to the term ”libertarian” as I prefer the term ”liberal” for the left wing of New Politics. However, I retain his terminology in direct quotes. I accept Stubager’s definition of the values of New Politics (2010: 508f), that authoritarians favor social hierarchy and the ordering of individuals in a system with a clear distinction 8 He argues that just as the class cleavage was reflected in a conflict between a socialist left and a capitalist right represented by their respective parties, education has now given rise to a new cleavage that lies beneath what has been seen as a purely ideological conflict over political values about immigration and environmentalism. In order to demonstrate the emergence of a new cleavage Stubager relies on the development by Bartolini & Mair (1990) of the classical Lipset & Rokkan’s article on “Cleavage Structures, Party Systems, and Voter Alignments” (1967) and further refined by Knutsen & Scarbrough (1995). Political cleavages are defined as consisting of three inter-related elements: (1) a socio-structural; (2) a psychological; and (3) an organizational. Cleavages arise because socio-structurally defined groups between superior and inferior groups or persons, that for authoritarians such hierarchies are both natural and right, that libertarians and liberals dislike social hierarchies and prefer the free and equal interaction of people without regard to social positions of any kind, and that in addition to the attitudes to hierarchy, attitudes to tolerance for nonconformity form a core aspect of the New Politics dimension. Entailed in a libertarian and liberal position, thus, is a basic respect for and tolerance of other people – including those who deviate from one’s own norms or the norms of society. Variety among humans is, in fact, seen as something to be protected for its own sake. Not so for authoritarians: Those who deviate from conventional norms or who stand outside society should first and foremost be made to comply with the norms of society. Their deviance is not accorded any value in itself; variety is potentially bad and deserves no protection. In this way hierarchy and tolerance form the ideas underlying the New Politics values. The difference between liberals and libertarians, however, is their view on the state. Whereas liberals disagree on the role of the state, libertarians support an extreme form of laissez-faire capitalism. They favour property rights and the market. People’s choices are unrestrained by any central, supervising authority. Differently stated the difference between liberals and libertarians is a distinction between moral and political liberalism on the one hand and economic liberalism on the other hand. You can be a liberal without being a liberalist or libertarian - as you can be social without being a socialist. The mistaken terminology is taken over from American researchers such as Flanagan (1987) and Flanagan & Lee (2003). Terminologically “authoritarian” and “libertatrian” tally nicely, and the terminology may also make some sense in the United States, where “liberal” is often used as similar to leftwing, social-democratic or even socialist. But for Europe it is misleading, which is clearly demonstrated by the need for researchers such as Herbert P. Kitschelt to introduce a term such as “left-libertarian” in order to cover the combination of individual freedom and social justice: “The parties are ‘left’ because they call for economic redistribution; they are ‘libertarian’, because they emphasize individual freedom, participation and social decentralization and attack the traditional socialist instrumentalities of economic redistribution, a strong bureaucratic state with centralised planning machinery” (Kitschelt, 1988: 155). . 9 disagree about certain matters. To be able to speak of a cleavage it is crucial to document that sociostructurally defined groups have developed opposing interests that may be either material or nonmaterial (i.e. values) and that the members of the opposing groups support organizations such as political parties that articulate the interests of the groups in the political arena. The underlying conflicts can be seen as erupting due to macro-social developments that has consequences for the interests of the socio-structurally defined groups. They arise in so-called critical junctures (Lipset & Rokkan, 1967: 37) where new issues become salient due to macro-social changes that elevate them onto the political agenda. There has been a marked and steady increase in the educational level among Danes, for instance the proportion with tertiary educations has increased from 12 per cent in 1983 to 22 per cent in 2003. During the same period the proportion having only primary or lower secondary education has dropped from 52 per cent to 35 per cent. This development constitutes an important pre-condition to the establishment of an education-based cleavage. For a political cleavage to develop is necessary that the conflict of interests is activated at the structural level by events that put the conflicting perspectives in play in critical junctures. According to Stubager this has, indeed, happened in Denmark: An overview of Danish politics through the past two and a half decades reveals that in particular two issues related to authoritarian–libertarian values have experienced marked changes in their salience: environmental issues and the issue of immigration. As for the former, the environment first made its way onto the public agenda in the late 1960s and early 1970s, but the mid 1980s brought increased focus on problems related to pollution. The result was a marked jump in the salience of the environment to voters who placed the issue high on the agenda in the late 1980s. Another critical juncture has manifested itself in relation to the issue of immigration. Although a certain amount of immigration is no new phenomenon in Denmark, the number of guest workers and refugees that have arrived in the country over the past few decades far surpasses anything 10 seen before. This development has not gone unnoticed among the voters … the immigration issue was put on the public agenda in the mid 1980s and the 1990s brought a steady increase in salience culminating in 2001 when the issue was seen as second in importance only to the somewhat vaguer issue of welfare … the result of these developments was an activation of the dimension in the minds of the voters. Thus, the combined impact of the increasing salience of the two issues has been an activation of the conflict between authoritarian and libertarian values (Stubager, 2010: 509f). Stubager concludes his empirical analysis that a considerable – and changing – relationship between both the old and new value dimensions and voting has been shown. His results indicate that an increasing importance of a cleavage over authoritarian–libertarian/liberal values and a decreasing importance of a cleavage over economic values have taken place. The decline of the class variable has main impact among the three traditionally class-based parties (Social Democrats, Conservatives and Liberals) while the education variable retains – and in one case increases – its impact in relation to the three parties most closely associated with the new cleavage (Socialists Peoples Party, Social Liberals at the liberal end and Danish People’s Party at the authoritarian end). Linkage between the electoral and parliamentary level The question is, then, whether and to what extent this new two-dimensionality is linked to parliamentary politics? A study by Asbjørn Skjæveland (2005) has investigated this question on the basis of divisions on passed bills in the Danish parliament. He concludes that the two levels have not been linked because there is still one (left-right) dimension in the Danish parliament, Folketing: The parties may also today (2001-03) be arranged along only one dimension, which roughly speaking is a conflict between parties, which are far apart, and a cooperation between parties that are close to each other ... It is not claimed that new political issues were not important ... the argument is simply that one can still make do with a single dimension when you place the 11 parliamentary groups on the basis of their voting behavior at the third reading of the legislation” (Skjæveland, 2005: 419). Erik Damgaard, the nestor of Danish parliamentary research, has speculated how this lack of linkage between the parliamentary and the electoral level might be explained. He argues ... There is a difference in the voting situation at the two levels. The votes of the electors are, so to say, individual, autonomous and influenced by many factors. The voting of the (disciplined) party groups is, however, highly structured and negotiated between the coalition parties themselves through government ... [and] solid coordination procedures and current agreements on political issues, which may also involve permanent support parties. In addition, there are the many political accommodations, which precisely oblige the parties with respect to their voting on a number of agreed issues (Damgaard, 2005: 390f). Legislative accommodations or agreements (forlig)2 are in Denmark a vital element in government through broad consensus. Flemming Juul Christiansen has shown that 17 per cent of the legislation from 1953 to 2005 was covered by political accommodations (2008: 73 and 155). He has further shown that a significant smaller share of legislation is covered by legislative accommodations under majoritarian governments than under minority governments, whereas no significant differences could be documented between minority governments with and without a permanent support party (formal and substantive minority governments) (2008: 76-78 and 155). Moreover, he could show that the number of legislative accommodations varies with the competition between the political parties as measured by the number of proposals other than legislation or the degree of unanimous legislation: The stronger the party competition, the more accommodations (2008: 78-83 and 155). In Figure 1 the relationship between legislative accommodations and bills passed with unanimous and non-unanimous The translation to English of the Danish “forlig” is not well established. In the English summary to his Ph.d. thesis 2 Flemming Juul Christiansen talks about “accommodations”, but in later papers he talks about “agreements” (see for instance Christiansen & Pedersen, 2011: 4). 12 vote is shown and the figure, in addition, clearly indicates a tendency towards an increasing number of accommodations. Figure 1 If the strength of the parliamentary basis of Danish minority governments has no impact on the extent to which political accommodations are entered, it is of some interest to clarify whether there are other differences between minority governments with permanent support (formal minority governments) and without permanent support (substantial minority governments) with regard to policy-making. Do formal minority governments rely more on their support party/parties by governing through bloc politics than substantial minority governments? Comparing the winner coalitions during three Danish governments give an answer to this question. The minority government from 1998 to 2001 was a coalition of the Social Democrats and the Social Liberals. Its parliamentary basis was the left wing Socialist People’s and the Unity List, but it passed major structural reform with the non-socialist parties, being flexible when seeking support for policy proposals (Green-Pedersen, 2001). Thus, this government seems to come close to the substantive type of minority government . The Liberal-Conservative government formed in 2001 represented a break with the traditional form of “co-operative democracy” (”samarbejdende folkestyre”) and policymaking across the centre. It was a right-wing Government receiving permanent support from the Danish People’s Party and it was widely accused of conducting bloc-politics. Thus, it seems to be a clear case of a formal type of minority government. Table 3 compares the centre-left government formed in 2011 with the two former minority governments in order to examine whether it represents a return to the normalcy before 2001. 13 Erik Damgaard and Henrik Jensen have compared the two governmental periods 1998-2001 and 2001-04 and treat the left-wing parties in 1998-2001 as support parties for the Social DemocraticSocial Liberal government. In order to simplify the analysis they reduce the winning coalitions to five: (1) All parties; (2) broad majorities, where governmental parties and parties from both to the right and the left of the government vote together; (3) governmental parties and support parties against the reminding parties, i.e. bloc coalitions; (4) governmental parties without support parties; and (5) alternative majorities, where the winning coalition does not comprise the governmental parties (Damgaard & Jensen, 2009: 104). Table 3 Table 3 shows that about one third of all passed bills were adopted unanimously at the final divisions. This pattern is similar for the three governments, perhaps even higher for the new centre-left government formed in 2011. Another half of the bills were passed with a broad majority in 1998-2001 and 2001-04, but only by a quarter in 2011-12. This difference is more apparent than real because it partly reflects the changed composition of the government in 2011. The table shows that 27.8 per cent of the bills were passed by the vote of the governmental parties, the Unity List and one or more of the non-socialist parties, but had the Socialist People’s Party (as in 1998-2001) been treated as a left-wing party outside the government this figure would have been much higher, as the SPP voted for all the passed bills in the 2011-12 session. In fact, this means that a broad majority (the government plus parties from the non-socialist opposition) comprised 49.5 per cent (27. 8 + 21.7 per cent) which is at the same level as previously. The most remarkable winning coalition to be observed is where a conflict is demonstrated between the government and the opposition by a bloc majority comprised by governmental and support parties. Here the new centre-left government in the 2011-12 session is more 14 similar to the right-wing government supported by the Danish People’s Party 2001-04 (12.6 and 12.5 per cent respectively) than with the centre-left government 1998-2001 (6.9 per cent). At this point, there seems to be no return to a pre-2001 normalcy - nor a return to the alternative majorities of the 1980’s (see Damgaard & Svensson, 1989). Laws have binding effect for the citizens whereas resolutions and decisions mark the Folketing’s political opinions towards the government and the public. Whereas the government prepares almost all bills, the opposition has a larger lee-way with regard to resolutions and decisions. Thus, it is to be expected that proposals and debate of resolutions and decisions to a larger extent is part of the competition between the political parties, resulting in a higher level of conflict. This is clearly the case for both resolutions and decisions in 1998-2001 and 2001-04. As too few resolutions for a reasonable comparison were passed in the 2011-12 session (N=5), only winning coalitions on passed decisions are considered. Once again it is remarkable that the new centre-left government is more alike to the rightwing government than to the 1998-2001 centre-left government. Two out of five decisions were passed with bloc votes where the government confronted the opposition, while this was only the case in one of twenty in 1998-2001. The centre-left government 1998-2001 could not to the same extent as the following governments rely on support parties when the life of the government was at stake. It is, as a matter of fact, not really accurate (as Damgaard and Jensen) to talk about support parties for the 1998-2001 period. The Unity List and The Socialist People’s Party should rather be described as forming the parliamentary basis than permanent support parties for the centre-left government in this period. After 2011 the Socialist People’s Party joined the government and the Unity List acted – at least in this first session of the life of the new government – as a permanent support party to the same extent as the Danish People’s Party to the Liberal-Conservative government. Christoffer Green-Pedersen has argued about the Social Democratic-Social Liberal minority government up to 2001 that it was able to govern the economy successfully because its bargaining 15 position had been strengthened (2001: 53). Along the same line Kaare Strøm (1990: 97) holds that shifting coalition strategies offer minority governments optimal conditions for having their policies passed, but it also renders them vulnerable to defeat. In the Danish case, it has been argued that the governing effectiveness of minority governments was dependent on the possibility of being flexible when seeking support for policy proposals: What a minority government needs is more than one possible way of building a majority behind its proposals. If a minority government has only one way of building a majority in parliament, the opposition party - or parties - necessary to build this majority are in a veto position in relation to the policies which the minority government can pass (Green-Pedersen, 2001: 56). The Social Democratic-Social Liberal government passed some policies with the non-socialist opposition, some policies with the left-wing opposition and some policies with the Socialist People's Party and some of the centre parties. When a minority government finds itself in this kind of position, the Danish case indicates that a minority government can govern quite effectively. Due to the flexibility in building a majority, it can have “almost all the required policies passed in parliament” (Green-Pedersen, 2001: 64). The Social Democratic-Social Liberal minority government of the 1990’s was an equilibrium government as defined by Laver and Shepsle (1996: 66-69), because there was no other feasible government that a majority would prefer. The left-wing parties have supported the governments in the cabinet formation process so, if they withdrew their support, the Government would fall. However, an alternative Government would most probably be a non-socialist government, implying that the left-wing opposition would be without policy influence (GreenPedersen, 2001: 64). 16 On the one hand, this meant that a threat from the left-wing opposition of bringing down the centreleft government was not really credible. In reality, the left-wing was not in a position to force the government into choosing sides. On the other hand, the right-wing opposition wanted to bring down the government, but it could only do so if the left-wing opposition was willing to cooperate. For both the left-wing and the right-wing opposition the situation in relation to the Government was basically the same: “The Government will be in power until, for instance, an election destroys the equilibrium situation. The opposition faces a trade-off between influencing the policy of the Government and having a clear opposition profile” (Green Pedersen, 2001: 64f). The question is whether this relationship between the government and the opposition to the left and the right has been re-established after 2011, i.e. whether a return to normalcy has taken place with respect to flexibility and effectiveness for the government and the prospects for its survival? The answer to this question at the time of writing (September 2012) blows in the wind, but scattered information indicate that the flexibility of the new centre-left government is quite high, its effectiveness perhaps better that its reputation and its chances for survival not as bad as they may seem. The performance of the centre-left government formed in 2011 First of all, the flexibility of the government has been quite high. As shown in Table 3 it has been able to pass legislation with support from parties both to the left and to the right. After the Folketing went on summer vacation it even compromised with the Liberals and the Conservatives in June on a tax reform. “Denmark in work” was the title of the tax reform that the Minister of Taxation announced in February 2012. The objective was to facilitate the taxation of individuals. In presenting the reform in May Prime Minister Helle Thorning-Schmidt stressed that the tax cuts for those in work would increase both the supply of labour and employment. After dramatic negotiations in which the Unity 17 List believed to have reached an agreement with the government, the negotiations resulted in an agreement between the government parties and the Liberals and the Conservatives involving a reduction of the top tax by raising the borderline for top tax and a postponement of the regulation of transfer payments.3 The Unity List was furious. Its spokesman responded with the comment: "The confidence of the Unity List in the government is currently non-existent. We are no longer support party for this government. We are in opposition” (TV News, June 22, 2012). To confront the party that had acted as its support party definitely is a sign of high flexibility! The crucial question is, of course, whether a threat from the left-wing of bringing down the centre-left government is really credible? The effectiveness of the centre-left government formed in 2011seems to be less impressive than the effectiveness of the centre-left government in the 1990’s, but it is difficult to compare exactly. It is a fact, however, that not only the Social Democrats and the Socialist People’s Party have been accused of broken promises, but also the government as a whole has been blamed for given up important elements from its own programme, most notable the announced three-part-negotiations with the labour unions and the employers with a view to expand the labour force, and the congestion charge or payment ring (“betalingsring”) in Copenhagen. Nevertheless, it has been pointed out that the government over little more than six months had actually been able to implement 42 out of 95 points in the government program while 52 points were either in the process or were not yet addressed. Only one point was openly abandoned: the Payment ring (Ritzau, April 16, 2012 referring to the newspaper Berlingske Tidende). 3 According to professor Jørgen Goul Andersen (University of Aalborg) the tax reform marks the final death of the Danish flexicurity model. “Flexicurity is mostly past, and this is just a further nail in the coffin.” The Liberal-Conservative government took the first step in 2010 when it shortened the unemployment benefit period from four to two years and also extended the demand for rehabilitation from 26 to 52 weeks. In 2011 the centre-left government - forced by a majority in parliament - reduced the early retirement scheme. The last remnant of flexicurity has been the compensation you receive as unemployed in terms of the size of unemployment benefits or cash benefit. "Now the compensation is cut further, and it is by the way pretty low for an average worker. So you cannot any longer talk about flexicurity in Denmark” (The newspaper Information, May 29, 2012). The concept of flexicurity - which is a combination of the two English words ‘flexibility’ and ‘security’ - has in a Danish context meant that employers can easily hire and fire employees. Conversely, the employees need not have to fear - at first - to leave house and home if they lose a job. 18 Two months later the weekly magazine Mandag Morgen published an analysis under the heading: “The broken-promises-government is a myth” claiming that behind the image of broken promises a more complex political reality was hidden. A detailed review of the joint political initiatives from the Social Democrats and the Socialist People’s Party before the election showed that the parties had been able to carry through far more of their proposals than it had appeared in the media. The two party leaders have not only gained a large number of their comprehensive reform proposals into the government's legislative program on priority areas such as employment, education, health, climate, energy, welfare, foreign policy, trade and growth. Mandag Morgen further argued that the government's economic policy was more ‘red’ than the picture that the opposition and the media had been trying to draw. In addition, many of the proposals that the Social Democrats and the Socialist People’s Party had been accused of braking in the weeks after the election had since been taken up by the government. All in all, out of 315 joint proposals advanced by the Social Democrats and the Socialist People’s 270 proposals had been addressed: 70 had already been adopted by law or as a new initiative. Another 148 proposals were the subject of current negotiations, forthcoming reform proposals or committee work. The remaining 52 proposals covered by the government program had not yet been launched, of these 45 (14 per cent of 315) had been dropped, but these dropped proposals had dominated the public debate and helped to send the Prime Minister to take the count. Even if a mere quantitative analysis is not sufficient for a complete evaluation of the effectiveness of the centreleft government, it is nevertheless evident that the image of the government is worse that its record. In a number of interviews to Danish newspapers Prime Minister Helle Thorning-Schmidt in August 2012 admitted that the new government – and in particular the Social Democrats and the Social People’s Party - had had a bad start because of a number of mistakes. She gave three main reasons (see the newspaper Morgenavisen Jyllands-Posten, August 10, 2012). First, against numerous accusations of broken electoral promises the government had not made it sufficiently clear that the election result 19 demanded compromises. This meant that the image of broken promises had hold on. Second, the government had focused too much on long-range reforms, for instance asking Danes to work more in order to increase the supply of man power towards 2020, instead of giving priority to actual problems of unemployment. Finally, the government had initiated too many reforms without giving proper explanations, which had made it impossible for the voters to keep up. The centre-left government has obviously disappointed a large number of its voters. This is clearly indicated by the decline of popular support for the three government parties in opinion polls and a growing popular support for the left-wing Unity List (up to 10.8 per cent in early June 2012) and the non-socialist opposition parties, for instance increased support for the Liberals (34 per cent in early June 2012). In particular the decline for the once largest party, the Social Democrats, is remarkable (a low of 16.3 per cent in late June 2012) - see Figure 2. Figure 2 On the one hand, this declining popular support can be taken as a sign of weakness for the centre-left government, but on the other hand it may actually have strengthened its parliamentary position in relation to the left wing Unity List, because bringing down the government will surely result in an electoral defeat for the ‘red’ bloc and the formation of a new and stronger non-socialist government. In this respect, a return to pre-2001 normalcy has taken place. It has to be remembered in this context that only once in the post-war period - in 1967 when a breakup in the Socialist People’s Party resulted in the resignation of a Social Democratic minority government - has intra-party conflict been the cause for termination of a Danish government (Damgaard, 2008: 306). Nevertheless, the life of the government is far from safe. Its problems are illustrated by the fact that shortly after tough negotiations on the finance bill between the government and the Unity List was started, the chairman of the 20 Socialist People’s Party and Foreign Minister, Villy Søvndal, on September 7 announced that he resigned as chairman of the party causing public turmoil on the election of a new chairman. Conclusion The formation of the centre-left government of the Social Democrats, the Social Liberals and the Socialist People’s Party in October 2011 and the first months of its governing does to some extent represent a return to normal Danish politics with the Social Liberals as a pivot party in control. Indeed, the Social Liberals have taken a dominant position and the left wing has during the first parliamentary session even acted more clearly as a support party than in the 1990s. The government has shown remarkable flexibility and a better effectiveness than acknowledged by the public. Moreover, it holds a strong equilibrium position between the left-wing and the right-wing. At least it remains to be seen whether the Unity List will really bring down the government by refusing to vote for the finance bill for 2013 with a prospect of winning votes in a coming election but loosing policy influence to a new non-socialist government. 21 Table 1. The 2007 and 2009 Folketing Election results November 2007 September 2011 Per Cent Seats Per Cent Seats Unity List (UL) 2.2 4 6.7 12 Socialist People’s Party (SPP) 13.0 23 9.2 16 Social Democrats (SD) 25.5 45 24.8 44 Social Liberals (SL) 5.1 9 9.5 17 Christians People’s Party (CPP) 0.9 0 0.8 0 Liberal Alliance (LA) 2.8 5 5.0 9 Conservatives (Con) 10.4 18 4.9 8 Liberals (Lib) 26.2 46 26.7 47 Danish People’s Party (DPP) 13.9 25 12.3 22 0 0 0.1 0 100.0 175 100.0 175 Outside parties Sum Note: Two members elected on the Faroe Islands and two members elected on Greenland not included. 22 Table 2. Danish Governments 1945-2011 Majority One party Coalitions with two or more parties 0 pct. (N=0) 11 pct. (N=4) Minority 40 pct. 49 pct. (N=14) (N=17) N= 35, when the 2001, 2005 and 2007 Lib+Con minority coalition governments and the 2011 SPP+SD+SL minority coalition government are added to the information in Müller, Bergman & Strøm, 2008: 8 23 Table 3. Types of Winning Coalitions for three Government Periods. (N=100 Per Cent) Winning Passed bills Resolutions Decisions coalition SD + SL Lib+Con SPP+SD SD + SL Lib+Con SPP+SD SD + SL Lib+Con SPP+SD 1998- 2001-04 +SL 1998- 2001-04 +SL 1998- 2001-04 +SL 2011-12 2001 2011-12 2001 2001 All parties 2011-12 29.0 31.0 37.9 13.1 13.3 (60.0) 10.9 12.5 13.9 46.6 49.8 27.8 42.6 45.0 (0) 50.0 35.5 38.9 6.9 12.5 12.6 28.4 20.4 (0) 4.9 40.8 38.9 17.1 6.4 21.7 14.2 17.8 (40.0) 33.7 10.5 8.3 .4 .2 0 1.7 3.3 (0) .5 .7 0 (713) (622) (198) (176) (180) (5) (184) (152) (36) The Government and parties to the left and the right The Government and support parties The Government without support parties Alternative majority (N) Sources: Damgaard & Jensen, 2009: 107, Table 3.6 for the 1998-2001 and 2001-04 governments; my coding for the 2011-12 parliamentary session. 24 Figure 1. Number of legislative Accommodations 1953-2005 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Unanimous Non-unanimous Note: A governmental period is here defined by a change of party composition or an election, but without a change of prime minister – i.e. different from Strøm, Müller & Bergman, 2011. Source: Christiansen, 2008: 79. 25 Figure 2: Support for Political Parties 2011-12. Per Cent 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Election September 2011 January 2012 UL February 2012 March 2012 SPP SD April 2012 SL Source: Epinion, 2012, for Denmarks Radio. 26 May 2012 Red bloc Mid June 2012 End June 2012 Blue bloc August 2012 Literature Andersen, Johannes & Jørgen Goul Andersen (2003). “Klassernes forsvinden”, pp. 207-21 in Jørgen Goul Andersen & Ole Borre (eds.), Politisk forandring. Værdipolitik og nye skillelinjer ved folketingsvalget 2001, Aarhus: Systime Academic. Bartolini, Stefani & Peter Mair (1990). Identity, Competition and Electoral Availability, Canmbridge: Cambridge University Press. Borre, Ole (1995). “Old and New Politics in Denmark”, Scandinavian Political Studies, vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 187-205. Borre, Ole (2007). ”Issue voting i Danmark 2001-2005”, pp, 177-94 in Jørgen Goul Andersen, Johannes Andersen, Ole Borre, Kasper Møller Hansen & Hans Jørgen Nielsen (eds.), Det nye politiske Landskab. Folketingsvalget 2005 i perspektiv, Aarhus: academica. Christiansen, Flemming Juul (2008). Politiske forlig i Folketinget. Partikonkurrence og samarbejde, Aarhus: Forlaget Politica. Christiansen, Flemming Juul & Helene Helboe Pedersen (2011). Minority Coalition Governance in Denmark, Paper prepared for the Research Section on Danish and Comparative Politics, Department of Political Science, University of Aarhus, September 16, 2011. Dalton, Russel J. (2002). Citizen Politics. Public Opinion and Political Parties in Advanced Industrial Democracies, (3.ed.), New York: Chatham House Publichers. Damgaard, Erik (2005). ”Parlamentarisk konflikt og samarbejde”, Politica, vol. 37, no. 4, pp. 385-95. Damgaard, Erik (2008). ”Cabinet Termination” pp. 301-26 in Kaare Strøm, Wolfgang C. Müller & Torbjörn Bergman (eds.), Cabinets and Coalition Bargaining: The Democratic Life Cycle in Western Europe, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Damgaard, Erik & Henrik Jensen (2009). ”Folketinget”, pp. 81-117 in Anne Skorkjær Binderkratz, Jørgen Grønnegaard Christensen, Peter Munk Christiansen, Erik Damgaard, Jørgen Elklit & Henrik Jensen, Det demokratiske system. Valg, Folketinget, forvaltning og organisationer, Aarhus: Academica (2. ed.). Damgaard, Erik & Palle Svensson (1989). ”Who Governs? Parties and Politics in Denmark”, European Journal of Political Research, vol. 17, no. 6, pp. 731-45. Epinion (2012). Politisk Barometer (http://www.dr.dk/surveymaster/PolitikBarometer2011.swf). Flanagan, Scott C. (1987). “Value Change in Industrial Societies”, American Political Science Review, vol. 81, no. 4, pp. 1303-19. 27 Flanagan, Scott C. & Aie-Rie Lee (2003). “The New Politics, Culture Wars, and the AuthoritarianLibertarian Change in Advanced Industrial Democracies”, Comparative Political Studies, vol 36, no, 3, ppl235-70. Green-Pedersen, Christoffer (2001). ”Minority Governments and Party Politics: The Political and Institutional Background to the “Danish Miracle””, Journal of Public Policy, vol 21, no. 1, pp. 5370. Inglehart, Ronald (1997). Modernization and Postmodernization. Cultural, Economic, and Political Change in 43 Societies, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Kitschelt, Herbert (1988). “The Life Expectancy of Left-libertarian Parties. Does structural transformation or economic decline explain party innovation? A Response to Wilhelm P. Bürklin”, European Sociological Review, vol. 4, no. 2, pp. 155-60. Knutsen, Oddbjørn & Elinor Scarbrough (1995). “Cleavage Politics” pp. 492-523 in Jan W. van Deth & Elinor Scarbrough (eds.), The Impact of Values, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Lipset, Seymour Martin & Stein Rokkan (1967). “Cleavage Structures, Party Systems, and Voter Alignments: An Introduction”, pp. 1-64 in Seymour Martin Lipset & Stein Rokkan (eds.), Party Systems and Voter Alignments. Cross-National Perspectives, New York: The Free Press. Miller, Warren E. & Teresa E. Levitin (1976). Leadership & Change: The New Politics and the American Electorate, Cambridge, M.A.: Whinthrop Publishers. Müller, Wolfgang C., Torbjörn Bergman & Kaare Strøm (2008). ”Coalitions Theory and Cabinet Governance: An Introduction” pp. 1-50 in Kaare Strøm, Wolfgang C. Müller & Torbjörn Bergman (eds.), Cabinets and Coalition Bargaining: The Democratic Life Cycle in Western Europe, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Skjæveland, Asbjørn (2005). ”Dimensionaliteten i Folketinget: Er der en ny politisk dimension?”, Politica, vol. 37, no. 4, pp. 411-22. Strøm, Kaare (1990). Minority Government and Majority Rule, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Stubager, Rune (2006). The Education Cleavage: New Politics in Denmark, Aarhus: Forlaget Politica. Stubager, Rune (2010). “The Development of the Education Cleavage: Denmark as a Critical Case”, West European Politics, vol. 33, no. 3, pp. 305-33. 28