北京师范大学 教育研究方法讲座系列 (2): 教育政策研究 第七讲 教育政策实施过程的研究(一) The Top-down or Bottom–up Debate A. Theories of Policy Implementation: An Overview 1. The rational-technical and top-down approach: It indicates theoretical orientations taking implementation as a separate stage of the policy cycle, which is characterized as an enforcement and execution of the state’s policy decision. 2. The interpretive and bottom-up approach: It summarizes theoretical orientations conceiving implementation as process of interpretations, figuring out what to do and delivering concrete services to program/policy recipients on diverse localities and situations by “street-level bureaucrats within different organizational setting. 3. The top-down and bottom-up synthesis and the third generation of implementation theory: It characterizes theoretical orientations perceiving implementation as process of constituting coalition, structuration, networking, institutionalization, and learning within which various parties in a specific policy domain/area strive to realize a policy, program or project. B. The Rational-technical and Top-down Approach: 1. Policy implementation technical control of the execution of decisions from top down a. Sabatier and Mazmanian define that “implementation is the carrying out of a basic policy decision. …The implementation process normally runs through a number of stages i. beginning with passage of the basic status, ii. followed by the policy output (decisions) of the implementing agencies, iii. the compliance of the target groups with those decisions, the actual impact – both intended and unintended – of those outputs, iv. the perceived impacts of agency decisions, and v. finally, important revisions (or attempted revision) in the basic status.” (1995, p. 153; numbering mine) b. Accordingly, implementation is perceived as technical problems of control over the internality and externality of the policy, which has been specified by Sabarier and Mazmanian as follows i. Tractability of the problem - vailability of valid technical theory and technology - Diversity of target-group behavior - Target group as percentage of the population - Extent of behavior change required W.K. Tsang Policy Studies in Education 1 W.K. Tsang Policy Studies in Education 2 ii. Ability of status to structure implementation - Clear and consistent objectives - Incorporation of adequate causal theory - Financial resources - Hierarchical integration with and among implementing agency - Recruitment of implementing official - Formal access by outsiders iii. Non-statutory variables affecting implementation - Socioeconomic conditions and technology - Media attention to the problem - Public support - Attitudes and resource of constituency groups - Support from sovereign - Commitment and leadership skill of implementing officials c. Six sufficient and generally necessary conditions for effective implementation i. Clear and consistent objectives ii. Adequate causal theory iii. Implementation process legally structured to enhance W.K. Tsang Policy Studies in Education 3 compliance by implementing officials and target groups iv. Committed and skillful implementing officials v. Support of interest groups and sovereigns vi. Changes in socioeconomic conditions which do not substantially undermine political support or causal theory. 2. Hierarchy and market: the mechanism of policy implementation Weimer & Vining (2005) underline that there are two basic mechanisms in coordinating collective action into attaining societal objectives. One is through market mechanism and the other is state intervention through the bureaucratic hierarchy. a. Market mechanism: “Collective action enables society to produce, distribute, and consume a great variety and abundance of goods (and services). Most collective action arises from voluntary agreements among people - within families, private organizations and exchange relations.” (Weimer & Vining, 2005, p.30) i. Individual rational choice: According to the above-cited premise of liberal economic perspective, the basic decision units in collective actions are individual choices. It is further assumed that these basic units will act in accordance with the principles of maximization of utility and profit. ii. Prefect competitive market: At macroscopic level, these individual rational choices will meet and exchange in a prefect competitive market with the following operational principles/assumptions (Stiglitz & Walsh, 2002, p. 228; and Stiger, 1986; p. 267)) - All participants (Firms and individuals) take market price as given; i.e. numbers of participants are sufficiently large - Actions by individual participants do not directly affect other participants except through price, i.e. they act independently and freely and not collectively; - All participants must possess tolerable or even prefect knowledge of the market opportunities; - Goods are things that only the buyer can enjoy, i.e. they are private goods. They are of the nature + Rivalry in consumption + Excludability in use b. State intervention: State’s interventions into collective actions of production, distribution and consumption in society involve legitimately uses of coercive power in the name of market failure and/or compensating the losers in market. The means employed by the state are commonly called in public policy study the policy instrument. i. Conception of policy instrument: “Public policy instruments are the set of techniques by which governmental authorities wield their power in attempting to ensure support and effect or prevent social change.” (Veding, 1998, p.21) ii. Typology of policy instruments - Regulation (Sticks): they are “means undertaken by governmental unit to influence people by means of formulated rules and directives which mandate receivers to action in W.K. Tsang Policy Studies in Education 4 accordance with what is ordered in these rules and directive.” (p. 31) - Economic policy instruments (Carrots): They “involve either the handing out or the taking away of material resources, be they in cash or in kind. Economic instruments make it cheaper or more expensive in terms of money, time, effort, and other valuables to pursue certain actions (either compliance or defiance to policy measures).” (p. 32) - Information (Sermons): They refer “to as ‘moral suasion,’ or exhortation, covers attempts at influencing people through the transfer of knowledge, the communication of reasoned argument, and persuasion.” (p.33) c. Professional power as the third logic: Eliot Freidson contends that besides market and state, there is the third logic at work in public policy implementation process in modern society, namely professional power. i. The third logic in public policy: “For decades now, the popular watchwords driving policy formation (and implementation) have been ‘competition’ and ‘efficiency’, the first referring to competition in a free market, and the second to the benefit of the skilled management of firms (governmental agencies). …I will show in some detail how properties of professionalism fit together to form a whole that differs systematically from the free market on the one hand, and the …bureaucracy, in the other.” (Freidson, 2001, p.2-3) Therefore, Freidson contends that “like Max Weber’s model of rational-legal bureaucracy which represents managerialism and Adam Smith’s model of the free market which represents consumerism” (p. 180), “professionalism is conceived of as one of the three logically distinct methods of organizing and controlling.” (p.180) ii. Constituents of Professionalism: “Professionalism is based on specialized bodies of knowledge and skill that have no coercive power of their own but only what may be delegated to them by the state or capital. They gain their protected (and legitimate) status by project of successful persuasion, not by buying it or capturing it at the point of a gun. But because of the special nature of the knowledge and skill imputed to professionals as well as the fact that their practice is protected, friendly commentators have long invoked the need to trust their intention.” (p.214) Accordingly the constituents of professionalism may comprise - Academically respectable knowledge - Practically credible Skill - Socially trustful codes of ethnics and practices - Effective authority and autonomy over the above constituents W.K. Tsang Policy Studies in Education 5 C. The Interpretive and Bottom-up Model 1. Michael Lipsky’s street-level bureaucracy model a. Lipsky’s book entitled Street-level Level (1980) has been viewed as the leading challenge to the top-down model of policy implementation models and the starting point of bottom-up model. b. Lipsky “argue(s) that public policy is not best understood as made in legislatures or top-floor suites of high ranking administrators, because in important ways it is actually made in the crowded offices and daily encounters in street-level workers.” And “the street-level bureaucrats, the routines they establish, and the devices they invent to cope with uncertainties and work pressures, effectively become the public policies they carry out.” (Lipsky, 1993, p. 382) Accordingly, study of education policy implementation should look into teachers’ instructional routines delivered in crowded classrooms and school officials’ policy measures imposed upon teachers and students. c. Lipsky underlines that in implementing policy at street level, front-line worker are confronted with conflict and ambiguities. These may include i. Inadequate resource and unsatisfactory working condition, e.g. large classes for teachers, huge caseloads for social workers, dangerous and hostile neighborhood for police officers. ii. Unpredictable, uncooperative, skeptical clients iii. Unclear and ambiguous job specification and guidelines. d. Confronted with these inadequacies and uncertainties, street-level bureaucrats derive coping strategies or even survival strategies to deal with the unaccommodating working situations. Lipsky point out that in daily “client-processing” routines, street-level bureaucrats in fact have considerable amount of powers and discretions at their disposal, which may lead to substantial deviations from, if not complete alterations of, official and top-down policy specifications. These discretions or even deviations may take the from of i. Modification of client demand: This may include various devices to delay, deter or practically dissolve clients’ demands in overcrowded and overloaded working situations. ii. Modification of job conception: This may include strategies of lowering the service standards or even alteration of the natures and features of the services supposed to be delivered in order to ease the excessive demands. iii. Modification of client conception: This may include devices of differentiating clients into non-mandatory categories and to provide different service, e.g. “creaming off” the deserving or educable and “marginalizing” the undeserving and trouble-makers 2. Martin Rein’s down-ward puzzlement model a. Michael Rein (1983) puts forth a theoretical perspective of implementation by questioning the controllability of the implementation policy and injecting the concept of puzzlement and conflict into the study of policy implementation b. Rein does not conceptualize the policy implementation process and W.K. Tsang Policy Studies in Education 6 a clearly defined enforcement process, instead he contends that “Implementation is understood as a declaration of government preferences, mediated by a number of actors, who create a circular process characterized by reciprocal power relations and negotiations, then the actors must take into account three potentially conflicting imperatives: (a) the legal imperative to do what is legally required, (b) the rational-bureaucratic imperative to do what is rationally defensible, and the consensual imperative to do what can help to establish agreement among contending influential parties who have a stake in the outcome.” (p.118) c. Apart from the three components of the implementation process and the three conflicting imperatives, Rein has further specifies three types of primary actors in the implementation process. They are i. guideline developers, ii. interest groups, and iii. program administrators d. In view of such a complicate arena of implementation, Rein underlines that “policy implementation is a matter not only of power but of puzzlement, of ‘men collectively wondering what to do.’” (p.117) Such puzzlement is mainly derived from the following scenarios (p. 117) i. The program administrators and front-line works “do not know what is required of them (by the legislation or executive policy) (since they are asked either to pursue uncertain or evolving goals or reconcile incompatible requirements) ii. “The resources at hand are insufficient for the task.” iii. The workers “lack the knowledge and skill (and technology) to take action.” e. The downward spiral of puzzlement Rein further specifies that “When the purposes of policy are unclear and incompatible, each successive stage in the process of implementation provides a new context for seeking further clarification. One of the consequences of passing ambiguity an inconsistent legislation is that the arena of decision making shifts to a lower level. The everyday practitioners become the ones who resolve the lack of consensus through their concrete actions.” (p.117) 3. Richard Elmore’s organizational model a. Elmore asserts that one of the vital features of policy implementation is “the process by which policies are translated into administrative actions. …(And) the translation of an idea into action involves certain crucial simplification.” (Elmore, 1993, p. 313) b. Elmore further points out that “virtually all public policies are implemented by large public organization. …(And) organizations are simplifiers; they work on problems by breaking them into discrete, manageable tasks and allocating responsibility for those tasks to specialized units.” (1993, p. 313) In other words, organizations assigned with the task to carry out policies and programs may modify, simplify or even re-orientate the policies measures to suit the internal structures and conventional procedures of the organization. W.K. Tsang Policy Studies in Education 7 c. Therefore, knowledge about organizational model, which the policy-implementing agencies subscribe to, is vital to understand the policy implementation process. Elmore has then summarized four organizational models commonly found in public-policy delivering agencies. They are i. Systems management model ii. Bureaucratic process model iii. Organizational development model iv. Conflict and bargaining models d. Different organizational models will translate a given policy in different way. They will simplify or “localize” in accordance with their i. central principle, ii. power structure, iii. decision making procedure, and iv. implementation process Policy Implementation as process of translation and simplification through large public organization System Management Model Bureaucratic Process Model Organizational Development Model Conflict & Bargaining Model Central Principle Power Structure Decision Making Procedure Implementation Process Discrete manageable tasks& responsibilities assigned to specialized units W.K. Tsang Policy Studies in Education 8