Journal of Baltic Studies (forthcoming) Baltic States in World Markets: Does Katzenstein’s Framework Still Hold? Vytautas Kuokštis, Institute of International Relations and Political Science, Vilnius University Abstract Small states, argued Peter Katzenstein a quarter of a century ago, are different. Faced with the fluctuations of world markets, they adopt democratic corporatism and domestic compensation, thus ensuring political legitimacy and successful economic adjustment. The Baltic countries are an interesting case study for this framework, because in many ways they are ‘smaller’ than the seven countries analysed by Katzenstein. This article finds that, on a broader level, Katzenstein’s framework is very helpful in highlighting the key developments in the Baltic countries. On the other hand, the specific causal mechanism that can be drawn from this framework running from smallness to democratic corporatism to political legitimacy as well as domestic compensation has not developed in the Baltics. Key words: Katzenstein, small states, Baltic countries, democratic corporatism, legitimacy, domestic compensation 1 Introduction Small States in World Markets (SSWM) by Peter Katzenstein (1985) is a major work. At the time of writing this article, SSWM yields 3493 citations on Google Scholar. Since its publication, SSWM has inspired many lines of research and equipped scholars with new ways of thinking about issues in comparative and international political economy. In particular, Katzenstein managed to draw attention to small countries which had been neglected by previous scholars (Ingebritsen 2010). In his review of contemporary study of political economy, Mark Blyth (2009, p. 194) names SSWM as one of the three founding texts of the field, along with Peter Gourevitch’s Politics in Hard times (1986) and Peter Hall’s Governing the Economy (1986). Question is: how well does the theoretical framework of SSWM travel? Does it still apply a quarter of a century since its inception? In his own revisit of SSWM in 2003, Katzenstein recognized that while he had carefully delimited his investigation to seven early industrializers of the Western ‘core’ nations (Sweden, Norway, Denmark, the Netherlands, Belgium, Austria, Switzerland), his conclusions could be potentially fruitfully applied and tested in other contexts: ‘analysis could have pushed further by investigating, in addition, the strategies of other small states situated differently in the world economy’ (Katzenstein 2003, p. 13). Subsequent literature generally confirms Katzenstein’s insights in different temporal and geographical settings. According to Eric Jones (2008, p. 8), ‘Katzenstein’s thesis about small states and world markets remains relatively unchallenged’. The Baltic countries make a compelling case for testing the arguments of Katzenstein’s framework. Firstly they are small - indeed, they are smaller than the seven ‘dwarfs’ of SSWM. Recently, their smallness and vulnerability was painfully exposed by a very severe economic crisis in 2008-2010. Secondly, the Baltic countries seem to pose a challenge for Katzenstein’s 2 predictions – given that they are very small and vulnerable, it is puzzling why they have not developed democratic corporatism and strong domestic compensation mechanisms. This article therefore sets out to answer the question: does (and in what ways) the Baltic empirical experience fit into Katzenstein’s framework? The implications of Katzenstein’s book are quite diverse, which speaks of the contribution that SSWM has had to the scholarly community. At the same time, this gives rise to some confusion, as it is possible to derive different and sometimes even contradictory insights from Katzenstein’s work (or at least its interpretations). In this article, I provide two interpretations. One interpretation is a ‘narrow’ one that posits a specific causal connection that runs from smallness to corporatism and domestic compensation to legitimate and flexible economic adjustment. The other is a more general (‘broad’) interpretation providing guidelines for analysis and variables to look into rather than speaking about a specific causal chain. This ‘broad’ interpretation encourages scholars to seriously take into account history, ideas, and size; it also suggests political legitimacy as a precondition for the success of economic policy. The article surveys the current stock of literature on Baltic economic policy by framing it according to Katzenstein’s approach. It reveals that in certain ways the Baltic countries do not fit into Katzenstein’s framework (interpreted in a narrow way). While they are even smaller and thus more vulnerable than the seven countries of SSWM, of all the new EU member countries they have been the least inclined towards corporatism and domestic compensation policies. Furthermore, while Lithuania and Latvia show very low levels of political legitimacy measured by the level of trust in political institutions (which is compatible with the predictions of Katzenstein’s framework), Estonia, which in fact pursued the most consistent (neo)liberal policies, is characterized by relatively high levels of political 3 trust, and thus serves as a deviant case for Katzenstein’s theory formulated in a ‘narrow’ way. Nevertheless, the article concludes that the broader interpretation of SSWM illuminates the core themes of Baltic developments since regaining independence. This article argues that the broader interpretation helps to shed light on the emergence, continuity, and even on some aspects of the relative success of the Baltic politico-economic regimes (in particular Estonia’s better performance). Based on the analysis, it is concluded that SSWM continues to be of relevance to the study of politics and economics of small countries (and beyond). The first section describes Katzenstein’s original contribution and its two interpretations. The second section discusses and measures Baltic ‘smallness’. In the third section, the ‘narrow’ and ‘broad’ interpretations of SSWM are tested in the Baltic empirical case. The SSWM and its two interpretations Katzentein wrote his book in order to solve an interesting puzzle about small Western European countries (1985, p. 9). On the one hand, political scientists emphasized their political stability generated by corporatism. On the other hand, economists focused on their economic flexibility and successful performance. In SSWM, Katzenstein aimed to resolve this conundrum by arguing that these two aspects were in fact related: ‘they are not contradictory but mutually contingent’ (p. 9). He noted how other states could potentially 4 learn from their experience, as even ‘large industrial countries are beginning to experience an increasing economic openness and vulnerability’ (p. 9). Katzenstein chose to investigate the political economies of seven small Western European countries. Although he did not explicitly state what ‘smallness’ meant, he largely discussed such aspects as population and size of the economy. Importantly, smallness was also related to and to some extent captured by economic openness. Overall, Katzenstein noted that ‘small countries are more open and vulnerable than large ones, economically, politically, and militarily’ (1985, p. 81). Smallness and openness generate vulnerability stemming from changes in international economic conditions. Small countries are more vulnerable to these changes because they need depend heavily on imports. Furthermore, they tend to specialize in certain sectors and are thus less well diversified. Finally, important parameters of economic performance, such as growth rates and inflation, are heavily influenced by outside forces. Overall, according to Katzenstein, all countries must find ways to respond to global economic change. However, there are three basic responses. First, ‘liberal countries such as the United States rely on macroeconomic policies and market solutions’ combined with ‘limited, ad hoc protectionist policies’ (p. 23). Second, ‘statist countries such as Japan are endowed with the means and the institutions to pre-empt the costs of change through policies that pursue the structural transformation of their economies’ (p. 23). Small countries, however, do not have the means to adopt either of these two approaches. Instead, the elites in small European countries ‘live with change by compensating for it’ (p. 24). They have ‘a preference for a reactive and flexible policy of industrial adjustment (…) relying heavily on indirect policy instruments such as taxation rather than broad-gauged political efforts to transform the structures of their economies’ (p. 27). 5 What is this ‘domestic compensation’? It includes measures such as welfare spending to compensate the losers from economic changes and reduce the uncertainty stemming from market fluctuations. According to Katzenstein, ‘these policies are carried by the conviction that it is important to counter some of the harmful effects of international liberalization’ (1985, p. 47). This is what explains a faster growth of public economy in smaller states than in large ones in Europe (Katzenstein 1985, p. 54). Besides, these small countries ‘have tried to restrain their wages and, occasionally, prices through a governmentcoordinated incomes policy (as in the Netherlands and Denmark), or through a centralized system of collective bargaining (as in Sweden and Norway), or though some combination of the two (as in Austria)’ (Katzenstein 1985, p. 56). Wage restraint is used to ensure competitiveness and adjust to balance of payments problems. In turn, the policies of domestic compensation allow for securing political legitimacy: ‘through their policies, political leaders in the small European states have maintained the legitimacy of the political arrangements governing their societies (…) Political leaders retain a tight hold on mass participation, and electoral changes have been very small’ (Katzenstein 1985, p. 28). In his follow-up article writing about the small Western European industrialized countries, Katzenstein (2003, p. 19) notes that ‘since for decades their policies offered generous social protection against international dislocations, confidence levels are high and stable’. Katzenstein (1985, p. 28) acknowledges that legitimacy is a ‘broad construct’ and difficult to measure. When writing about legitimacy, he refers to such aspects as trust in politicians and political institutions, high levels of participation, small electoral changes and lack of protests (Katzenstein 1985, p. 28). Both domestic compensation policies and political legitimacy are created via the institutions of ‘democratic corporatism’. Katzenstein distinguishes the ‘democratic corporatism’ characteristic of small industrialized Western European states from 6 authoritarian corporatism (e.g. in fascist Italy) or ‘state capitalism’ (e.g. in Japan). Democratic corporatism has the following characteristics (Katzenstein, 1985, p. 32): ‘an ideology of social partnership expressed at the national level; a relatively centralized and concentrated system of interest groups; and voluntary and informal coordination of conflicting objectives through continuous political bargaining between interest groups, state bureaucracies, and political parties’. Corporatist institutions ensure greater political stability and consensual, rather than confrontational, policies. Eric Jones (2008, p. 9) stated this in the following way: ‘small states are more consensual because they are more vulnerable to world market forces (and because they are aware of that vulnerability)’. All of these preconditions also ensure a successful adjustment to changing economic conditions. Political legitimacy and consensual politics reduce tension within society and form a basis for the search for flexible solutions and policy learning. Furthermore, coordinated wage bargaining helps to avoid deteriorating competitiveness and associated macroeconomic problems. Narrow interpretation One possible way of reading SSWM is extracting a specific causal chain running from smallness to vulnerability to corporatism and domestic compensation to political legitimacy and finally to successful economic performance. Smallness (vulnerability) increases the chances for (or leads to, if stated deterministically) democratic corporatism and domestic compensation policies. Domestic compensation refers to the size of the public sector, and especially welfare spending. In Hardiman’s words, ‘the “compensation hypothesis” holds that increasing trade exposure gives rise to pressures for an expansion in public spending, especially on welfare items’ (Hardiman, Murphy & Burke 2008, p. 599). Of course, Katzenstein has not been the only author to lay out this argument. 7 Other authors provided theoretical and empirical support for the assertion that increased economic openness leads to public sector growth (e.g. Rodrik 1998). It is interesting that in his follow-up article, Katzenstein (2003, p. 22) makes a specific prediction about the future development of Eastern European capitalist systems, including those in the Baltic countries. After noticing what he saw as corporatist trends, he outlines his expectations: The emerging social market economies are unlikely to resemble statist or neoliberal variants of capitalism. It is more likely that they will have greater resemblance with the institutions of the German variant of capitalism, among the large industrial states the closest cousin of the democratic corporatism of the small European states. Focusing on the second part of the causal argument, democratic corporatism and domestic compensation create condition for political legitimacy. This, in turn, helps to secure successful economic performance. The prediction is that countries (at least small ones) which have democratic corporatist institutions as well as strong domestic compensation will be more successful economically and, even more importantly, politically, and as a result more trust in political institutions. One should note here that this assertion also implies a counterfactual: in the absence of democratic corporatist arrangements and domestic compensation policies, wide economic fluctuations would preclude the build-up of political legitimacy and trust or erode its existing stock. Overall, the expectation is that small open countries lacking legitimacy due to lack of democratic corporatism and domestic compensation will be less economically and politically successful. 8 Broad interpretation However there is another way of interpreting SSWM. In contrast to the ‘narrow’ version, the ‘broader’ interpretation refers not to specific causal connections outlined above, but rather to a more general way of approaching the study of political economy in particular and politics in general. What I mean by ‘broad’ interpretation in this article is the position to take into account size (smallness) as a variable, analyse ideas and history, as well as recognize the importance of political legitimacy in affecting economic performance. Note that only the first item focuses on differentiating small states from larger ones. History, ideas and political legitimacy are important regardless of state size. To begin with, one of the main lessons of SSWM is that size is important and should be treated as a variable rather than a constant. In ‘Small States and Small States Revisited’, Katzenstein (2003) briefly explains his motivation for writing SSWM. SSWM was a follow-up on an earlier research project – Between Power and Plenty (Katzenstein 1977) – and an attempt to address some of the latter’s drawbacks. One of the chief ones was inattention to size as an explanatory variable. Smallness and vulnerability – Katzenstein maintains – have important and far-reaching consequences for the development and functioning of small countries’ politico-economic regimes. Of course, the ‘narrow’ interpretation also focuses on the effects of smallness, but it formulates a specific prediction on its role. By contrast, the ‘broad’ version simply states that size is significant, but the way it affects any country’s political economy and politics is contingent. The second implication of SSWM is the significance of history. Specifically, ‘in the small European states (…) a tradition of accomodative politics dating back beyond the nineteenth century facilitated the political reorientation that took place in the 1930s and 1940s’ (Katzenstein 1985, p. 35). In SSWM, Katzenstein claims that history is important, which means that there are powerful continuities to a given country’s economic and political 9 strategies as well as the related policy choices. He explains the emergence of and differences in democratic corporatism historically. In other words, choices are not simply made in an abstract vacuum, but rather are conditioned by historical context. In explaining the emergence and continuities of the corporatist systems in small Western nations, Katzenstein turns to their experience of vulnerability in the first half of the twentieth century. One of the conditions for the formation of democratic corporatism, Katzenstein argues, was weak political right. Notice that this argument is in some contradiction with the first causal link of the ‘narrow’ interpretation, because vulnerability alone is no longer enough to produce corporatism – rather, democratic corporatism is a product of two necessary but insufficient conditions: (perception of) vulnerability and weak political right. In fact, adopting a historically informed perspective it’s possible to argue that this corrected version of the causal chain is still flawed in the sense that while vulnerability and weak right produced corporatism in the specific temporal and spatial context (industrialized small western countries), it might not occur in other contexts. In other words, causal processes are contextspecific and should be treated as such. Third, SSWM highlighted the significance of ideas. In his revisit of SSWM, Katzenstein (2003, p. 11) writes this: What really mattered politically was the perception of vulnerability, economic and otherwise. Perceived vulnerability generated an ideology of social partnership that had acted like a glue for the corporatist politics of the small European states. This was the first and most important explanatory variable in Small States. Katzenstein continues noting that this point was largely missed in the reception and reviews that followed SSWM’s publication. He argues that the field of political economy was not yet ready to include ideas as an important and researchable variable into the analysis of political and economic reality. Consequently, Mark Blyth (1997, p. 201) sees the seeds of constructivist political economy in Katzenstein’s work: 10 This is why Small States is more than a synthesis of coalitional and institutional approaches. It also opened the door to moving beyond them, to put ideas and social constructions front and center in political economy explanations rather than treat them as a residual category to mop up variance unexplained by these other approaches. Finally, Katzenstein’s work attests to the importance of political legitimacy. As Herman Schwartz (2010, p. 365) points out, it is exactly the issue of political legitimacy, and not economic efficiency, that is at the core of SSWM: ‘Small States in World Markets is about political efficacy and legitimation rather than scoring who is ahead in the economic sweepstakes. Its case for democratic corporatism rests on norms, particularly stability, rather than on narrow measures of economic efficiency’. In Katzenstein’s words, ‘economic performance, then, is not a yardstick by which we can directly measure the successes and failures of the small European states’ (Katzenstein 1985, p. 28). Still, even if economic performance was not the key issue in SSWM, one can draw the implication that political legitimacy does matter for economic performance. Political legitimacy here refers to the same concept as described above under the ‘narrow’ interpretation. Furthermore, it does not contradict the causal chain posited above about the positive influence of political legitimacy on economic performance. However, the ‘broader’ version, in contrast to the ‘narrow’ interpretation, does not hold that democratic corporatism and domestic compensation are necessary conditions for political legitimacy. Furthermore, the ‘dividends’ of high legitimacy potentially encompass other dimensions of economic performance not covered in SSWM. For instance, scholars argue that trust in political institutions might be important in encouraging tax morale and therefore fiscal performance (Torgler 2003). 11 Baltic smallness Before turning to the analysis and initial comparison of Baltic ‘smallness’ to the ‘size’ of original countries analysed in SSWM, it is relevant to ask whether one is not comparing apples and oranges in this case as the background conditions of the two countries are very different. First of all, the primary goal of the article is not the comparison of these two groups. Even so, while in some regards these two groups of countries greatly diverge, one must also remember that neither the ‘narrow’ nor the ‘broad’ versions of the framework speak against such a comparison or the extension of the framework to new cases. The ‘narrow’ version as formulated in the theoretical part does not limit itself to any particular geographical or historical setting and in fact predicts a universal (although possibly probabilistic rather than deterministic) relationship between smallness on the one hand and domestic compensation, democratic corporatism and legitimacy on the other. In contrast, the ‘broad’ version is sensitive to a particular historical, social and ideational setting, but again the way it is formulated (sensitivity to size, ideas, history and legitimacy) does not preclude applying the approach elsewhere. Finally, as already mentioned, Katzenstein admitted the desirability of applying the framework to new settings and even made predictions about the emerging political economies in Eastern Europe. Turning to the analytic part, in economic terms the Baltic countries are ‘smaller’ than the seven countries of SSWM, and thus make interesting cases for studying how SSWM’s framework fits their experience. Table 1 below reveals that the Baltic countries are generally indeed ‘smaller’ (more vulnerable) than the original ‘dwarfs’. This is true both in terms of absolute GDP figures and population size. Furthermore, volatility of economic conditions in the Baltic countries – as illustrated by standard deviation of annual GDP growth – is way higher than the one experienced by the 7 ‘SSWM countries’. Behind this statistic lies the story of a recent roller-coaster ride of the Baltic countries – after posting 12 impressive growth numbers in the run-up to the crisis, all three Baltic States recorded double digit contractions in 2009. A similar, although less dramatic, story occurred a decade ago when the Baltic countries were hit by the Russian crisis in 1998-1999. As Aldis Austers (2014, p. 9) puts it, ‘the crisis of 2008-2010 can be seen as just another episode in a drama related to Latvian experience in a capitalistic world’. Only in terms of trade openness do the ‘7 dwarfs’ match the Baltic ‘smallness’. Table 1 here Smallness and vulnerability are not confined to the economic realm, but can also be generated by political conditions. Baltic countries historically have been exposed to larger threats with real possibilities of national extinction than the ‘7 dwarfs’. Due to their unfavourable geopolitical location, they often found themselves at the crossroads of great power politics. During the twentieth century alone they gained independence from Tsarist Russia, only to be occupied by the Soviet Union and then by Nazi Germany and once again by the Soviet Union. Finally independence was restored after fifty years of Communist rule that involved not only the loss of independence but also massive deportations and a complete changeover of the socio-economic system. As was put by Lamoreaux and Galbreath (p. 1), ‘in 1940 and 1944, smallness meant forced incorporation into the Soviet Union’. Problems with Russia continue till the present days. Even the entrance into the EU (European Union) and NATO (North Atlantic Treaty Organisation) did not calm these tensions: ‘five years after the double enlargement, the permafrost in Baltic-Russian relations shows no signs of melting, but instead seems to thrive in the increasingly chilly climate of the Russo-Western relationship’ (Berg & Ehin 2009, p. 1). Furthermore, in Lithuania’s case 13 one can observe re-emergence of problems with Poland that have been muted over much of the recent independence period. In Estonia and Latvia, the sense of vulnerability is fostered because of big ethnic Russian minorities. Recent Russian actions in Ukraine involving annexation of Crimea on the grounds of protecting local Russians have added to the Baltic sense of vulnerability. In response to these events, all three Baltic countries requested stronger signs of commitment and security guarantees from their NATO partners. In the words of Maria Mälksoo (2006, p. 277), ‘The quest of the Baltic states for membership in the EU and NATO has been the politics of survival par excellence, aimed at securing Western security guarantees against historically aggressive and unstable neighbouring Russia’. Mälksoo (2006, p. 277) concludes that ‘despite certain relief in their immediate security concerns after the dual enlargement, the shift by the Baltic states from existential politics to normal politics is far from being accomplished’. Narrow interpretation and Baltic experience 1. Smallness democratic corporatism and domestic compensation I will start with the narrower interpretation. Turning to the first link in the causal chain, things immediately get complicated for the theory. Given that the Baltic countries are small and very open, based on the ‘narrow’ version one would have expected them, first, to develop democratic corporatism and, second, to have strong policies of domestic compensation. Neither of these happened. First, the Baltic countries are actually some of the least corporatist in the EU. According to Thorhallsson and Kattel (2012, p. 2), Estonia is ‘an ideal test case of the advantages and disadvantages of small European states that have not followed the corporatist trend’. Trade unions in the Baltic countries are weak, with little capacity to influence public policy. Baltic 14 trade unions have one of the lowest density rates in the EU and among the new member states (see Table 2). Furthermore, density rates have been declining fast. From 2003 to 2008 total trade union membership declined by 16 percent in Latvia, 18 percent in Estonia and 34 percent in Lithuania (Carley 2009). The Baltic countries were among the six EU members were these figures fell most significantly in that period. Employers in the Baltics are not organized either (Norkus 2008, p. 632). There are no formal or informal nation-wide wage bargaining processes in the Baltic countries. According to Bohle and Greskovits (2007, p. 447), Baltic countries are characterized by ‘low union density, decentralized, uncoordinated wage bargaining and low coverage rates of collective agreements’. Several scholars (Feldmann 2006; Norkus 2008) have compared two small new EU member states, Estonia and Slovenia, and concluded that they approximate two opposite models of capitalist systems that emerged after transition. In contrast to Estonia (one could also argue Lithuania and Latvia), Slovenia is an example of ‘democratic corporatism’ with institutionalized practices of interest (both employers’ and employees’) representation. Slovenia most closely approximates the small country model analysed in the SSWM. Interestingly, during the last crisis of 2008-2010 the weak rudiments of democratic corporatism were neglected even further (Gonser 2010) and thus the existing institutional structure reinforced. Economic adjustment packages – which were based on very high levels of fiscal consolidation involving a mixture of spending cuts and tax increases – were crafted very quickly, after little consultation with social groups. According to Kallaste and Woolfson (2013, p. 253), in the Baltics ‘a negotiated response was either not sought at all by governments or was of minor importance at all levels of interaction between the social partners. If anything, national-level social dialogue deteriorated, remaining at a low level even after the crisis had peaked’. 15 As for domestic compensation, the Baltic countries have one of the smallest public sectors in the EU (see Figure 1). Table 2 provides several more specific indicators of the extent of domestic compensation, such as welfare state (social) expenditure, state support for businesses as well as labour market policy expenditure. Baltic countries emerge generally as less compensating than other new member states and substantially less than the EU average. As Bohle and Greskovits (2007) describe, the Baltic countries feature a low level of ‘protection’ for society and domestic businesses from fluctuations in economic conditions. Figure 1 here In other words, contrary to the narrow interpretation of SSWM (and Katzenstein’s predictions in 2003), smallness and vulnerability in the Baltic countries, reinforced by severe economic crises, did not lead to democratic corporatism and substantial domestic compensation. Table 2 here. 2. Lack of democratic corporatism and domestic compensation low political legitimacy Next, given that the Baltic countries opted for non-corporatist regimes, one should follow the counterfactual derived in the theoretical section: one should see lower and/or eroding levels of trust in political institutions that are measures for the broader concept of 16 political legitimacy. Does empirical evidence support this prediction? Latvia’s and Lithuania’s situation is indeed compatible with this interpretation: political trust (i.e. trust in political institutions) in these countries is very low (see Table 3 below). The absence of domestic compensation policies can at least be advanced as a strong candidate explanation for these facts, although the usual caveat about correlation versus causation holds. One fact undermining this explanation is that during the ‘fat years’ before the crisis with very rapid wage and public expenditure growth did not bring higher levels of trust. In 2007, only 24 percent of Lithuanians and 19 percent of Latvians and as many as 62 percent of Estonians said they tended to trust their national parliament (European Commission 2008, p. 56). Table 3 here Nevertheless, Estonia’s situation is incompatible with the second link of the ‘narrow’ interpretation of Katzenstein’s theory (see Table 2). Estonia has actually pursued even more (neo)liberal policies (for instance, it liberalized trade policies most radically and the earliest of the three Baltic nations, and was the first to adopt a very strict monetary arrangement, the Currency board), but it has also managed to build up a solid trust base. Furthermore, electoral volatility in Estonia has been lower than in Latvia and Lithuania (Powell & Tucker 2013, p. 9). The latest elections in 2011 after the economic crisis confirmed this trend – in fact, the incumbent Reform Party increased its number of seats even after implementing austerity measures during a very painful economic crisis. Writing on the continuing political legitimacy of small Western corporatist countries, Katzenstein in 2003 (p. 19) noted that ‘an indirect reflection of the learning capacity and performance of the small European states is the relatively constant and high 17 levels of confidence in political institutions that their citizens express, in sharp contrast to declining and relatively low levels in the large industrial states’. By that measure, Estonia has held up well. According to Standard Eurobarometer, in the spring of 2010, just after a double-digit contraction of GDP in 2009 and a spike in unemployment, Estonians were among the most optimistic in the EU regarding the direction of their country. The percentage of people who supported the ‘direction where the country was going’ was 47 percent, only surpassed by Sweden (61 percent) (European Commission 2010, p. 111). In other words, Estonia is a deviant case for the ‘narrow’ interpretation of Katzenstein’s theory: high level of legitimacy exists despite the posited necessary condition – corporatist arrangements and strong domestic compensation (see section ‘Discussion and conclusions’ below for a possible explanation of why this might be the case). 3. Lack of corporatism and domestic compensation low political legitimacy lower success in economic adjustment The final causal link relates to political legitimacy's influence on the success of economic adjustment. Regarding this last link, no easy verdict can be passed on SSWM framework in the Baltic case. First, SSWM spoke about political legitimacy produced by corporatist arrangements and domestic compensation. Since Estonian legitimacy has been caused by other factors, one could argue that the analysis of legitimacy’s influence on economic performance is invalid with reference to SSWM framework. Second, SSWM spoke about legitimacy giving rise to the necessary flexibility in adjustment related to industrial policy. What the Baltic countries did during the last crisis (and before) was not engage in increased domestic compensation or flexible industrial adaptation but to opt for orthodox macro-management with the aim to ensure macroeconomic and financial stability. 18 In other words, they sought to solve the crisis in the same familiar way, with little flexibility or rethinking of their approach (although with a very high level of flexibility in terms of labour market adjustment (i.e. fall in wages), which is a completely different matter). Whether this continuity is a good thing from a normative perspective is an open question At least in terms of response to the last economic crisis, the answer depends on whether the results were ‘successful’. On the one hand, the Baltic countries managed to preserve the fixed exchange rate and return to fiscal sustainability. At the same time, they suffered very big economic contractions, saw increased emigration and there are indicators in Latvia and Lithuania to suggest that populations were largely dissatisfied with the approach to the crisis (Kuokštis and Vilpišauskas 2010). Despite very similar background conditions, including external economic and political challenges (vulnerability), the fact that Baltic countries score so differently on political trust makes them an interesting case to see whether Estonia’s higher score helped the country in terms of their specific chosen adjustment. Still, such an interpretation goes significantly beyond the ‘narrow’ causal chain posited above and will be covered in the following section under ‘broad’ interpretation. Broad interpretation and Baltic experience To clarify, the four broad implications of Katzenstein’s framework emphasize four different aspects. Three of them (the importance of history, ideas, and size) point to a broad ‘politico-economic regime’ or economic policy package. By themselves, they are normatively neutral (history can affect economic policies in all sorts of ways, as can ideas or perception of vulnerability). In contrast, the fourth implication – political legitimacy’s influence on economic results – has clear normative connotations: the hypothesis is that high 19 level of political legitimacy helps to adjust successfully in economic terms (although not necessarily using corporatist institutions and domestic compensation). The Baltic experience since transition demonstrates the limits of purely materialist/rationalist accounts Dorothee Bohle and Bela Greskovits (2007) as well as Rawi Abdelal (2001) on different grounds have argued convincingly for the importance of ideational dimension in accounting for the formation of Baltic capitalist systems in the 1990s. Abdelal contrasts the experience of Lithuania, Belarus and Ukraine after the collapse of the Soviet Union and concludes that identity was the crucial explanatory factor for radically different foreign economic policy orientations chosen by the three countries (Westoriented, East-oriented, and ambiguous respectively). Bohle and Greskovits aim to describe and explain the types of capitalism that emerged in the new EU member states. In their words, ‘the decisions concerning the new regimes have been motivated both by the legacies of the past and their perception as either threats or assets from the viewpoint of national sovereignty and economic independence’ (Bohle & Greskovits 2007, p. 444). Their argument is bolstered by the fact that objective structural conditions cannot account for the divergence in development of the Baltic countries on the one hand and the Visegrad group as well as Slovenia on the other. For instance, industrial structure measured in terms of product sophistication in the early 1990s was similar, and only diverged later (Bohle & Greskovits 2007, p. 459). Ideas could also explain why trade unions played and continue to play such a small role in the Baltics. As Gonser put it, trade unions in the Baltics are ‘associated with the past and, therefore, objected in many cases’ (Gonser 2010, p. 2). In general, leftist economic and social policy ideas in the Baltics suffered greatly during the transition, in contrast to, for instance, Slovenia. According to Norkus, ex-communists in the Baltics essentially implemented neoliberal economic policies (2008, p. 623). The Baltic experience is very much compatible with Katzenstein’s assertion that ‘in the rationalist 20 world of political economy actor identities are assumed to be fixed and unproblematic, an intellectually untenable position in the case of the small European states, and perhaps more generally’ (Katzenstein 2003, p. 11). Moreover, the choices made during the transition period, as has already been mentioned, were closely related to the (perception of) vulnerability stemming from ‘smallness’, just as would be indicated by the ‘broad’ version of Katzenstein’s framework. It was the perception of this threat that moved the Baltic countries to pursue very liberal economic policy. As Bohle and Greskovits write, ‘these countries could neither take their nation nor their state institutions for granted, and inherited the least favourable legacies in terms of economic institutions from state socialism’ (Bohle & Greskovits 2007, p. 444). Elsewhere Greskovits writing about Estonia notes that ‘stability culture and trust in its guardians, the currency board, a balanced budget, and central bankers, could become a cornerstone of national identity, especially as measures to foster national independence and transformation have been introduced as part and parcel of the same policy package’ (Greskovits 2009, p. 211). This sense of geopolitical threat could also be one of the explanations why the Baltic countries are among the ones most eager to join the Eurozone (Estonia did this in 2011, Latvia in 2014 and Lithuania is expected to join from 2015). Interestingly, Latvia started showing more determination to join the Eurozone after the Great Recession than Lithuania, although there were no significant changes in structural-economic conditions. A plausible candidate to explain this difference is the fact that Latvia went through a bigger crisis than Lithuania. Latvia was the only country that experienced a collapse of a major domestic bank during the crisis and was forced to turn to international financial assistance. In turn, this could have produced a higher sense of ‘smallness’ and ‘vulnerability’. In the theoretical part, it was also argued that Katzenstein’s framework interpreted broadly can be seen to argue for the importance of ‘history’. History means that 21 policy choices are prone to inertia – i.e. the more some course of action and policies had been applied in the past, the likelier it is that they will be continued. The experience of the Baltic countries indeed reflects this. A good example can be the very high level of support for fixed exchange rates specifically and currency board systems more generally. Kuokštis and Vilpišauskas (2010) analyse how the decision to preserve the fixed exchange rates rather than seek currency devaluation during the last crisis did not stem from international pressure or simple material interests. Instead, fixed exchange rate systems which had been created in early 1990s became stronger over time, as they anchored macroeconomic stability and also increased the number of interest groups incentivized to support them. Furthermore, writing about fiscal policy choices during the crisis, Raudla and Kattel (2011, p. 163) argue that these ‘became path-dependent as a result of positive feedback loops from previous periods of fiscal consolidation’. Interestingly, most outside observers predicted the collapse of fixed exchange rate regimes in the Baltic countries, but this did not happen (Kuokštis and Vilpišauskas 2010). Sensitivity to the specific historical context of the Baltic countries as suggested by the ‘broad’ interpretation of SSWM would likely have precluded such acontextual, excessively bold predictions. Furthermore, it is exactly this sensitivity to context and history that allows us to answer why smallness failed to foster democratic corporatism and extensive domestic compensation in the Baltics, as would have been predicted by the ‘narrow’ interpretation. While smallness found its way into democratic corporatist arrangements in the states analysed in SSWM, under specific Baltic conditions existing in the early transition a high degree of vulnerability was channelled into a different set of institutions. As Katzenstein (1985, p. 136) put it, ‘small size is thus not treated as master variable that somehow forces a particular political solution – the relationship between small size and democratic corporatism is historically contingent rather than logically necessary’. Finally, one should deal with the importance of political legitimacy, and 22 specifically its effect on economic performance. As has been mentioned, during the last crisis for the Baltic countries the major challenges arose and most important actions were taken in the domain of fiscal policy. While all three Baltic countries chose to pursue very similar adjustment policies in the form of macroeconomic austerity, Estonia’s attempts were clearly more successful. The northern-most of the three Baltic countries had prepared better for the crisis by accumulating fiscal reserves, reacted faster when the crisis started, and was also able to reduce budget deficit much more successfully, enabling it to join the Eurozone from 2011. Compared to 2008, in 2009 public deficit as percentage of GDP expanded by 5.6 percentage points in Latvia, 6.1 percentage points in Lithuania and it actually decreased by 0.9 percentage points in Estonia, although all three countries were experiencing double-digit contractions in real economic activity (author’s calculations based on Eurostat data). Economic-structural conditions cannot account for this difference, as broad economic developments as well as tax and spending policies were very similar in the Baltic countries (Kuokštis 2012). One convincing explanation is that these factors – crisisreadiness, faster reaction and more successful results of tax policies – can be explained by a gap in political trust among the three Baltic countries mentioned earlier. Correlation is not causation, of course, but given the large empirically grounded literature on the relationship between trust and tax compliance and very similar economic trends, there seems to be a strong case for linking Estonia’s better performance to its larger stock of political trust (Kuokštis 2012). So while the specific causal link was different from the one posited under the ‘narrow’ interpretation, the Baltic experience demonstrates the role of political legitimacy in ensuring the success of economic policies. 23 Discussion and conclusions How does Katzenstein’s theory hold when faced with the empirical case of the Baltic countries? The answer to this question depends on which interpretation (narrow or broad) of the SSWM is applied. In terms of the narrow interpretation, the empirical Baltic case, especially Estonia, presents serious challenges to the framework. At the same time, the broad version is useful in highlighting the main developments in the Baltics since regaining independence. Regarding the ‘narrow’ interpretation, the Baltic countries do present important problems for Katzenstein’s framework. First, vulnerability stemming from high degree of economic openness as well as a special geopolitical situation did not lead to high level of domestic compensation and corporatist practices. Quite to the contrary – the Baltic countries are some of the least corporatist and ‘compensating’ countries among the EU member states. It has to be noted that Bohle and Greskovits provide an interpretation which is more compatible with Katzenstein’s account – namely that loans from Western banks served as compensation mechanisms substituting for real welfare policies (Bohle & Greskovits 2009). Even so, this interpretation only refers to the compensation side and leaves out corporatism, and in this regard still fails to corroborate the causal chain of SSWM. Second, it is doubtful whether credit booms were a result of a conscious effort by politicians to provide compensation policies, rather than an outcome of the specific construction of Baltic macroeconomic regimes (in other words, credit booms in the Baltics seems to have been due to an error of omission rather than commission). Still, Latvian and Lithuanian empirical record is compatible with the second link in the SSWM causal chain – given the absence of corporatist and significant welfare policies, the observation of very low levels of trust within Latvian and Lithuanian societies is in line with the ‘narrow’ version of Katzenstein’s framework. The caveat here is that a 24 comprehensive test of causal rather than correlational association of these two variables has been outside the scope of the article. The Estonian case is a different story, though. Its relatively high level of political legitimacy and anti-corporatist policies is a significant challenge toward Katzenstein’s framework when interpreted in a narrow sense. What can explain this? To the best of my knowledge, no attempt has been made in the literature to tackle this puzzle. Examination of this question is beyond the confines of this article, but it is possible to formulate a suggestion for future research. The hypothesis is that Estonians trust their government more despite the fact that their government's performance is well below that of, say, Scandinavian countries, but because it is relatively better than that in its ‘reference’ group – which can in turn be hypothesized to be the two other Baltic countries, Latvia and Lithuania. These two serve as natural reference points for Estonians, because all three Baltic countries started at almost identical positions in early 1990s in terms of economic development and political situation, yet Estonia emerged fairly quickly as the leader of the pack, and its governments have been able to exploit this relative lead vis-à-vis the other Baltic States both in terms of relative indicators of performance (e.g. GDP growth or corruption indices) as well as specific landmarks of achievement (e.g. being invited to negotiate with the European Union first and more recently – the first of the three to enter the Eurozone). The broader interpretation of SSWM does reveal crucial elements of recent Baltic economic and political history. Size matters, and so does history, ideas, and political legitimacy. However, ‘smallness’ effects are context-dependent – while smallness and vulnerability matter, the specific way that they matter can be very different. This is where ‘history’ and ‘ideas’ enter the scene – the specific Baltic situation at the beginning of transition meant that the perception of vulnerability was channelled to (neo)liberal policies 25 reflecting the desire to abandon the previous socio-economic system, consolidate nationhood and integrate into the Western political and economic structures. 26 References Austers, A. (2014) ‘Latvia’s Controversial “Success Story”,’ in Bukovskis, K. (ed) (2014) The Politics of Economic Sustainability: Baltic and Visegrad Responses to the European Economic Crisis (Riga, Latvian Institute of International Affairs). Abdelal, R. (2001) National Purpose in the World Economy: Post-Soviet States in Comparative Perspective (Ithaca, Cornell University Press). Berg, E., & P. Ehin. (eds) (2009) Identity and foreign policy: Baltic-Russian relations and European integration (Burlington: Ashgate Publishing). Blyth, M. (2009) ‘An Approach to Comparative Analysis or a Subfield within a Subfield? Political Economy,’ in Lichbach, M. I. & Zuckerman, A. S. (eds) (2009) Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press), pp. 193-219. Bohle, D. & B. Greskovits (2007) ‘Neoliberalism, embedded neoliberalism and neocorporatism: Towards transnational capitalism in Central-Eastern Europe,’ West European Politics 30, 3, pp. 443–466. Bohle, D. & B. Greskovits (2009) ‘East-Central Europe’s Quandary,’ Journal of Democracy, 20, 4, pp. 50-63. Carley, M. (2009) ‘Trade union membership 2003-2008,’ European industrial relations observatory online, available http://www.eurofound.europa.eu/eiro/studies/tn0904019s/tn0904019s.htm, at: accessed 10 March 2014. European Commission, Eurobarometer 68, May 2008, available at: http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/eb/eb68/eb_68_en.pdf, accessed 12 March 2014. 27 European Commission, Eurobarometer 73, November 2010, available at: http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/eb/eb73/eb73_vol1_en.pdf, accessed 20 October 2012. Feldmann, M. (2006) ‘Emerging Varieties of Capitalism in Transition Countries. Industrial Relations and Wage Bargaining in Estonia and Slovenia,’ Comparative Political Studies, 39, 7, pp. 829-864. Gonser, M. (2010) ‘How Hard a Blow for the Collective Representation of Labour Interests? - The Baltic Industrial Relations and the Financial Crisis,’ Emecon, 1, available at: http://www.emecon.eu/current-issue/gonser/. Gourevitch, P. (1986) Politics in Hard times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises (Ithaca, Cornell University Press). Greskovits, B. (2009) ‘Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity,’ in Dyson, K. H. F. & Marcussen, M. (eds) (2009) Central Banks in the Age of the Euro: Europeanization, Convergence, and Power (Oxford, Oxford University Press). Hall, P. (1986) Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France (Oxford, Oxford University Press). Hardiman, N., P. Murphy & O. Burke (2008) ‘The Politics of Economic Adjustment in a Liberal Market Economy: The Social Compensation Hypothesis Revisited,’ Irish Political Studies, 23, 4, pp. 599-626. Ingebritsen, C. (2010) ‘Katzenstein’s Legacy 25 Years After: Small States in World Markets,’ European Political Science, 9, 3, pp. 359–364. 28 Jones, E. (2008) Economic adjustment and political transformation in small states (Oxford, Oxford University Press). Kallaste, E. & C. Woolfson (2013) ‘Negotiated Responses to the Crisis in the Baltic countries,’ Transfer: European Review of Labour and Research, 19, 2, pp. 253-266. Katzenstein, P. J. (2003) ‘Small States and Small States Revisited,’ New Political Economy, 8, 1, pp. 9–30. Katzenstein, P. J. (1985) Small states in world markets: industrial policy in Europe (Ithaca: Cornell University Press). Katzenstein, P. J. (ed.) (1977) Between power and plenty: Foreign economic policies of advanced industrial states (Madison, University of Wisconsin Press). Kuokštis, V. & R. Vilpišauskas (2010) ‘Economic Adjustment to the Crisis in the Baltic States in Comparative Perspective,’ Paper presented at 7th Pan-European International Relations Conference, Stockholm, Sweden, 9-11 September. Kuokštis, V. (2012) ‘Trust and Taxes: Estonian and Lithuanian Fiscal Performance During the Crisis,’ Paper presented at American Political Science Association Annual Meeting, 30 August – 2 September. Lamoreaux, J. W. & D. Galbreath (2008) ‘The Baltic States as ‘Small States’: Negotiating the ‘East’ by Engaging the ‘West’,’ Journal of Baltic Studies, 39, 1, pp. 1-14. Mälksoo, M. (2006) ‘From Existential Politics Towards Normal Politics? The Baltic States in the Enlarged Europe,’ Security Dialogue, 37, 3, pp. 275-298. Masso, J., K. Espenberg, A. Masso, I. Mierina & K. Philips (2012) ‘Growing Inequalities and its Impacs in the Baltics,’ Country Report for the Baltic States Estonia, 29 Latvia, Lithuania, available at: research.org/system/uploads/437/original/Baltics.pdf?1370077200, http://giniaccessed 10 March 2014. Powell, E.N. & J.A. Tucker (2013), ‘Revisiting Electoral Volatility in PostCommunist Countries: New Data, New Results and New Approaches,’ British Journal of Political Science, 44, 1, pp. 123-147. Raudla, R. & R. Kattel (2011) ‘Why Did Estonia Choose Fiscal Retrenchment after the 2008 Crisis?’ Journal of Public Policy, 31, 2, pp. 163-186. Rodrik, D. (1998) ‘Why do more open economies have bigger governments?’ Journal of Political Economy, 106, 5, pp. 997-1032. Schwartz, H. (2010) ‘Small States in the Rear-view Mirror: Legitimacy in the Management of Economy and Society,’ European Political Science, 9, 4, 365-374. Thorhallsson, B. & R. Kattel (2012) ‘Neo-liberal Small States and Economic Crisis: Lessons for Democratic Corporatism,’ Journal of Baltic Studies, 44, 1, pp. 83-103. Torgler, B. (2003) ‘Tax Morale, Rule-Governed Behaviour and Trust,’ Constitutional Political Economy, 14, 2, pp. 119-140. Visser, J. (2011) The ICTWSS Database: Database on Institutional Characteristics of Trade Unions, Wage Setting, State Intervention and Social Pacts in 34 Countries Between 1960 and 2007. Version 3. Amsterdam Institute for Advanced Labour Studies (AIAS), University of Amsterdam. Available at http://www.uva-aias.net/208. 30 Table 1. Smallness and openness indicators for the three Baltic countries and the seven countries analysed in Katzenstein's SSWM Table 1. Smalness and openness indicators for the three Baltic countries and the seven countries analysed in Katzenstein’s SSWM GDP, in Exports/GDP, Population, in Volatility of billions of in percentage thousands growth, euro (2012) (2012) (2012) standard deviation of real GDP growth from 2002-2012 Estonia 17 91 1325 7.27 Latvia 22 62 2045 8.47 Lithuania 33 84 3004 6.95 Austria 307 57 8408 2.05 Belgium 376 86 11095 1.71 Denmark 245 55 5581 2.42 Netherlands 600 88 16730 2.14 Norway 389 41 4986 1.56 Sweden 408 49 9483 3.03 Switzerland 491 52 7955 1.76 Sources: Eurostat 2013; author’s calculations. 31 Table 2. Selected indicators of domestic compensation and democratic corporatism for the Baltic countries, Visegrad countries and EU average Expenditure on Non crisis state Labour market social protection, aid to industry policy expenditure, (net union in percentage of and services, in in percentage of membership as a GDP (2011) percentage of GDP (2011) proportion of wage GDP (2009-2011) Union density rate and salary earners in employment) (2009) Estonia 16.1 0.11 0.73 7.1 Latvia 15.1 0.27 0.69 14.8 Lithuania 17.0 0.37 0.56 8.5 Poland 19.2 0.73 0.72 15.1 Czech 20.4 0.64 0.56 17.4 Slovakia 18.2 0.33 0.79 17.2 Hungary 23.0 1.33 1.01 16.8 Slovenia 25.0 0.89 1.24 26.6 EU 29.1 0.48 1.95 NA Republic average Sources: Columns 1, 2 and 3: Eurostat; Column 4: Visser. 32 Table 3. Trust in political institutions in the Baltic countries. Parliament Government Political parties Regional/local Justice system authorities Estonia 49 58 21 59 76 Latvia 11 15 4 40 48 Lithuania 8 15 6 24 48 36 20 50 66 All countries in 38 Eurobarometer (average) Percentage of people who tend to trust in a given institution in 2010 (for parliament and government) and 2011 (political parties, regional/local authorities and justice system). Sources: Masso, Espenberg, Masso, Mierina, Philips 2012, p. 92, based on Eurobarometer surveys. 70.0 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 Bulgaria Lithuania Latvia Romania Slovakia Estonia Poland Ireland Malta Norway Luxembourg Czech Republic Germany Cyprus Croatia Portugal Iceland Spain United Kingdom Slovenia Hungary Netherlands Italy Austria Sweden Greece Belgium France Finland Denmark 0.0 Figure 1. EU member states and selected other countries in terms of expenditure as percentage of GDP in 2012. Source: Eurostat. 33