Baltic smallness

advertisement
Journal of Baltic Studies (forthcoming)
Baltic States in World Markets: Does Katzenstein’s Framework
Still Hold?
Vytautas Kuokštis, Institute of International Relations and Political Science, Vilnius
University
Abstract
Small states, argued Peter Katzenstein a quarter of a century ago, are different. Faced with
the fluctuations of world markets, they adopt democratic corporatism and domestic
compensation, thus ensuring political legitimacy and successful economic adjustment. The
Baltic countries are an interesting case study for this framework, because in many ways they
are ‘smaller’ than the seven countries analysed by Katzenstein. This article finds that, on a
broader level, Katzenstein’s framework is very helpful in highlighting the key developments
in the Baltic countries. On the other hand, the specific causal mechanism that can be drawn
from this framework running from smallness to democratic corporatism to political
legitimacy as well as domestic compensation has not developed in the Baltics.
Key words: Katzenstein, small states, Baltic countries, democratic corporatism, legitimacy,
domestic compensation
1
Introduction
Small States in World Markets (SSWM) by Peter Katzenstein (1985) is a
major work. At the time of writing this article, SSWM yields 3493 citations on Google
Scholar. Since its publication, SSWM has inspired many lines of research and equipped
scholars with new ways of thinking about issues in comparative and international political
economy. In particular, Katzenstein managed to draw attention to small countries which had
been neglected by previous scholars (Ingebritsen 2010). In his review of contemporary study
of political economy, Mark Blyth (2009, p. 194) names SSWM as one of the three founding
texts of the field, along with Peter Gourevitch’s Politics in Hard times (1986) and Peter
Hall’s Governing the Economy (1986).
Question is: how well does the theoretical framework of SSWM travel? Does it
still apply a quarter of a century since its inception? In his own revisit of SSWM in 2003,
Katzenstein recognized that while he had carefully delimited his investigation to seven early
industrializers of the Western ‘core’ nations (Sweden, Norway, Denmark, the Netherlands,
Belgium, Austria, Switzerland), his conclusions could be potentially fruitfully applied and
tested in other contexts: ‘analysis could have pushed further by investigating, in addition, the
strategies of other small states situated differently in the world economy’ (Katzenstein 2003,
p. 13).
Subsequent literature generally confirms Katzenstein’s insights in different
temporal and geographical settings. According to Eric Jones (2008, p. 8), ‘Katzenstein’s
thesis about small states and world markets remains relatively unchallenged’. The Baltic
countries make a compelling case for testing the arguments of Katzenstein’s framework.
Firstly they are small - indeed, they are smaller than the seven ‘dwarfs’ of SSWM. Recently,
their smallness and vulnerability was painfully exposed by a very severe economic crisis in
2008-2010. Secondly, the Baltic countries seem to pose a challenge for Katzenstein’s
2
predictions – given that they are very small and vulnerable, it is puzzling why they have not
developed democratic corporatism and strong domestic compensation mechanisms. This
article therefore sets out to answer the question: does (and in what ways) the Baltic
empirical experience fit into Katzenstein’s framework?
The implications of Katzenstein’s book are quite diverse, which speaks of the
contribution that SSWM has had to the scholarly community. At the same time, this gives
rise to some confusion, as it is possible to derive different and sometimes even contradictory
insights from Katzenstein’s work (or at least its interpretations). In this article, I provide two
interpretations. One interpretation is a ‘narrow’ one that posits a specific causal connection
that runs from smallness to corporatism and domestic compensation to legitimate and
flexible economic adjustment. The other is a more general (‘broad’) interpretation providing
guidelines for analysis and variables to look into rather than speaking about a specific causal
chain. This ‘broad’ interpretation encourages scholars to seriously take into account history,
ideas, and size; it also suggests political legitimacy as a precondition for the success of
economic policy.
The article surveys the current stock of literature on Baltic economic policy by
framing it according to Katzenstein’s approach. It reveals that in certain ways the Baltic
countries do not fit into Katzenstein’s framework (interpreted in a narrow way). While they
are even smaller and thus more vulnerable than the seven countries of SSWM, of all the new
EU member countries they have been the least inclined towards corporatism and domestic
compensation policies. Furthermore, while Lithuania and Latvia show very low levels of
political legitimacy measured by the level of trust in political institutions (which is
compatible with the predictions of Katzenstein’s framework), Estonia, which in fact pursued
the most consistent (neo)liberal policies, is characterized by relatively high levels of political
3
trust, and thus serves as a deviant case for Katzenstein’s theory formulated in a ‘narrow’
way.
Nevertheless, the article concludes that the broader interpretation of SSWM
illuminates the core themes of Baltic developments since regaining independence. This
article argues that the broader interpretation helps to shed light on the emergence, continuity,
and even on some aspects of the relative success of the Baltic politico-economic regimes (in
particular Estonia’s better performance). Based on the analysis, it is concluded that SSWM
continues to be of relevance to the study of politics and economics of small countries (and
beyond).
The first section describes Katzenstein’s original contribution and its two
interpretations. The second section discusses and measures Baltic ‘smallness’. In the third
section, the ‘narrow’ and ‘broad’ interpretations of SSWM are tested in the Baltic empirical
case.
The SSWM and its two interpretations
Katzentein wrote his book in order to solve an interesting puzzle about small
Western European countries (1985, p. 9). On the one hand, political scientists emphasized
their political stability generated by corporatism. On the other hand, economists focused on
their economic flexibility and successful performance. In SSWM, Katzenstein aimed to
resolve this conundrum by arguing that these two aspects were in fact related: ‘they are not
contradictory but mutually contingent’ (p. 9). He noted how other states could potentially
4
learn from their experience, as even ‘large industrial countries are beginning to experience
an increasing economic openness and vulnerability’ (p. 9).
Katzenstein chose to investigate the political economies of seven small
Western European countries. Although he did not explicitly state what ‘smallness’ meant, he
largely discussed such aspects as population and size of the economy. Importantly,
smallness was also related to and to some extent captured by economic openness. Overall,
Katzenstein noted that ‘small countries are more open and vulnerable than large ones,
economically, politically, and militarily’ (1985, p. 81). Smallness and openness generate
vulnerability stemming from changes in international economic conditions. Small countries
are more vulnerable to these changes because they need depend heavily on imports.
Furthermore, they tend to specialize in certain sectors and are thus less well diversified.
Finally, important parameters of economic performance, such as growth rates and inflation,
are heavily influenced by outside forces.
Overall, according to Katzenstein, all countries must find ways to respond to
global economic change. However, there are three basic responses. First, ‘liberal countries
such as the United States rely on macroeconomic policies and market solutions’ combined
with ‘limited, ad hoc protectionist policies’ (p. 23). Second, ‘statist countries such as Japan
are endowed with the means and the institutions to pre-empt the costs of change through
policies that pursue the structural transformation of their economies’ (p. 23). Small
countries, however, do not have the means to adopt either of these two approaches. Instead,
the elites in small European countries ‘live with change by compensating for it’ (p. 24).
They have ‘a preference for a reactive and flexible policy of industrial adjustment (…)
relying heavily on indirect policy instruments such as taxation rather than broad-gauged
political efforts to transform the structures of their economies’ (p. 27).
5
What is this ‘domestic compensation’? It includes measures such as welfare
spending to compensate the losers from economic changes and reduce the uncertainty
stemming from market fluctuations. According to Katzenstein, ‘these policies are carried by
the conviction that it is important to counter some of the harmful effects of international
liberalization’ (1985, p. 47). This is what explains a faster growth of public economy in
smaller states than in large ones in Europe (Katzenstein 1985, p. 54). Besides, these small
countries ‘have tried to restrain their wages and, occasionally, prices through a governmentcoordinated incomes policy (as in the Netherlands and Denmark), or through a centralized
system of collective bargaining (as in Sweden and Norway), or though some combination of
the two (as in Austria)’ (Katzenstein 1985, p. 56). Wage restraint is used to ensure
competitiveness and adjust to balance of payments problems.
In turn, the policies of domestic compensation allow for securing political
legitimacy: ‘through their policies, political leaders in the small European states have
maintained the legitimacy of the political arrangements governing their societies (…)
Political leaders retain a tight hold on mass participation, and electoral changes have been
very small’ (Katzenstein 1985, p. 28). In his follow-up article writing about the small
Western European industrialized countries, Katzenstein (2003, p. 19) notes that ‘since for
decades their policies offered generous social protection against international dislocations,
confidence levels are high and stable’. Katzenstein (1985, p. 28) acknowledges that
legitimacy is a ‘broad construct’ and difficult to measure. When writing about legitimacy, he
refers to such aspects as trust in politicians and political institutions, high levels of
participation, small electoral changes and lack of protests (Katzenstein 1985, p. 28).
Both domestic compensation policies and political legitimacy are created via
the institutions of ‘democratic corporatism’. Katzenstein distinguishes the ‘democratic
corporatism’ characteristic of small industrialized Western European states from
6
authoritarian corporatism (e.g. in fascist Italy) or ‘state capitalism’ (e.g. in Japan).
Democratic corporatism has the following characteristics (Katzenstein, 1985, p. 32): ‘an
ideology of social partnership expressed at the national level; a relatively centralized and
concentrated system of interest groups; and voluntary and informal coordination of
conflicting objectives through continuous political bargaining between interest groups, state
bureaucracies, and political parties’. Corporatist institutions ensure greater political stability
and consensual, rather than confrontational, policies. Eric Jones (2008, p. 9) stated this in the
following way: ‘small states are more consensual because they are more vulnerable to world
market forces (and because they are aware of that vulnerability)’.
All of these preconditions also ensure a successful adjustment to changing
economic conditions. Political legitimacy and consensual politics reduce tension within
society and form a basis for the search for flexible solutions and policy learning.
Furthermore, coordinated wage bargaining helps to avoid deteriorating competitiveness and
associated macroeconomic problems.
Narrow interpretation
One possible way of reading SSWM is extracting a specific causal chain
running from smallness to vulnerability to corporatism and domestic compensation to
political legitimacy and finally to successful economic performance. Smallness
(vulnerability) increases the chances for (or leads to, if stated deterministically) democratic
corporatism and domestic compensation policies. Domestic compensation refers to the size
of the public sector, and especially welfare spending. In Hardiman’s words, ‘the
“compensation hypothesis” holds that increasing trade exposure gives rise to pressures for
an expansion in public spending, especially on welfare items’ (Hardiman, Murphy & Burke
2008, p. 599). Of course, Katzenstein has not been the only author to lay out this argument.
7
Other authors provided theoretical and empirical support for the assertion that increased
economic openness leads to public sector growth (e.g. Rodrik 1998).
It is interesting that in his follow-up article, Katzenstein (2003, p. 22) makes a
specific prediction about the future development of Eastern European capitalist systems,
including those in the Baltic countries. After noticing what he saw as corporatist trends, he
outlines his expectations:
The emerging social market economies are unlikely to resemble statist or neoliberal
variants of capitalism. It is more likely that they will have greater resemblance with the
institutions of the German variant of capitalism, among the large industrial states the
closest cousin of the democratic corporatism of the small European states.
Focusing on the second part of the causal argument, democratic corporatism and domestic
compensation create condition for political legitimacy. This, in turn, helps to secure
successful economic performance. The prediction is that countries (at least small ones)
which have democratic corporatist institutions as well as strong domestic compensation will
be more successful economically and, even more importantly, politically, and as a result
more trust in political institutions. One should note here that this assertion also implies a
counterfactual: in the absence of democratic corporatist arrangements and domestic
compensation policies, wide economic fluctuations would preclude the build-up of political
legitimacy and trust or erode its existing stock. Overall, the expectation is that small open
countries lacking legitimacy due to lack of democratic corporatism and domestic
compensation will be less economically and politically successful.
8
Broad interpretation
However there is another way of interpreting SSWM. In contrast to the
‘narrow’ version, the ‘broader’ interpretation refers not to specific causal connections
outlined above, but rather to a more general way of approaching the study of political
economy in particular and politics in general. What I mean by ‘broad’ interpretation in this
article is the position to take into account size (smallness) as a variable, analyse ideas and
history, as well as recognize the importance of political legitimacy in affecting economic
performance. Note that only the first item focuses on differentiating small states from larger
ones. History, ideas and political legitimacy are important regardless of state size.
To begin with, one of the main lessons of SSWM is that size is important and
should be treated as a variable rather than a constant. In ‘Small States and Small States
Revisited’, Katzenstein (2003) briefly explains his motivation for writing SSWM. SSWM
was a follow-up on an earlier research project – Between Power and Plenty (Katzenstein
1977) – and an attempt to address some of the latter’s drawbacks. One of the chief ones was
inattention to size as an explanatory variable. Smallness and vulnerability – Katzenstein
maintains – have important and far-reaching consequences for the development and
functioning of small countries’ politico-economic regimes. Of course, the ‘narrow’
interpretation also focuses on the effects of smallness, but it formulates a specific prediction
on its role. By contrast, the ‘broad’ version simply states that size is significant, but the way
it affects any country’s political economy and politics is contingent.
The second implication of SSWM is the significance of history. Specifically,
‘in the small European states (…) a tradition of accomodative politics dating back beyond
the nineteenth century facilitated the political reorientation that took place in the 1930s and
1940s’ (Katzenstein 1985, p. 35). In SSWM, Katzenstein claims that history is important,
which means that there are powerful continuities to a given country’s economic and political
9
strategies as well as the related policy choices. He explains the emergence of and differences
in democratic corporatism historically. In other words, choices are not simply made in an
abstract vacuum, but rather are conditioned by historical context.
In
explaining
the
emergence and continuities of the corporatist systems in small Western nations, Katzenstein
turns to their experience of vulnerability in the first half of the twentieth century. One of the
conditions for the formation of democratic corporatism, Katzenstein argues, was weak
political right. Notice that this argument is in some contradiction with the first causal link of
the ‘narrow’ interpretation, because vulnerability alone is no longer enough to produce
corporatism – rather, democratic corporatism is a product of two necessary but insufficient
conditions: (perception of) vulnerability and weak political right. In fact, adopting a
historically informed perspective it’s possible to argue that this corrected version of the
causal chain is still flawed in the sense that while vulnerability and weak right produced
corporatism in the specific temporal and spatial context (industrialized small western
countries), it might not occur in other contexts. In other words, causal processes are contextspecific and should be treated as such. Third, SSWM highlighted the significance of ideas.
In his revisit of SSWM, Katzenstein (2003, p. 11) writes this:
What really mattered politically was the perception of vulnerability, economic and
otherwise. Perceived vulnerability generated an ideology of social partnership that had
acted like a glue for the corporatist politics of the small European states. This was the first
and most important explanatory variable in Small States.
Katzenstein continues noting that this point was largely missed in the reception
and reviews that followed SSWM’s publication. He argues that the field of political
economy was not yet ready to include ideas as an important and researchable variable into
the analysis of political and economic reality. Consequently, Mark Blyth (1997, p. 201) sees
the seeds of constructivist political economy in Katzenstein’s work:
10
This is why Small States is more than a synthesis of coalitional and institutional approaches.
It also opened the door to moving beyond them, to put ideas and social constructions front
and center in political economy explanations rather than treat them as a residual category
to mop up variance unexplained by these other approaches.
Finally, Katzenstein’s work attests to the importance of political legitimacy. As
Herman Schwartz (2010, p. 365) points out, it is exactly the issue of political legitimacy, and
not economic efficiency, that is at the core of SSWM: ‘Small States in World Markets is
about political efficacy and legitimation rather than scoring who is ahead in the economic
sweepstakes. Its case for democratic corporatism rests on norms, particularly stability, rather
than on narrow measures of economic efficiency’. In Katzenstein’s words, ‘economic
performance, then, is not a yardstick by which we can directly measure the successes and
failures of the small European states’ (Katzenstein 1985, p. 28). Still, even if economic
performance was not the key issue in SSWM, one can draw the implication that political
legitimacy does matter for economic performance.
Political legitimacy here refers to the same concept as described above under
the ‘narrow’ interpretation. Furthermore, it does not contradict the causal chain posited
above about the positive influence of political legitimacy on economic performance.
However, the ‘broader’ version, in contrast to the ‘narrow’ interpretation, does not hold that
democratic corporatism and domestic compensation are necessary conditions for political
legitimacy. Furthermore, the ‘dividends’ of high legitimacy potentially encompass other
dimensions of economic performance not covered in SSWM. For instance, scholars argue
that trust in political institutions might be important in encouraging tax morale and therefore
fiscal performance (Torgler 2003).
11
Baltic smallness
Before turning to the analysis and initial comparison of Baltic ‘smallness’ to
the ‘size’ of original countries analysed in SSWM, it is relevant to ask whether one is not
comparing apples and oranges in this case as the background conditions of the two countries
are very different. First of all, the primary goal of the article is not the comparison of these
two groups. Even so, while in some regards these two groups of countries greatly diverge,
one must also remember that neither the ‘narrow’ nor the ‘broad’ versions of the framework
speak against such a comparison or the extension of the framework to new cases. The
‘narrow’ version as formulated in the theoretical part does not limit itself to any particular
geographical or historical setting and in fact predicts a universal (although possibly
probabilistic rather than deterministic) relationship between smallness on the one hand and
domestic compensation, democratic corporatism and legitimacy on the other. In contrast, the
‘broad’ version is sensitive to a particular historical, social and ideational setting, but again
the way it is formulated (sensitivity to size, ideas, history and legitimacy) does not preclude
applying the approach elsewhere. Finally, as already mentioned, Katzenstein admitted the
desirability of applying the framework to new settings and even made predictions about the
emerging political economies in Eastern Europe.
Turning to the analytic part, in economic terms the Baltic countries are
‘smaller’ than the seven countries of SSWM, and thus make interesting cases for studying
how SSWM’s framework fits their experience. Table 1 below reveals that the Baltic
countries are generally indeed ‘smaller’ (more vulnerable) than the original ‘dwarfs’. This is
true both in terms of absolute GDP figures and population size. Furthermore, volatility of
economic conditions in the Baltic countries – as illustrated by standard deviation of annual
GDP growth – is way higher than the one experienced by the 7 ‘SSWM countries’. Behind
this statistic lies the story of a recent roller-coaster ride of the Baltic countries – after posting
12
impressive growth numbers in the run-up to the crisis, all three Baltic States recorded double
digit contractions in 2009. A similar, although less dramatic, story occurred a decade ago
when the Baltic countries were hit by the Russian crisis in 1998-1999. As Aldis Austers
(2014, p. 9) puts it, ‘the crisis of 2008-2010 can be seen as just another episode in a drama
related to Latvian experience in a capitalistic world’. Only in terms of trade openness do the
‘7 dwarfs’ match the Baltic ‘smallness’.
Table 1 here
Smallness and vulnerability are not confined to the economic realm, but can
also be generated by political conditions. Baltic countries historically have been exposed to
larger threats with real possibilities of national extinction than the ‘7 dwarfs’. Due to their
unfavourable geopolitical location, they often found themselves at the crossroads of great
power politics. During the twentieth century alone they gained independence from Tsarist
Russia, only to be occupied by the Soviet Union and then by Nazi Germany and once again
by the Soviet Union. Finally independence was restored after fifty years of Communist rule
that involved not only the loss of independence but also massive deportations and a
complete changeover of the socio-economic system. As was put by Lamoreaux and
Galbreath (p. 1), ‘in 1940 and 1944, smallness meant forced incorporation into the Soviet
Union’. Problems with Russia continue till the present days. Even the entrance into the EU
(European Union) and NATO (North Atlantic Treaty Organisation) did not calm these
tensions: ‘five years after the double enlargement, the permafrost in Baltic-Russian relations
shows no signs of melting, but instead seems to thrive in the increasingly chilly climate of
the Russo-Western relationship’ (Berg & Ehin 2009, p. 1). Furthermore, in Lithuania’s case
13
one can observe re-emergence of problems with Poland that have been muted over much of
the recent independence period. In Estonia and Latvia, the sense of vulnerability is fostered
because of big ethnic Russian minorities. Recent Russian actions in Ukraine involving
annexation of Crimea on the grounds of protecting local Russians have added to the Baltic
sense of vulnerability. In response to these events, all three Baltic countries requested
stronger signs of commitment and security guarantees from their NATO partners.
In the words of Maria Mälksoo (2006, p. 277), ‘The quest of the Baltic states
for membership in the EU and NATO has been the politics of survival par excellence, aimed
at securing Western security guarantees against historically aggressive and unstable
neighbouring Russia’. Mälksoo (2006, p. 277) concludes that ‘despite certain relief in their
immediate security concerns after the dual enlargement, the shift by the Baltic states from
existential politics to normal politics is far from being accomplished’.
Narrow interpretation and Baltic experience
1. Smallness  democratic corporatism and domestic compensation
I will start with the narrower interpretation. Turning to the first link in the causal chain,
things immediately get complicated for the theory. Given that the Baltic countries are small
and very open, based on the ‘narrow’ version one would have expected them, first, to
develop democratic corporatism and, second, to have strong policies of domestic
compensation. Neither of these happened.
First, the Baltic countries are actually some of the least corporatist in the EU. According
to Thorhallsson and Kattel (2012, p. 2), Estonia is ‘an ideal test case of the advantages and
disadvantages of small European states that have not followed the corporatist trend’. Trade
unions in the Baltic countries are weak, with little capacity to influence public policy. Baltic
14
trade unions have one of the lowest density rates in the EU and among the new member
states (see Table 2). Furthermore, density rates have been declining fast. From 2003 to 2008
total trade union membership declined by 16 percent in Latvia, 18 percent in Estonia and 34
percent in Lithuania (Carley 2009). The Baltic countries were among the six EU members
were these figures fell most significantly in that period. Employers in the Baltics are not
organized either (Norkus 2008, p. 632). There are no formal or informal nation-wide wage
bargaining processes in the Baltic countries. According to Bohle and Greskovits (2007, p.
447), Baltic countries are characterized by ‘low union density, decentralized, uncoordinated
wage bargaining and low coverage rates of collective agreements’. Several scholars
(Feldmann 2006; Norkus 2008) have compared two small new EU member states, Estonia
and Slovenia, and concluded that they approximate two opposite models of capitalist
systems that emerged after transition. In contrast to Estonia (one could also argue Lithuania
and Latvia), Slovenia is an example of ‘democratic corporatism’ with institutionalized
practices of interest (both employers’ and employees’) representation. Slovenia most closely
approximates the small country model analysed in the SSWM.
Interestingly, during the last crisis of 2008-2010 the weak rudiments of democratic
corporatism were neglected even further (Gonser 2010) and thus the existing institutional
structure reinforced. Economic adjustment packages – which were based on very high levels
of fiscal consolidation involving a mixture of spending cuts and tax increases – were crafted
very quickly, after little consultation with social groups. According to Kallaste and
Woolfson (2013, p. 253), in the Baltics ‘a negotiated response was either not sought at all by
governments or was of minor importance at all levels of interaction between the social
partners. If anything, national-level social dialogue deteriorated, remaining at a low level
even after the crisis had peaked’.
15
As for domestic compensation, the Baltic countries have one of the smallest public
sectors in the EU (see Figure 1). Table 2 provides several more specific indicators of the
extent of domestic compensation, such as welfare state (social) expenditure, state support for
businesses as well as labour market policy expenditure. Baltic countries emerge generally as
less compensating than other new member states and substantially less than the EU average.
As Bohle and Greskovits (2007) describe, the Baltic countries feature a low level of
‘protection’ for society and domestic businesses from fluctuations in economic conditions.
Figure 1 here
In other words, contrary to the narrow interpretation of SSWM (and Katzenstein’s
predictions in 2003), smallness and vulnerability in the Baltic countries, reinforced by severe
economic crises, did not lead to democratic corporatism and substantial domestic
compensation.
Table 2 here.
2. Lack of democratic corporatism and domestic compensation  low political
legitimacy
Next, given that the Baltic countries opted for non-corporatist regimes, one should
follow the counterfactual derived in the theoretical section: one should see lower and/or
eroding levels of trust in political institutions that are measures for the broader concept of
16
political legitimacy. Does empirical evidence support this prediction? Latvia’s and
Lithuania’s situation is indeed compatible with this interpretation: political trust (i.e. trust in
political institutions) in these countries is very low (see Table 3 below). The absence of
domestic compensation policies can at least be advanced as a strong candidate explanation
for these facts, although the usual caveat about correlation versus causation holds. One fact
undermining this explanation is that during the ‘fat years’ before the crisis with very rapid
wage and public expenditure growth did not bring higher levels of trust. In 2007, only 24
percent of Lithuanians and 19 percent of Latvians and as many as 62 percent of Estonians
said they tended to trust their national parliament (European Commission 2008, p. 56).
Table 3 here
Nevertheless, Estonia’s situation is incompatible with the second link of the
‘narrow’ interpretation of Katzenstein’s theory (see Table 2). Estonia has actually pursued
even more (neo)liberal policies (for instance, it liberalized trade policies most radically and
the earliest of the three Baltic nations, and was the first to adopt a very strict monetary
arrangement, the Currency board), but it has also managed to build up a solid trust base.
Furthermore, electoral volatility in Estonia has been lower than in Latvia and Lithuania
(Powell & Tucker 2013, p. 9). The latest elections in 2011 after the economic crisis
confirmed this trend – in fact, the incumbent Reform Party increased its number of seats
even after implementing austerity measures during a very painful economic crisis.
Writing on the continuing political legitimacy of small Western corporatist
countries, Katzenstein in 2003 (p. 19) noted that ‘an indirect reflection of the learning
capacity and performance of the small European states is the relatively constant and high
17
levels of confidence in political institutions that their citizens express, in sharp contrast to
declining and relatively low levels in the large industrial states’. By that measure, Estonia
has held up well. According to Standard Eurobarometer, in the spring of 2010, just after a
double-digit contraction of GDP in 2009 and a spike in unemployment, Estonians were
among the most optimistic in the EU regarding the direction of their country. The percentage
of people who supported the ‘direction where the country was going’ was 47 percent, only
surpassed by Sweden (61 percent) (European Commission 2010, p. 111). In other words,
Estonia is a deviant case for the ‘narrow’ interpretation of Katzenstein’s theory: high level of
legitimacy exists despite the posited necessary condition – corporatist arrangements and
strong domestic compensation (see section ‘Discussion and conclusions’ below for a
possible explanation of why this might be the case).
3. Lack of corporatism and domestic compensation  low political legitimacy 
lower success in economic adjustment
The final causal link relates to political legitimacy's influence on the success of
economic adjustment. Regarding this last link, no easy verdict can be passed on SSWM
framework in the Baltic case. First, SSWM spoke about political legitimacy produced by
corporatist arrangements and domestic compensation. Since Estonian legitimacy has been
caused by other factors, one could argue that the analysis of legitimacy’s influence on
economic performance is invalid with reference to SSWM framework. Second, SSWM
spoke about legitimacy giving rise to the necessary flexibility in adjustment related to
industrial policy. What the Baltic countries did during the last crisis (and before) was not
engage in increased domestic compensation or flexible industrial adaptation but to opt for
orthodox macro-management with the aim to ensure macroeconomic and financial stability.
18
In other words, they sought to solve the crisis in the same familiar way, with little flexibility
or rethinking of their approach (although with a very high level of flexibility in terms of
labour market adjustment (i.e. fall in wages), which is a completely different matter).
Whether this continuity is a good thing from a normative perspective is an open question At
least in terms of response to the last economic crisis, the answer depends on whether the
results were ‘successful’. On the one hand, the Baltic countries managed to preserve the
fixed exchange rate and return to fiscal sustainability. At the same time, they suffered very
big economic contractions, saw increased emigration and there are indicators in Latvia and
Lithuania to suggest that populations were largely dissatisfied with the approach to the crisis
(Kuokštis and Vilpišauskas 2010).
Despite very similar background conditions, including external economic and political
challenges (vulnerability), the fact that Baltic countries score so differently on political trust
makes them an interesting case to see whether Estonia’s higher score helped the country in
terms of their specific chosen adjustment. Still, such an interpretation goes significantly
beyond the ‘narrow’ causal chain posited above and will be covered in the following section
under ‘broad’ interpretation.
Broad interpretation and Baltic experience
To clarify, the four broad implications of Katzenstein’s framework emphasize
four different aspects. Three of them (the importance of history, ideas, and size) point to a
broad ‘politico-economic regime’ or economic policy package. By themselves, they are
normatively neutral (history can affect economic policies in all sorts of ways, as can ideas or
perception of vulnerability). In contrast, the fourth implication – political legitimacy’s
influence on economic results – has clear normative connotations: the hypothesis is that high
19
level of political legitimacy helps to adjust successfully in economic terms (although not
necessarily using corporatist institutions and domestic compensation).
The Baltic experience since transition demonstrates the limits of purely
materialist/rationalist accounts Dorothee Bohle and Bela Greskovits (2007) as well as Rawi
Abdelal (2001) on different grounds have argued convincingly for the importance of
ideational dimension in accounting for the formation of Baltic capitalist systems in the
1990s. Abdelal contrasts the experience of Lithuania, Belarus and Ukraine after the collapse
of the Soviet Union and concludes that identity was the crucial explanatory factor for
radically different foreign economic policy orientations chosen by the three countries (Westoriented, East-oriented, and ambiguous respectively). Bohle and Greskovits aim to describe
and explain the types of capitalism that emerged in the new EU member states. In their
words, ‘the decisions concerning the new regimes have been motivated both by the legacies
of the past and their perception as either threats or assets from the viewpoint of national
sovereignty and economic independence’ (Bohle & Greskovits 2007, p. 444). Their
argument is bolstered by the fact that objective structural conditions cannot account for the
divergence in development of the Baltic countries on the one hand and the Visegrad group
as well as Slovenia on the other. For instance, industrial structure measured in terms of
product sophistication in the early 1990s was similar, and only diverged later (Bohle &
Greskovits 2007, p. 459). Ideas could also explain why trade unions played and continue to
play such a small role in the Baltics. As Gonser put it, trade unions in the Baltics are
‘associated with the past and, therefore, objected in many cases’ (Gonser 2010, p. 2). In
general, leftist economic and social policy ideas in the Baltics suffered greatly during the
transition, in contrast to, for instance, Slovenia. According to Norkus, ex-communists in the
Baltics essentially implemented neoliberal economic policies (2008, p. 623). The Baltic
experience is very much compatible with Katzenstein’s assertion that ‘in the rationalist
20
world of political economy actor identities are assumed to be fixed and unproblematic, an
intellectually untenable position in the case of the small European states, and perhaps more
generally’ (Katzenstein 2003, p. 11).
Moreover, the choices made during the transition
period, as has already been mentioned, were closely related to the (perception of)
vulnerability stemming from ‘smallness’, just as would be indicated by the ‘broad’ version
of Katzenstein’s framework. It was the perception of this threat that moved the Baltic
countries to pursue very liberal economic policy. As Bohle and Greskovits write, ‘these
countries could neither take their nation nor their state institutions for granted, and inherited
the least favourable legacies in terms of economic institutions from state socialism’ (Bohle
& Greskovits 2007, p. 444). Elsewhere Greskovits writing about Estonia notes that ‘stability
culture and trust in its guardians, the currency board, a balanced budget, and central bankers,
could become a cornerstone of national identity, especially as measures to foster national
independence and transformation have been introduced as part and parcel of the same policy
package’ (Greskovits 2009, p. 211). This sense of geopolitical threat could also be one of the
explanations why the Baltic countries are among the ones most eager to join the Eurozone
(Estonia did this in 2011, Latvia in 2014 and Lithuania is expected to join from 2015).
Interestingly, Latvia started showing more determination to join the Eurozone after the Great
Recession than Lithuania, although there were no significant changes in structural-economic
conditions. A plausible candidate to explain this difference is the fact that Latvia went
through a bigger crisis than Lithuania. Latvia was the only country that experienced a
collapse of a major domestic bank during the crisis and was forced to turn to international
financial assistance. In turn, this could have produced a higher sense of ‘smallness’ and
‘vulnerability’.
In the theoretical part, it was also argued that Katzenstein’s framework
interpreted broadly can be seen to argue for the importance of ‘history’. History means that
21
policy choices are prone to inertia – i.e. the more some course of action and policies had
been applied in the past, the likelier it is that they will be continued. The experience of the
Baltic countries indeed reflects this. A good example can be the very high level of support
for fixed exchange rates specifically and currency board systems more generally. Kuokštis
and Vilpišauskas (2010) analyse how the decision to preserve the fixed exchange rates rather
than seek currency devaluation during the last crisis did not stem from international pressure
or simple material interests. Instead, fixed exchange rate systems which had been created in
early 1990s became stronger over time, as they anchored macroeconomic stability and also
increased the number of interest groups incentivized to support them. Furthermore, writing
about fiscal policy choices during the crisis, Raudla and Kattel (2011, p. 163) argue that
these ‘became path-dependent as a result of positive feedback loops from previous periods
of fiscal consolidation’. Interestingly, most outside observers predicted the collapse of fixed
exchange rate regimes in the Baltic countries, but this did not happen (Kuokštis and
Vilpišauskas 2010). Sensitivity to the specific historical context of the Baltic countries as
suggested by the ‘broad’ interpretation of SSWM would likely have precluded such acontextual, excessively bold predictions. Furthermore, it is exactly this sensitivity to context
and history that allows us to answer why smallness failed to foster democratic corporatism
and extensive domestic compensation in the Baltics, as would have been predicted by the
‘narrow’ interpretation. While smallness found its way into democratic corporatist
arrangements in the states analysed in SSWM, under specific Baltic conditions existing in
the early transition a high degree of vulnerability was channelled into a different set of
institutions. As Katzenstein (1985, p. 136) put it, ‘small size is thus not treated as master
variable that somehow forces a particular political solution – the relationship between small
size and democratic corporatism is historically contingent rather than logically necessary’.
Finally, one should deal with the importance of political legitimacy, and
22
specifically its effect on economic performance. As has been mentioned, during the last
crisis for the Baltic countries the major challenges arose and most important actions were
taken in the domain of fiscal policy. While all three Baltic countries chose to pursue very
similar adjustment policies in the form of macroeconomic austerity, Estonia’s attempts were
clearly more successful. The northern-most of the three Baltic countries had prepared better
for the crisis by accumulating fiscal reserves, reacted faster when the crisis started, and was
also able to reduce budget deficit much more successfully, enabling it to join the Eurozone
from 2011. Compared to 2008, in 2009 public deficit as percentage of GDP expanded by 5.6
percentage points in Latvia, 6.1 percentage points in Lithuania and it actually decreased by
0.9 percentage points in Estonia, although all three countries were experiencing double-digit
contractions in real economic activity (author’s calculations based on Eurostat data).
Economic-structural conditions cannot account for this difference, as broad
economic developments as well as tax and spending policies were very similar in the Baltic
countries (Kuokštis 2012). One convincing explanation is that these factors – crisisreadiness, faster reaction and more successful results of tax policies – can be explained by a
gap in political trust among the three Baltic countries mentioned earlier. Correlation is not
causation, of course, but given the large empirically grounded literature on the relationship
between trust and tax compliance and very similar economic trends, there seems to be a
strong case for linking Estonia’s better performance to its larger stock of political trust
(Kuokštis 2012). So while the specific causal link was different from the one posited under
the ‘narrow’ interpretation, the Baltic experience demonstrates the role of political
legitimacy in ensuring the success of economic policies.
23
Discussion and conclusions
How does Katzenstein’s theory hold when faced with the empirical case of the
Baltic countries? The answer to this question depends on which interpretation (narrow or
broad) of the SSWM is applied. In terms of the narrow interpretation, the empirical Baltic
case, especially Estonia, presents serious challenges to the framework. At the same time, the
broad version is useful in highlighting the main developments in the Baltics since regaining
independence.
Regarding the ‘narrow’ interpretation, the Baltic countries do present
important problems for Katzenstein’s framework. First, vulnerability stemming from high
degree of economic openness as well as a special geopolitical situation did not lead to high
level of domestic compensation and corporatist practices. Quite to the contrary – the Baltic
countries are some of the least corporatist and ‘compensating’ countries among the EU
member states. It has to be noted that Bohle and Greskovits provide an interpretation which
is more compatible with Katzenstein’s account – namely that loans from Western banks
served as compensation mechanisms substituting for real welfare policies (Bohle &
Greskovits 2009). Even so, this interpretation only refers to the compensation side and
leaves out corporatism, and in this regard still fails to corroborate the causal chain of
SSWM. Second, it is doubtful whether credit booms were a result of a conscious effort by
politicians to provide compensation policies, rather than an outcome of the specific
construction of Baltic macroeconomic regimes (in other words, credit booms in the Baltics
seems to have been due to an error of omission rather than commission).
Still, Latvian and Lithuanian empirical record is compatible with the second
link in the SSWM causal chain – given the absence of corporatist and significant welfare
policies, the observation of very low levels of trust within Latvian and Lithuanian societies
is in line with the ‘narrow’ version of Katzenstein’s framework. The caveat here is that a
24
comprehensive test of causal rather than correlational association of these two variables has
been outside the scope of the article.
The Estonian case is a different story, though. Its relatively high level of
political legitimacy and anti-corporatist policies is a significant challenge toward
Katzenstein’s framework when interpreted in a narrow sense. What can explain this? To the
best of my knowledge, no attempt has been made in the literature to tackle this puzzle.
Examination of this question is beyond the confines of this article, but it is possible to
formulate a suggestion for future research. The hypothesis is that Estonians trust their
government more despite the fact that their government's performance is well below that of,
say, Scandinavian countries, but because it is relatively better than that in its ‘reference’
group – which can in turn be hypothesized to be the two other Baltic countries, Latvia and
Lithuania. These two serve as natural reference points for Estonians, because all three Baltic
countries started at almost identical positions in early 1990s in terms of economic
development and political situation, yet Estonia emerged fairly quickly as the leader of the
pack, and its governments have been able to exploit this relative lead vis-à-vis the other
Baltic States both in terms of relative indicators of performance (e.g. GDP growth or
corruption indices) as well as specific landmarks of achievement (e.g. being invited to
negotiate with the European Union first and more recently – the first of the three to enter the
Eurozone).
The broader interpretation of SSWM does reveal crucial elements of recent
Baltic economic and political history. Size matters, and so does history, ideas, and political
legitimacy. However, ‘smallness’ effects are context-dependent – while smallness and
vulnerability matter, the specific way that they matter can be very different. This is where
‘history’ and ‘ideas’ enter the scene – the specific Baltic situation at the beginning of
transition meant that the perception of vulnerability was channelled to (neo)liberal policies
25
reflecting the desire to abandon the previous socio-economic system, consolidate nationhood
and integrate into the Western political and economic structures.
26
References
Austers, A. (2014) ‘Latvia’s Controversial “Success Story”,’ in Bukovskis, K.
(ed) (2014) The Politics of Economic Sustainability: Baltic and Visegrad Responses to the
European Economic Crisis (Riga, Latvian Institute of International Affairs).
Abdelal, R. (2001) National Purpose in the World Economy: Post-Soviet States
in Comparative Perspective (Ithaca, Cornell University Press).
Berg, E., & P. Ehin. (eds) (2009) Identity and foreign policy: Baltic-Russian
relations and European integration (Burlington: Ashgate Publishing).
Blyth, M. (2009) ‘An Approach to Comparative Analysis or a Subfield within a
Subfield? Political Economy,’ in Lichbach, M. I. & Zuckerman, A. S. (eds) (2009)
Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure (Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press), pp. 193-219.
Bohle, D. & B. Greskovits (2007) ‘Neoliberalism, embedded neoliberalism and
neocorporatism: Towards transnational capitalism in Central-Eastern Europe,’ West
European Politics 30, 3, pp. 443–466.
Bohle, D. & B. Greskovits (2009) ‘East-Central Europe’s Quandary,’ Journal
of Democracy, 20, 4, pp. 50-63.
Carley, M. (2009) ‘Trade union membership 2003-2008,’ European industrial
relations
observatory
online,
available
http://www.eurofound.europa.eu/eiro/studies/tn0904019s/tn0904019s.htm,
at:
accessed
10
March 2014.
European Commission, Eurobarometer 68, May 2008, available at:
http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/eb/eb68/eb_68_en.pdf, accessed 12 March 2014.
27
European Commission, Eurobarometer 73, November 2010, available at:
http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/eb/eb73/eb73_vol1_en.pdf, accessed 20 October
2012.
Feldmann, M. (2006) ‘Emerging Varieties of Capitalism in Transition
Countries. Industrial Relations and Wage Bargaining in Estonia and Slovenia,’ Comparative
Political Studies, 39, 7, pp. 829-864.
Gonser, M. (2010) ‘How Hard a Blow for the Collective Representation of
Labour Interests? - The Baltic Industrial Relations and the Financial Crisis,’ Emecon, 1,
available at: http://www.emecon.eu/current-issue/gonser/.
Gourevitch, P. (1986) Politics in Hard times: Comparative Responses to
International Economic Crises (Ithaca, Cornell University Press).
Greskovits, B. (2009) ‘Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity,’
in Dyson, K. H. F. & Marcussen, M. (eds) (2009) Central Banks in the Age of the Euro:
Europeanization, Convergence, and Power (Oxford, Oxford University Press).
Hall, P. (1986) Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in
Britain and France (Oxford, Oxford University Press).
Hardiman, N., P. Murphy & O. Burke (2008) ‘The Politics of Economic
Adjustment in a Liberal Market Economy: The Social Compensation Hypothesis Revisited,’
Irish Political Studies, 23, 4, pp. 599-626.
Ingebritsen, C. (2010) ‘Katzenstein’s Legacy 25 Years After: Small States in
World Markets,’ European Political Science, 9, 3, pp. 359–364.
28
Jones, E. (2008) Economic adjustment and political transformation in small
states (Oxford, Oxford University Press).
Kallaste, E. & C. Woolfson (2013) ‘Negotiated Responses to the Crisis in the
Baltic countries,’ Transfer: European Review of Labour and Research, 19, 2, pp. 253-266.
Katzenstein, P. J. (2003) ‘Small States and Small States Revisited,’ New
Political Economy, 8, 1, pp. 9–30.
Katzenstein, P. J. (1985) Small states in world markets: industrial policy in
Europe (Ithaca: Cornell University Press).
Katzenstein, P. J. (ed.) (1977) Between power and plenty: Foreign economic
policies of advanced industrial states (Madison, University of Wisconsin Press).
Kuokštis, V. & R. Vilpišauskas (2010) ‘Economic Adjustment to the Crisis in
the Baltic States in Comparative Perspective,’ Paper presented at 7th Pan-European
International Relations Conference, Stockholm, Sweden, 9-11 September.
Kuokštis, V. (2012) ‘Trust and Taxes: Estonian and Lithuanian Fiscal
Performance During the Crisis,’ Paper presented at American Political Science Association
Annual Meeting, 30 August – 2 September.
Lamoreaux, J. W. & D. Galbreath (2008) ‘The Baltic States as ‘Small States’:
Negotiating the ‘East’ by Engaging the ‘West’,’ Journal of Baltic Studies, 39, 1, pp. 1-14.
Mälksoo, M. (2006) ‘From Existential Politics Towards Normal Politics? The
Baltic States in the Enlarged Europe,’ Security Dialogue, 37, 3, pp. 275-298.
Masso, J., K. Espenberg, A. Masso, I. Mierina & K. Philips (2012) ‘Growing
Inequalities and its Impacs in the Baltics,’ Country Report for the Baltic States Estonia,
29
Latvia,
Lithuania,
available
at:
research.org/system/uploads/437/original/Baltics.pdf?1370077200,
http://giniaccessed
10
March
2014.
Powell, E.N. & J.A. Tucker (2013), ‘Revisiting Electoral Volatility in PostCommunist Countries: New Data, New Results and New Approaches,’ British Journal of
Political Science, 44, 1, pp. 123-147.
Raudla, R. & R. Kattel (2011) ‘Why Did Estonia Choose Fiscal Retrenchment
after the 2008 Crisis?’ Journal of Public Policy, 31, 2, pp. 163-186.
Rodrik, D. (1998) ‘Why do more open economies have bigger governments?’
Journal of Political Economy, 106, 5, pp. 997-1032.
Schwartz, H. (2010) ‘Small States in the Rear-view Mirror: Legitimacy in the
Management of Economy and Society,’ European Political Science, 9, 4, 365-374.
Thorhallsson, B. & R. Kattel (2012) ‘Neo-liberal Small States and Economic
Crisis: Lessons for Democratic Corporatism,’ Journal of Baltic Studies, 44, 1, pp. 83-103.
Torgler, B. (2003) ‘Tax Morale, Rule-Governed Behaviour and Trust,’
Constitutional Political Economy, 14, 2, pp. 119-140.
Visser, J. (2011) The ICTWSS Database: Database on Institutional
Characteristics of Trade Unions, Wage Setting, State Intervention and Social Pacts in 34
Countries Between 1960 and 2007. Version 3. Amsterdam Institute for Advanced Labour
Studies (AIAS), University of Amsterdam. Available at http://www.uva-aias.net/208.
30
Table 1. Smallness and openness indicators for the three Baltic countries and the seven
countries analysed in Katzenstein's SSWM
Table 1. Smalness and openness indicators for the three Baltic countries and the seven countries
analysed in Katzenstein’s SSWM
GDP, in
Exports/GDP,
Population, in
Volatility of
billions of
in percentage
thousands
growth,
euro (2012)
(2012)
(2012)
standard
deviation of
real GDP
growth from
2002-2012
Estonia
17
91
1325
7.27
Latvia
22
62
2045
8.47
Lithuania
33
84
3004
6.95
Austria
307
57
8408
2.05
Belgium
376
86
11095
1.71
Denmark
245
55
5581
2.42
Netherlands
600
88
16730
2.14
Norway
389
41
4986
1.56
Sweden
408
49
9483
3.03
Switzerland
491
52
7955
1.76
Sources: Eurostat 2013; author’s calculations.
31
Table 2. Selected indicators of domestic compensation and democratic corporatism for the
Baltic countries, Visegrad countries and EU average
Expenditure on
Non crisis state
Labour market
social protection,
aid to industry
policy expenditure, (net union
in percentage of
and services, in
in percentage of
membership as a
GDP (2011)
percentage of
GDP (2011)
proportion of wage
GDP (2009-2011)
Union density rate
and salary earners
in employment)
(2009)
Estonia
16.1
0.11
0.73
7.1
Latvia
15.1
0.27
0.69
14.8
Lithuania
17.0
0.37
0.56
8.5
Poland
19.2
0.73
0.72
15.1
Czech
20.4
0.64
0.56
17.4
Slovakia
18.2
0.33
0.79
17.2
Hungary
23.0
1.33
1.01
16.8
Slovenia
25.0
0.89
1.24
26.6
EU
29.1
0.48
1.95
NA
Republic
average
Sources: Columns 1, 2 and 3: Eurostat; Column 4: Visser.
32
Table 3. Trust in political institutions in the Baltic countries.
Parliament
Government
Political parties Regional/local
Justice system
authorities
Estonia
49
58
21
59
76
Latvia
11
15
4
40
48
Lithuania
8
15
6
24
48
36
20
50
66
All countries in 38
Eurobarometer
(average)
Percentage of people who tend to trust in a given institution in 2010 (for parliament and
government) and 2011 (political parties, regional/local authorities and justice system). Sources:
Masso, Espenberg, Masso, Mierina, Philips 2012, p. 92, based on Eurobarometer surveys.
70.0
60.0
50.0
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0
Bulgaria
Lithuania
Latvia
Romania
Slovakia
Estonia
Poland
Ireland
Malta
Norway
Luxembourg
Czech Republic
Germany
Cyprus
Croatia
Portugal
Iceland
Spain
United Kingdom
Slovenia
Hungary
Netherlands
Italy
Austria
Sweden
Greece
Belgium
France
Finland
Denmark
0.0
Figure 1. EU member states and selected other countries in terms of expenditure as
percentage of GDP in 2012. Source: Eurostat.
33
Download