Problem 1: Insurance Consider the insurance model described in 2.1.1. Chapter 6. (1) Explain equation (3) and the Arrow-Borch condition. Left side: Marginal rate of substitution between Leisure and consumption Right side: Marginal productivity of labor. Condition for pareto efficient allocation (first best) Indifference curve, slope : W B Production function, slope: A h Allocation A is first best pareto efficient, as the slopes of the production function and the agent’s indifference curve are equal. If the agent worked more and consumed more goods, she could receive the same utility as before. However, allocation B is not feasible under the given production function. There is no other combination of hours worked, h, and consumption, W (=c), that provides the agent with the same level of utility as allocation A. Arrow Borch condition Left side: Agent’s Marginal Rate of Substitution measured by marginal utilities of consumption in two different states. Right side: Principal’s Marginal Rate of Substation measured by marginal utilities of consumption in two different states Risk sharing is optimal if both MRS are equal. Intuition: Imagine if the agent’s ratio of marginal utilities (MRS) equals 3 and the principal’s 1 (risk neutral). Then the agent would be willing to give up 3 units of consumption in the good state (θ) to receive one more unit of consumption in the bad state (є). The principal however, only demands 1 unit for compensation, if he has to give up one unit in state θ. Pareto improvement possible (2) Let the Agent’s utility function be given by 𝑈(𝐶, 𝐿) = 10ln(𝐶) + 5ln(L). Leisure is 24-hours worked. The production function is given by 𝑓(ℎ, 𝜀) = 10𝜀 + 𝜀ℎ while the Principal’s utility function is 𝑣(𝜋) = 2√𝜋. Is the following contract optimal? CONTRACT 1: Good state: 𝜀 = 𝑔 = 1 W(g)=, 10, h(g)=19 Bad state: 𝜀 = 𝑔 = 0,5 W(b)=10, h(g)=14 Assume now that the Principal’s utility function instead is given by 𝑣(𝜋) = 10𝜋. Is the contract optimal now? Optimal contract is characterized by UL [W(ε), 1 − h(ε)] = fn [h(ε), ε], UC [W(ε), 1 − h(ε)] UC [W(ε), 1 − h(ε)] V ′ [π(ε)] = ′ , UC [W(θ), 1 − h(θ)] V [π(θ)] ∀ε ∈ ε ∀(ε, θ) ∈ ε2 Thus, UL = 5 10 , UC = , fh = ε ∵ L = 24 − h, W = C 24 − h W Therefore, 5⁄ 24 − h = ε ⋯ (1) 10⁄ W And, for the optimal risk-sharing, there should be 10⁄ 1 W(g) V ′ [π(ε)] ′ = ′ , V (π) = ⋯ (2) 10⁄ V [π(θ)] √π W(b) To be the optimal contract, the both equations (1) and (2) must be satisfied. Contract 1 : Goodstate ∶ ε = g = 1, W(g) = 10, h(g) = 19 Badstate ∶ ε = g = 0.5, W(b) = 10, h(g) = 14 Let’s substitute those numbers to the equation (1) and (2), 5 5 = 1(good), = 0.5(bad) ⋯ (1) 24 − 19 24 − 14 1 ≠ 1 = √0.5 ⋯ (2) 1⁄ √0.5 The second equation is not satisfied. Therefore, the Contract 1 is not the optimal contract. Assume V(π)=10π, then V’(π)=10 For the first equation, there is not any change. Thus, it is satisfied. For the second equation, 1= V ′ [π(ε)] 10 = =1 V ′ [π(θ)] 10 Therefore, under the assumption that the principal is now risk neutral (V(π)=10π), the contract is optimal because the agent has the same utility in both states. In the absence of asymmetric information full insurance is optimal as the principal does not face the trade-off between incentives and insurance. (3) The figure below shows profits and wage costs in the Norwegian Maritime sector. Comment the figure in light of the theoretical model (“Driftsresultat”= profits, “Lønnskostnader”= wage costs). Corresponding to the assumptions of the model, wages don’t fluctuate as much as profits. This can reflect the fact that the agent is more risk averse than the principal (or has limited access to the capital market) and needs insurance. Therefore wages did not increase as much as profits, especially during the period 2002 – 2008. Nevertheless in reality there is probably asymmetric information. This means that the principal faces a trade-off between incentives and insurance. So wages are not totally fixed. This is a result of the fact that the principal wants to set incentives. There are some facts that contradict the model: - Wages have never declined significantly. This might be due to rigidities (contracts, unions and other interest groups, …) Further, wage costs do not perfectly reflect wages itself. So, rises and declines of wage costs might be a result of changes in taxes and/or social charges (4) Use the provided dataset for the US and compare the predictions from the insurance model (regarding business cycles) to the fluctuations in hours worked and weekly earnings from 1979 to 2010. Here we have to look at equation 3: The marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure must be equal to the marginal productivity of labour. The change in the marginal utility in consumption must be equal to the change in the marginal utility of leisure with respect to a constant marginal productivity of labour. A decline in working hours means a rise in leisure and the marginal utility of leisure decreases and a increase in the wage rate leads to higher consumption opportunities and therefore to a lower marginal utility of consumption. All in all the development of working hours and wages must go in opposite direction to maintain a constant marginal rate of substitution. When we look at the data we see that in the years between 1979 and 2010 there are continous upand downward movements. But in almost half of this specific time horizont, these two variables go in the same direction. In addition the magnitude of the changes are different. If a positive productivity shock occurs,the marginal productivity of labour increases. Corresponding to themodel, the marginal rate of substitution has to increase as well. That means that the marginal utility of leisure must rise relatively to the marginal utlity of consumption. Thus the consumption of leisure decreases relatively to the consumption of physical goods. Some facts that contradict the model: assymetric information, leisure is not a normal good, rigidities.. If you just take into consideration the last six years, the dataset fits approximative with the model. Hours worked per employee 1860 1840 1820 Hours worked per employee, from OECD Employment Statistics 1800 1780 1760 1740 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 1720 Weekly earnings 360 350 340 330 Weekly earnings (in 1982 USD), from CPS, BLS 320 310 300 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 290