DYNAMIC MODELLING OF POLLUTION ABATEMENT IN A CGE FRAMEWORK Rob DELLINK, Marjan Hofkes, Ekko van Ierland and Harmen Verbruggen* Environmental Economics and Natural Resources group Wageningen University Hollandseweg 1 6706 KN Wageningen, The Netherlands tel. +31 317 482009 fax +31 317 484933 email Rob.Dellink@alg.shhk.wag-ur.nl http://www.sls.wageningen-ur.nl/enr/staff/dellink/dellink.html ABSTRACT This paper deals with the specification of pollution abatement in dynamic Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) models and analyses the dynamic feedback mechanisms between economic variables and abatement in the context of environmental policy. A small-open-economy model is presented, in which bottom-up technical and economic information on abatement techniques is integrated in a top-down CGE-approach. The practical suitability of the specification is illustrated in the empirical application focusing on climate change and acidification. Finally, the sensitivity analysis focuses on the impact of the assumptions underlying the specification of emissions and abatement. The results show that the specification of the environmental issues is highly relevant for the calculation of the economic costs of environmental policy. This holds especially for the specification of climate change abatement options, since controlling the emissions of greenhouse gasses leads to significant economic costs, which depend largely on the availability of technological options for emission reduction. JEL CLASSIFICATION D58, O41, Q20 * Rob Dellink and Ekko van Ierland work at Wageningen University (The Netherlands); Marjan Hofkes and Harmen Verbruggen work at the Institute for Environmental Studies of Vrije Universiteit (The Netherlands). KEYWORDS Computable General Equilibrium models, pollution abatement, dynamics, tradable pollution permits 2 1. INTRODUCTION In order to make good estimations of the economic costs of environmental policy it is important how the abatement costs, and of the underlying abatement technologies, are specified. On the one hand, standard CGE models use smooth, continuous production and utility functions and do not pay explicit attention to the characteristics of the abatement technologies involved. This is a common critique by technically oriented scientists on these top-down economic models. On the other hand, most models that include the technical aspects of changing economic structures do not model the indirect economic effects of these technologies (i.e. they adopt a partial framework). The large number of technological options available for pollution reduction complicates the use of discrete technology modelling in CGE models. In this paper a different methodology is presented, which combines the advantages of the topdown approach of CGE models with the information on abatement technologies included in the bottom-up approach (for more details see Dellink, 2000). The paper deals with different ways in which pollution abatement can be modelled in dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) models. The CGE approach is chosen because it provides a consistent framework to analyse the economic impacts of environmental policy: it has sound micro-economic foundations and a complete description of the economy with both direct and indirect effects of policy changes. There is a growing literature on dynamic CGE models for environmental policy analysis, including e.g. Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1990) and Böhringer (1998); an overview of dynamic CGEs is given in Harrison et al. (2000). The set-up of this paper is as follows. In Section 2, the main CGE model is described. Section 3 deals with the specification of abatement with an emphasis on the dynamic characteristics of the abatement processes. Section 4 illustrates the model with a numerical example, analysing the dynamic impacts of climate change and acidification policies on the Dutch economy. Section 5 concludes. The appendices contain all the model equations (Appendix A1) and a description of the initial data (Appendix A2). 2. GENERAL DESCRIPTION OF THE MODEL The model used in this paper is a dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model with perfect foresight in the Ramsey tradition1. A more detailed description of the basic model is given in Dellink (2000), where this model specification is compared with other specifications of the dynamic issues. Here, only a general description of the model is given, focusing on the assumptions that are needed to build a multi-sectoral (dynamic) applied general equilibrium 1 The forward-looking model has the advantage over recursive-dynamic models that consumers maximise their utility not only based on the current state of the economy, but also on future welfare (discounted to present values). This intertemporal aspect lacks in a recursive-dynamic model. Empirical estimates suggest that consumers in reality do look ahead to some extent, but do not maximise their utility till infinity (Srinivasan, 1982 and Ballard and Goulder, 1985). Intuitively, it is hard to imagine that none of the economic agents in the model takes a long-term view for his or hers decisions (Solow, 1974). 3 model, including a specification of environmental pollution and abatement activities. The full set of equations of the model is represented in Appendix A1. Demand for and supply of produced goods and primary factors, which result from the agents’ optimisation problems, meet each other on the markets. Relative prices adjust such that an equilibrium is reached simultaneously on all markets (both current and future markets). Producers (firms) maximise profits under the restriction of their production technology, for given prices. The nested-CES production function consists of the input of labour and capital and intermediate deliveries from the other producing sectors. Each producer produces one unique output from the inputs. As full competition and constant returns to scale are assumed, no excess profits can be reaped and the maximum-profit-condition diminishes to a least-cost-condition. The private households are included as the single representative consumer,. The private households maximise the present value of current and future utility under a budget constraint, for given prices and given initial endowments. They own the production factors labour and capital (the endowments) and consume produced goods, for which a CES-type utility function is used. The budget constraint is only applied to the present value of all periods together and not to individual periods, so that intertemporal borrowing of funds is assumed possible 2. The annual labour supply is fixed, but the wage rate is fully flexible; an exogenous growth of the labour supply in efficiency units is assumed. This growth in the labour supply, which reflects both increases in the population as well as increases in technological efficiency, drives the growth of the economy. In the current version of the model, there is no international trade. This implies that the rate of return on investments is determined on the domestic market. The capital stock and investment levels are fully endogenised; households choose to save part of their income until the rate of return on investments equals the exogenously given interest rate. These savings are in turn used by the producers as capital investments. The forward-looking behaviour of the agents and the endogenous savings rate make this model of the Cass-Koopmans-Ramsey type Barro and Sala-iMartin (1995). The government sector collects taxes on all traded goods (both produced goods and the primary production factors) and uses the proceeds to finance public consumption of the two produced goods and pay for a lump-sum transfer to the private household. Furthermore, the assumption is made that public utility is unaffected by the model simulations, i.e. it stays at the level of the base projection; this is achieved by proportionately changing the existing tax rates to mitigate changes in income and/or expenditures of the government3. Production processes lead to pollution, which is regarded as a necessary (environmental) input for the production and utility functions. In the policy scenarios, pollution is controlled by the government by means of annual tradable pollution permits, that the producers and consumers can 2 However, as consumption goods have to be produced, which leads to additional income from the sale of the primary inputs, and there is not international trade, the income condition is satisfied for each period and intertemporal borrowing of funds does not occur. 3 This implies that the government budget constraint holds for every period. 4 buy from the government (the proceeds are used to reduce existing taxes) 4. In this way, a market for pollution permits is created, where, as in all markets in the model, prices are determined endogenously by equating demand and supply. Polluters have the choice between paying for their pollution permits or investing in pollution abatement. This choice is endogenous in the model, and the polluters will always choose the least-cost of the two. A third possibility for producers and consumers is a reduction of their production and consumption, respectively. This becomes a sensible option when both the marginal abatement cost and the price of the permits are higher than the value added foregone in reducing production or utility foregone in reducing consumption. Environmental quality is not directly included in the utility function, because it is assumed that the government sets the environmental targets by issuing a restricted number of pollution permits. Consumers’ environmental expenditures (on pollution rights and abatement) do have an impact on the maximum consumption and utility level achievable, but environmental stocks and damages are not taken into account. In policy terms, the model is not used for Pigouvian analyses (Pigou, 1938), where the optimal tax rate is determined by the trade-off between abatement costs and damage costs, but rather for Baumollian exercises where the cost-effective way to reach a predetermined policy target is analysed (Baumol, 1977). 3. THE DYNAMIC BEHAVIOUR OF ABATEMENT 3.1. Introduction As mentioned above, polluters have the choice between paying for pollution permits or paying for abatement. The calibration of the possibilities and costs of abatement options is important to get a good estimate of the economic costs of environmental policy. In most literature, the abatement costs are only implicitly modelled (as profit or utility losses), or modelled through a quadratic abatement cost curve (e.g. Nordhaus and Yang, 1996). Key exceptions are the detailed energyeconomic models (e.g. Manne et al., 1995) that specify alternative ways to produce energy (a form of emission abatement). More general specifications of abatement are used by Nestor and Pasurka (1995), Böhringer (1998) and Hyman (2001). A key feature of the model presented in this paper is that the expenditures on abatement are specified to capture as much information as possible about the technical measures underlying the abatement options. 3.2. The static trade-off between pollution and abatement As a first step in including the technical abatement information in the model, abatement cost curves have to be constructed for each environmental theme from the raw technical data for the base year. This step involves making an inventory of all available abatement options (both end-ofpipe and process-integrated options), ranking the measures by cost-effectiveness and solving some methodological and practical problems (including how to deal with measures that exclude each other and measures that have to be taken in a fixed order). For details on this first step see Dellink 4 Practical difficulties may lead to a different choice of policy instrument in reality. Nonetheless, the approach taken here is the cost-effective one and can therefore serve as a reference point for evaluating other policy instruments. 5 and van der Woerd (1997) and De Boer (2000a,b). Note that the abatement cost curves contain all known available options to reduce pollution, both end-of-pipe as well as process-integrated options; amongst others Pasurka (2001) stresses the importance of process-integrated measures. The abatement cost curves, which describe the marginal abatement costs, are translated for each environmental theme into a ‘substitution curve’ of pollution and abatement. This means that the abatement costs are presented as a function of pollution (a downward sloping curve). Then, for each theme a CES function (the substitution curve) is calibrated to best fit the abatement/pollution curve. The CES-elasticity thus estimated describes the environmental theme-specific possibilities to substitute between pollution and abatement (hence the name substitution curve). The technical potential to reduce pollution through abatement activities provides an absolute upper bound on abatement in the model. This is a clear advantage over the traditional quadratic abatement cost curves, where no true upper bound on abatement activities exists (the abatement costs will always be finite, no matter how much pollution is abated). Dellink (2000) includes more details on this procedure, that combines the advantages of the CGE approach with technical and economic information on abatement techniques. The trade-off between pollution and abatement in mathematical form looks as follows 5: ESe, j ,t CES ( EeU, j ,t , CES ( EeA, j ,t , Ae, j ,t ; eA, j ); eES, j ) for each (e,j,t), with eES, j 0 (1) where subscript e denotes the environmental theme, j the sector and t the time period. The formula shows that the total of delivered ‘environmental services’ ( ES e , j ,t )are a nested CES-function. On the highest level ‘unabatable’ emissions ( EeU, j ,t ) are combined with the aggregate of ‘abatable’ emissions ( EeA, j ,t ) and the expenditures on abatement ( Ae , j ,t ), with a substitution elasticity of zero A A ( eES , j 0 ). The lower level, CES ( Ee, j ,t , Ae, j ,t ; e, j ) , brings together the abatable emissions and expenditures on abatement with a substitution elasticity eA, j . This latter substitution elasticity is estimated using the procedure explained above; moreover, the division between abatable and unabatable emissions is based on the technical potential (expressed as share of total emissions and labelled eemax ,t ): U max EeA, j ,t eemax ,t Ee, j ,t and Ee , j ,t 1 ee ,t Ee , j ,t (2) Figure 1 illustrates the concept of the abatement cost curve and associated substitution curve. Note that the x-axis gives pollution instead of pollution reduction. In the case of climate change, emissions in the Netherlands can be reduced from 254 megatons of CO2-equivalents to 164 megatons CO2-equivalents (given the current state of technology) 6. Each mark on the abatement 5 To be precise, the trade-off is between expenditures on pollution rights and expenditures on abatement. A similar formula applies to the environmental services for the households. The notation CES ( x, y; xy ) is used to denote a CES function with two inputs, x and y, that are combined using a substitution elasticity xy . See the footnote in Appendix A1 for more details. 6 The graph and underlying data are based on analysis for 1990 and described in Verbruggen et al. (2001). 6 cost curve gives an individual technical measure; the line without markers shows the estimated substitution curve. Figure 1. A substitution curve for greenhouse gasses 4000 Technical potential Current emissions Emission reduction costs (annual; mln guilders) 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 Abatement cost curve 500 Substitution curve 0 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 emissions (Mtons CO2-equivalents) Note that in the construction of the abatement cost curves, all costs are transformed into annual costs, including the capital costs (annuity interest and depreciation payments) of the investments. In the model, these capital costs of abatement investments are treated similar to ‘conventional’ man-made capital, i.e. the firms pay the capital costs while the households provide the means necessary for investments (in the form of savings). This means that the order in which the measures are represented in the abatement cost curve is appropriate to the way the firms decide upon adoption of a measure. For sake of convenience, the ratio between investment costs and operational costs are assumed constant over all measures. 3.3. Development of abatement costs over time When moving from period t to period t+1, several effects take place that have an impact on the abatement cost curves and especially on the technical potential for emission reduction ( eemax ,t ) and the curvature of the curve (in model terms, the substitution elasticity eA, j ). The first effect that takes place is that some abatement measures are adopted by the polluters (diffusion of this abatement technology)7. At first glance, this would lead to a reduction of the technical potential and an increase in average abatement costs (since the least-cost options will be 7 Partial adoption (or diffusion) of a technology is a partial implementation of a measure and leads to a contraction of the respective point on the curve, with constant cost-effectiveness. Assuming an identical abatement function for all polluters means that first the most cost-effective measure will be fully taken before the next measure is partially implemented. The treatment of the abatement cost curve as a continuous function, instead of as a stepwise function with discrete choices (take the measure or not) implies that partial implementation of the measure in the economy (partial diffusion) is assumed possible. 7 implemented first). However, what is modelled in the substitution curve is the annual abatement costs. A polluter has to pay the costs of the same measure each year again; in other words, adopting a measure in year t does not automatically imply adoption of the same measure in year t+1: this implies that in the present specification the decision is reversible. Consequently, the substitution curve does not change due to this effect, as all adopted measures are present again in A the following year. The technical potential eemax ,t , the substitution elasticity e , j and the benchmark price of abatement PA all remain constant over time. The second effect is a reduction of the (marginal) costs of all existing measures, presumable at a higher rate than can be based on labour productivity developments (i.e. labour augmenting technological change plus other technological progress, like learning effects). This reduction in abatement costs can be explicitly modelled in the model as a reduction in the price of abatement coupled with an efficiency improvement in the abatement production process. This effect has no impact on the technical potential, but might lead to a (small) decrease of the substitution elasticity. The third effect is that new abatement measures will emerge through innovation (path-dependent, small innovations are part of the second effect). Though these new measures are presumably more efficient than existing measures, they are likely to be far from the adoption phase. Hence the substitution curve will be extended to above and to the left, thereby increasing the technical potential. The effect of these new measures on the substitution elasticity cannot be predicted beforehand, but is likely to be very small. Consequently, a constant substitution elasticity may be assumed. The fourth effect is that old techniques that are obsolete and have never been implemented are removed from the curve. This effect counters the third effect, but is likely to be smaller in size. In the base specification, the technical potential and substitution elasticity are assumed constant over time and the exogenous efficiency improvements in the abatement sector absent. However, as a sensitivity analysis, the increase in the technical potential is modelled through a linear growth function: every period the technical potential grows with g . A decreasing price of abatement is captured through exogenous efficiency improvements in the abatement sector ( abeiA,t ), coupled with decreasing associated prices. It is not unlikely that efficiency improvements in the abatement sector will not lead to a decrease in the use of inputs, but rather to a decrease in output prices. For example, increased fuel efficiency in cars has not lead to decreases in fuel use, but rather to larger cars. Finally, it should be recalled that the model also contains exogenous technological progress in environmental efficiency, governed by an autonomous pollution efficiency improvements ( apeie ,t ); this effect is present in both the base specification and the sensitivity analysis. 3.4. The base specification of the abatement sector In the base specification, abatement is modelled as a separate producer, where ‘abatement goods’ are produced using both produced goods and primary production factors as inputs. This is roughly in line with Nestor and Pasurka (1995), but there the abatement sector is an implicit part of the government sector, and hence does not have a specific structure. In the model presented here, a 8 CES production function is calibrated, for which the data are derived from substitution curves: the inputs in this production function represent the ‘spending effects’ of implementing technical measures8. It is assumed that these spending effects are homogenous over the complete abatement cost curve and do not differ between the environmental themes. The model thus includes one producer (the abatement sector) to represent the abatement activities. The output of the abatement sector is demanded by the other producers and by consumers, so each producer and consumer in principle has the same set of abatement technologies available. Each can, however, have different substitution possibilities between investing in abatement and buying pollution permits, as they have different initial combinations of abatement costs and pollution levels and hence start on different points on the curve. Consequently, the costs of abatement will differ between the producers. The marginal abatement costs will be equalised in the model, as the resulting equilibrium is characterised by cost-effectiveness. These marginal abatement costs in the new equilibrium will also equal the price of the pollution permits. Hence, all polluters are indifferent at the margin between polluting and investing in abatement. The equations for the base model are represented in Appendix A1. The model as described above assumes that expenditures on pollution abatement are reversible over time (see above). In other words, abatement is modelled as a flow variable, i.e. as a nondurable good, and decisions on abatement expenditures are short-term decisions. However, as capital is needed for production of the abatement goods, the choice of the abatement level is not entirely reversible (though the capital employed in the abatement sector can be transferred without costs to other sectors in the economy). From theory it follows that the price of the abatement goods equal the marginal abatement costs. In the bottom-up technical description of the abatement measures, annual costs consist of capital costs, that is the interest and depreciation costs associated with investments, and net operational costs. Marginal abatement costs are changing over time. Since the abatement sector is a production sector like the other production sectors, the production costs of abatement goods are influenced by the general development of labour productivity9. For example, as real labour costs decrease over time, so do the production costs of abatement. Consequently, if the production process of abatement is relatively labour-intensive the relative costs of abatement in comparison to other goods will decrease. Reversibly, if abatement is labour-extensive, the relative costs of abatement will increase over time10. Not only labour costs, but also the prices of all goods that are input to the abatement sector will influence the real abatement costs. 8 These spending effects are the increase in the demand for produced goods and primary factors by the abatement sector. 9 In the model, increases in labour productivity are modelled through an increase in the supply of labour, measured in efficiency units (i.e. not in number of people). Mathematically, this is equivalent. 10 Empirical data suggest that in the Netherlands abatement is more labour-intensive than the other produced goods (labour makes up a little less than 50% of abatement costs; Dellink, 2000), and hence real abatement costs are decreasing over time. 9 4. EMPIRICAL APPLICATION OF THE MODEL 4.1. Introduction The model specification described above is applied in this section in a numerical example, based on data for the Netherlands, with 1990 as the base year. Data sources are the national accounts (Statistics Netherlands, 2001) and environmental data provided by RIVM (2000). GDP is calibrated to 578 billion guilders and abatement expenditures amount to 360 million guilders (excluding expenditures on waste management, which are assumed to be part of the services sector). The full set of data as used in calibrating the model for 1990 is given in Appendix A2. In interpreting the results one should keep in mind that the description of the economy is kept simple, with only 3 production sectors and no international trade.11 The benchmark projection The benchmark projection (the simulation of the model without the environmental policy impulse) consists of an (autonomous) increase in labour productivity of 2% per year. This leads to a balanced growth of the economy of 2% per annum. There is an autonomous pollution efficiency improvement of 1% per year for acidifying emissions and 1.5% for greenhouse gas emissions, resulting in a growth of emissions of 1% and 0.5%, respectively, per year (values based on Verbruggen et al., 2001). All producers have a CES production function for intermediate deliveries and primary factors with an elasticity of substitution of 0.5. The substitution elasticity between abatement and pollution is set to 1.26 for climate and 1.4 for acid related emissions respectively (this value is based on Verbruggen et al., 2001)12. Investments are made up of agricultural and industrial goods and services in a ratio of 1:83:16. Private consumers have a utility function with a CES elasticity of 0.5; the corresponding elasticity for the government is set at 0 (Leontief’ utility function). The intertemporal rate of substitution of consumption is set at 0.75 (only applicable to the private households). The depreciation rate is set at 5 percent and the interest rate at 4 percent. The policy impulse Environmental policy aims at stabilisation of emissions at the 1990-level. As the emissions are rising in the benchmark projection, the stabilisation policy leads to increasingly large differences between the number of permits issued and the reference emissions (which can be interpreted as the base demand for the permits). Figure 2 shows how the issued number of permits deviates from the benchmark projection13. 11 Though these simplifications make the model results more tractable, the confidence to be placed on the numerical outcomes is limited. A full empirical analysis is beyond the scope of the current paper. 12 Note that the high APEI, high price, low elasticity and low technical potential for climate change reflects an abatement curve with a relatively long initial part of very low costs, combined with a steep increase in marginal abatement costs further in the curve. For acidification, the marginal abatement costs increase more gradually. 13 All results shown in this paper are relative changes compared to the benchmark projection values. 10 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 2025 2020 2015 2010 2005 2000 1995 1990 Figure 2. Effects of environmental policy on emissions for climate change and acidification %-change compared to benchmark 0% -5% -10% -15% -20% -25% -30% -35% -40% -45% -50% Climate change Acidification 4.2. Results for the policy scenario using the base specification It is expected that the environmental policy as discussed above will lead to increasing expenditures on abatement and a small reduction in GDP. Figure 3 shows the development of the demand for abatement goods over time. Even though in the base model the decision to adopt abatement measures is reversible, this does not imply that the substitution possibilities are infinite. First, there is a finite substitution elasticity between pollution and abatement; and second, there is a capital input in the abatement production function. This prevents a situation where extremely large fluctuations in the demand for abatement occurs. The results confirm that the demand for abatement goods is relatively stable over time. For all polluting sectors, the demand for abatement increases rapidly and even at an increasing rate. The increasing rate at which the demand for abatement grows cannot be directly explained by the development in pollution levels (compare Figure 3 with Figure 2). The more than proportionate increase of abatement over time can be attributed to the decreasing unit abatement costs over time (caused by the increases in labour productivity). Abatement expenditures increase by a factor 10 as compared to the benchmark projection in 2050. 11 Figure 3. Effects of environmental policy on the sectoral demand for abatement goods %-change compared to benchmark 1100% 1000% 900% 800% 700% 600% 500% 400% 300% 200% 100% Agriculture Industry Services 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 2025 2020 2015 2010 2005 2000 1995 1990 0% Private households The reduction in abatable emissions is substantial; in the later period, up to two-thirds of the abatable emissions are abated (see the left panel in Figure 4). For the unabatable emissions, the reduction is of course much smaller; it is slightly larger than the reduction in GDP (see the right panel in Figure 4). This clearly shows the shift in the economy from relatively dirty production to cleaner sectors. Note that though the development of both abatable and unabatable emissions are very similar for climate change and acidification, the share of abatable emissions in total emissions is smaller for climate change. Consequently, the reduction in total emissions is much smaller for climate change than for acidification (see also Figure 2). The reduction in unabatable emissions also shows that the marginal costs of abatement are becoming so high at higher rates of abatement that it becomes cheaper to reduce economic activity. Figure 4. Development of abatable and unabatable emissions 0% -10% -20% -30% -40% -50% -60% -70% -80% C l i m a te c h a n g e 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 0 .0 % - 0 .5 % - 1 .0 % - 1 .5 % - 2 .0 % - 2 .5 % - 3 .0 % C l i m a te c h a n g e A c i d i fi c a ti o n 2025 2020 2015 2010 2005 2000 1995 1990 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 2025 2020 2015 2010 2005 2000 1995 U n a b a ta b le e m is s io n s %-change com pared to benchm ark %-change com par e d to be nchm ar k 1990 Ab a ta b le e m is s io n s A c i d i fi c a ti o n Given the limited size of the abatement sector in the benchmark, the effects on the rest of the economy are expected to be limited. Table 1 shows that this is indeed the case in the short run, but 12 in the longer run the negative impact on GDP is above one percent. Apparently, the (indirect) positive impact of the increased abatement expenditures is too small to fully mitigate the negative direct impact of the environmental policy. Note that the long run decrease of GDP of between 1 and 2 percent is still moderate given the large decreases in emission levels. For example Tol (1997) shows that the world average estimate of GDP-loss of stabilising CO2 emissions in 2010 is 0.4%. In 2050, the agricultural sector is most negatively affected by the environmental policy, primarily due to the significantly decreasing consumption of agricultural goods (see Table 1 below)14. The agricultural sector is relatively worse off on the one hand due to the relatively high pollution intensities in this sector, and on the other hand due to the absence of the positive indirect effect of higher demand for products by the abatement sector. The least hurt by the environmental policy is the relatively clean and profitable services sector, though the general slowdown of the economy also generates a negative net impact on this sector from 2010 onwards. Table 1. Changes in main variables in the non-durable good case (%-change in volumes compared to 1990 2000 2010 2025 2050 0.00% -0.11% -0.24% -0.56% -1.64% -0.22% -0.58% -1.03% -2.16% -6.81% Private consumption of Industrial goods 0.05% -0.13% -0.32% -0.78% -2.95% Private consumption of Services 0.20% 0.13% 0.10% Sectoral production Agriculture -0.17% -0.37% -0.65% -1.34% -3.77% Sectoral production Industry -0.14% -0.28% -0.47% -0.95% -2.33% Sectoral production Services 0.10% benchmark) GDP Private consumption of Agricultural goods 0.03% -0.03% -0.77% 0.06% -0.33% -0.13% -0.60% Capital investment -0.31% -0.49% -1.52% -3.38% Abatement expenditures -0.33% 42.14% 107.37% 274.39% 922.06% Greenhouse gas emissions 0.00% -4.86% -9.49% -16.02% -25.87% Acidifying emissions 0.00% -9.47% -18.05% -29.41% -44.96% Capital investments drop in the first period to allow the households to have a higher level of consumption in the first period. This has a large positive impact on utility, while the resulting lower consumption levels in later periods (as the lower investments slowdown economic growth) have less impact on utility in present values, given the positive discount factor. The consumers foresee that they will be confronted with increasingly strict environmental policy and choose to adapt to that by slowing down the rate of economic growth and increasing current consumption. 14 The income elasticities of all goods are implicitly assumed to be equal to one, given the CES-structure of the utility function. This may be changed by introducing a Linear Expenditure System. Such an extension of the model is expected to have only a minor effect on the general outcomes of the model. 13 The impact of the environmental policy on the development of GDP, the income of private households and investments is shown graphically in Figure 5. Over time, the gap between the policy-GDP and the benchmark projection gets larger and larger. This mirrors the strictness of environmental policy, at least in qualitative terms. The impacts on GDP are relatively small, so that in absolute terms GDP keeps growing even with stabilisation of emissions. In other words, a decoupling between economic growth and environmental pressure related to climate change and acidification is achievable. 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 2025 2020 2015 2010 2005 2000 1995 1990 Figure 5. Impact of environmental policy on GDP and private household income %-change compared to benchmark 0.5% 0.0% -0.5% -1.0% -1.5% -2.0% -2.5% -3.0% -3.5% -4.0% GDP Income Private Households Investment 4.3. Results of sensitivity analysis 4.3.1. Exogenous developments in abatement technology In this first sensitivity analysis, the technical potential for emission reduction techniques increases with 1 percent-point every eight years (i.e. g ,e equals 0.00125). Consequently, the share of abatable greenhouse gas emissions is 41% in 1990 and slowly increases to 48.5% in 2050. This increase in the technical potential is combined with increasing efficiency in the abatement sector. An autonomous abatement efficiency improvement parameter ( abeiA,t ) of 1% per year is introduced, leading to decreasing abatement costs and a decreasing output price of the abatement sector. 14 Table 2. Main results of sensitivity analysis on abatement technology alternative specifications base incl. abatement (volumes; bln. only technical only efficiency technology potential effect effect benchmark specification 0 -0.76% -0.61% -0.61% -0.76% GDP 1990 578 578 578 578 578 GDP 2020 1047 1043 1043 1043 1043 GDP 2050 1897 1866 1871 1871 1866 Abatement 1990 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 Abatement 2020 0.65 2.00 2.63 1.96 2.68 Abatement 2050 1.18 12.07 18.85 10.50 21.68 15 NLG ) Equivalent Variation Table 2 shows the outcomes of this change in model specification for the equivalent variation, GDP and abatement expenditures. The different columns give the benchmark projection, the result for the base specification and the results of the sensitivity analysis on abatement technology. These alternative specifications are split into three parts: (i) including the increase in the technical potential over time, combined with increasing abatement efficiency; (ii) only the increase in technical potential; and (iii) only the increase in abatement efficiency. For the details of these alternative specifications see Section 3.3. above. The most striking result is an increase in abatement activity: in 2050, the increase in abatement is almost 1500 percent or an absolute level of 18.85 billion NLG, as shown in Table 2. In the base specification, the increase is 922 percent, leading to abatement expenditures of 12.07 billion NLG. This increase is in line with expectations, as both the increasing technical potential and the increased abatement efficiency lead to lower abatement costs relative to the price of the emission permits. The abatement efficiency improvement leads purely to a lower price of abatement, which is offset by an increase in the abatement volume, so that total expenditures on abatement remain constant. Consequently, there is no impact of the abatement efficiency improvement on the rest of the economy. The increase in the technical potential does have an impact on the rest of the economy, as it allows for more abatement and less emission reduction through economic restructuring. The perverse situation arises that the larger technical potential leads to a smaller increase in abatement than in the base specification. This can be explained by the fact that a larger share of abatable emissions means that the marginal abatement costs are lower. In other words, the starting point for substitution between abatable emissions and abatement shifts towards relatively more emissions and less abatement. Given the constant elasticity of substitution, this implies lower abatement costs. 15 NLG stands for Dutch guilders; 1 NLG = 0.45378 Euro. 15 4.3.2. Changing emission-abatement substitution elasticity Another assumption that is clearly relevant for the outcomes is the substitution elasticity between abatable emissions and abatement. In the base specification, this elasticity is calibrated to 1.26 for climate change and 1.41 for acidification, and assumed constant over time. The results of three sensitivity analyses are presented in Table 3. In the third column, both elasticities are decreasing with 0.01 per decade (so after 60 years they are 1.2 and 1.35, respectively). In the fourth column, they are assumed to be increasing at the same speed (and consequently in 2050 they equal 1.32 and 1.47, respectively). In the last column, the increase in this elasticity is assumed to apply only to climate change. This latter sensitivity analysis is added to show to what extent climate change causes the changes in the model results. The expected outcome is that a lower elasticity leads to a more negative economic impact, as marginal abatement costs are increasing more rapidly. Table 3. Main results of sensitivity analysis on emission-abatement substitution elasticity alternative specifications base lower elasticity higher elasticity higher elasticity (volumes; bln. benchmark specification NLG) Equivalent Variation for both for both climate ch. themes themes only 0 -0.76% -0.96% -0.64% -0.64% GDP 1990 578 578 578 578 578 GDP 2020 1047 1043 1042 1043 1043 GDP 2050 1897 1866 1859 1870 1870 Abatement 1990 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 Abatement 2020 0.65 2.00 2.04 1.97 1.97 Abatement 2050 1.18 12.07 13.75 10.75 10.78 The results shown in Table 3 confirm the expectations: a lower substitution elasticity between abatable emissions and abatement causes lower levels of GDP and consumption (and hence EV) in the long run. The abatement levels are higher, but not dramatically. The polluters are confronted with higher abatement cots than in the base specification, but they have no real alternative, as the costs of reducing unabatable emissions through a reduction of output are also very costly. For larger assumed substitution possibilities between abatable emissions and abatement the effects are opposite. Emissions are more easily reduced by abatement, as is reflected by the lower price of permits, and hence the economic costs of environmental policy are lower. But again, the impact is only small, especially in the earlier periods. As can be seen in the last column, the differences with the results of the base specification are completely due to the environmental theme of climate change. Clearly, the specification of substitution elasticity for climate change is relevant for the model outcomes, but the elasticity for acidification is not. This shows that climate change is the binding environmental theme, and that the influence of acidification is much smaller. This is not surprising, given the differences in the 16 abatement cost curves: the reduction possibilities for acidifying emissions are more favourable (compare the technical potential, initial permit price and substitution elasticity for both themes). 4.3.3. Changes in autonomous pollution efficiency improvements The final sensitivity analysis carried out is on the specification of the autonomous pollution efficiency parameter. In the base specification, emissions grow at a slower speed than economic production, due to increasing efficiency in the use of environmental resources; in terms of emissions this means that the emissions associated with one unit of production or consumption decrease over time. Table 4. Main results of sensitivity analysis on pollution efficiency improvements alternative specifications base lower efficiency (volumes; bln. benchmark specification NLG) higher higher for both efficiency for efficiency themes both themes climate ch. only Equivalent Variation 0 -0.76% -6.25% -0.03% -0.06% GDP 1990 578 578 578 578 578 GDP 2020 1047 1043 1028 1046 1046 GDP 2050 1897 1866 1633 1894 1894 Abatement 1990 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 0.36 Abatement 2020 0.65 2.00 6.14 0.74 0.85 Abatement 2050 1.18 12.07 47.43 1.55 2.12 As a sensitivity analysis, the autonomous pollution efficiency parameter is lowered and increased with 0.5 percent-points per year. Table 4 shows how important this parameter is in the long run. If emissions follow economic growth more closely, the required emission reduction to achieve the environmental policy target increase. More emissions have to be abated, both abatable and unabatable. Abatement levels are much higher, and GDP is much lower, not in the last place because of the high price of pollution permits. The equivalent variation, which indicates the development of consumption over time, goes from –0.76% in the base specification to –6.25% if pollution efficiency improvements are smaller. The sensitivity analysis with higher pollution efficiency effectively removes the environmental policy for climate change: the benchmark emissions of greenhouse gasses are constant over time and hence no further reductions are required to keep to the policy target. For acidification still some emission reductions are required. Consequently, there are still some economic costs from environmental policy and there is still some abatement, but much less than in the base specification. The price of climate change permits does not drop to zero, as the number of permits is still restricted; the price of these permits are however roughly comparable to the price in the benchmark and much lower than in the base specification. 17 Comparing the last two columns shows that the economic costs of the acidification policy are small at either rate of pollution efficiency improvements. Again, the results show that climate change is the dominant environmental theme. 5. CONCLUDING REMARKS This paper shows how important characteristics of pollution abatement can be captured in a CGE framework. The extended calibration of the abatement possibilities is important, as it has significant effects on the estimation of the (sectoral) economic costs of environmental policies. When environmental policy remains limited in size, there are cheap abatement options available, and the effect on the rest of the economy is minor. However, the more strict environmental policy becomes, the more significant it is to get the best possible representation of abatement possibilities. The macro-economic impacts of high marginal abatement costs can be significant. The sensitivity analysis shows that the specification of environmental issues is highly relevant for climate change, as this is the binding environmental theme, but not so much for acidification. Increasing abatement efficiency will have an impact on the abatement levels and price, but not on the rest of the economy. Changes in the technical potential for emission reduction are however relevant for the economic impacts of environmental policy, but do not influence abatement levels as much. It should be noted that many improvements to the model can be made, both in the specification of the model and in the calibration for empirical analysis. One major issue to be investigated in more detail is the possibility to capture endogenous technology. Clearly, price induced technological change is of the highest importance when one wants to specify pollution abatement as realistic as possible16. The durable goods specification of abatement as presented in this paper provides endogenous balancing of investments in abatement capital and other capital and thus captures price-induced technological progress in a rudimentary way. However, it is beyond the scope of the current paper to capture these issues in all detail. REFERENCES Ballard, C.L. and L.H. Goulder (1985). “Consumption taxes, foresight, and welfare: a computable general equilibrium analysis”, in: J. Piggott and J. Whalley, New developments in applied general equilibrium analysis, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Barro, R.J. and X. Sala-i-Martin (1995). Economic growth. New York, McGraw-Hill, Inc. Baumol, W.J. (1977). Economic theory and operations analysis, Prentice Hall, London. Böhringer, C. (1998). “The synthesis of bottom-up and top-down in energy policy modeling”. Energy Economics 20, pp. 233-248. de Boer, B. (2000a). The greenhouse effect. Mimeo, Statistics Netherlands, Voorburg. 16 For instance, a high price of pollution permits will most likely lead to innovations of new abatement technology, there are spill-over effects of general technological development to abatement technology and learning effects. 18 de Boer, B. (2000b). Depletion of the ozone layer. Mimeo, Statistics Netherlands, Voorburg. Dellink, R.B. (2000). Dynamics in an applied general equilibrium model with pollution and abatement, Global Economic Analysis Conference, Melbourne, Australia. Dellink, R.B. and K.F. van der Woerd (1997). Kosteneffectiviteit van milieuthema's. R-97/10, Institute for Environmental Studies, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam. Groot, F., M.W. Hofkes, and P. Mulder (2001). “A vintage model of technology diffusion: the effects of returns to diversity and learning-by-using”, OCFEB Research Memorandum 30. Harrison, G.W., S.E. Hougaard Jensen, L. Haagen Pedersen and T.F. Rutherford (eds.) (2000). Using dynamic general equilibrium models for policy analysis, North-Holland, Amsterdam. Hyman, R. C. (2001). A More Cost-Effective Strategy for Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions: Modeling the Impact of Methane Abatement Opportunities, MSc-thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Jorgenson, D.W. and P.J. Wilcoxen (1990). “Intertemporal general eguilibrium modeling of U.S. environmental regulation”. Journal of Policy Modeling 12 (4), pp. 715-744. Manne, A.S., R. Mendelsohn and R.G. Richels (1995). “Merge:a model for evaluating regional and global effects of GHG reduction policies”. Energy Policy 23 (1), pp. 17-34. Meijers, H.H.M. (1994). On the Diffusion of Technologies in a Vintage Framework: A Theoretical Considerations and Empirical Results, PhD-thesis, Maastricht: Rijksuniversiteit Limburg, 104. Nestor, D.V. and C.A. Pasurka (1995). “CGE model of pollution abatement processes for assessing the economic effects of environmental policy”, Economic Modeling 12, pp. 53-59. Nordhaus, W.D. and Z. Yang (1996). “A regional dynamic general-equilibrium model of alternative climate-change strategies”. American Economic Review, pp. 741-765. Pasurka, C.A. (2001). ‘Technical change and measuring pollution abatement costs: an activity analysis framework’, Environmental and Resource Economics 18, pp. 61-85. Pigou, A. (1938). The economics of welfare, MacMillan, London. RIVM (2000). Milieubalans 2000 (in Dutch), Samson, Alphen aan de Rijn. Solow, R.M. (1974). “The economics of resources or the resources of economics”, American Economic Review 64. Srinivan, T.N. (1982). “General equilibrium theory, project evaluation and economic development”, in: M. Gersovitz, C.F. Diaz-Alejandro, G. Ranis and M.R. Rosenszweig (eds.), The theory and experience of economic development, Allen and Unwin, London. Statistics Netherlands (2001). National Accounts 2000, Statistics Netherlands, Voorburg. Tol, R.S.J. (1997). A decision-analytic treatise of the enhanched greenhouse effect, PhD-thesis, Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam. Verbruggen, H., R.B. Dellink, R. Gerlagh, M.W. Hofkes and H.M.A. Jansen (2001). “Alternative calculations of a sustainable national income for the Netherlands according to Hueting”, in: E. van Ierland, S.J. Keuning, J.v.d. Straaten, and H.R.J. Vollebergh. (Editors). Economic Growth and Valuation of the Environment. Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd., Amsterdam. 19 APPENDIX A1. SPECIFICATION OF THE RELEVANT EQUATIONS FOR THE BASE MODEL Producers Goods production functions: Yj ,t CES (Y1,IDj ,t ,..., YJID, j ,t , K j ,t , L j ,t , ES1, j ,t ,..., ESE , j ,t ; 1j ,..., Vj ) for each (j,t)17 (1) Zero profit conditions: 0 j ,t J p j ,t Y j ,t (1 jj , j ) p jj ,t Y jjID, j ,t (1 A, j ) pA,t YAID, j ,t jj 1 for each (j,t) (2) ESe, jh,t CES ( EeU, jh,t , CES ( EeA, jh,t , Ae, jh,t ; eA, jh ); eES, jh ) for each (e,jh,t), with eES, jh 0 (3) E (1 L , j ) pL ,t L j ,t (1 K , j ) rK ,t K j ,t pe ,t Ee , j ,t e 1 Environmental services ‘production’ functions: Other environmental equations E Y j ,t 1 (1 apeie,t 1 ) EeA, j ,t Y j ,t for each (e,j,t) (4) E Y j ,t 1 (1 apeie,t 1 ) EeU, j ,t Y j ,t for each (e,j,t) (5) E Wh ,t 1 (1 apeie,t 1 ) EeA,h ,t Wh ,t for each (e,h,t) (6) E Wh ,t 1 (1 apeie,t 1 ) EeU,h ,t Wh ,t for each (e,h,t) (7) A e , j ,t 1 U e , j ,t 1 A e , h ,t 1 U e , h ,t 1 In the benchmark projection the division of abatable and unabatable emissions is given by 18: EeA, jh ,t 17 E A e , jh ,t EeU, jh,t e, jh,t for each (e,jh,t) (8) As usual, ‘…’ is used to indicate all items within the range as given by the items listed before and after. A general nested CES production function with for example 4 inputs and 2 levels can be written as: Y = (a1X1+ a2X2+ a34X34)1/ , and X34 = (a3X3+ a4X4)1/ for some parameters a1, a2, a34, a3, a4, where =(-1)/ and =(-1)/. A convenient notation is: Y = CES(X1, X2, X34; ); X34 = CES(X3, X4; ). 18 Note that this division of emissions may be different in the policy simulations, as both parts are endogenously determined in the model. 20 Consumers Utility functions: Wh,t CES (C1,h,t ,..., CJ ,h,t , ES1,h,t ,..., ESE ,h,t ; h1 ,..., hV ) for each (h,t) U h CES (Wh,1 ,...,Wh,T ; hUtil ) for each h (9) (10) Income balances – expenditures side: J E j 1 e 1 phW,t Wh,t (1 j ,h t ) p j ,t C j ,h,t pA,t Ae,h,t pe,t Ee,h,t for each (h,t) (11) Income balances – income side: T phW,t Wh,t pK ,T K h,T (1 K ,h t ) pK ,1 t 1 T K h ,1 (r ) E T pe,t Ee ,h ,t t 1 e 1 t 1 LS h T (1 L ,h t ) pL ,t Lh,t t 1 T LS t for each h TRh ,t t 1 (12) Capital accumulation (as the volume of capital is free, the equation is written for the associated prices): pK ,t (1 K ) pK ,t 1 rK ,t for each t (13) Terminal condition on capital (transversality condition): H K h 1 H h ,T (1 g L ) K h ,T 1 (14) h 1 Demographic developments: Lh,t 1 Lh,t (1 gL ) for each (h,t) (15) Rule for development in government expenditures: W' govt ',t W' govt ',t determines t and tLS (16) Market clearance Goods markets balance: J H jj 1 h 1 ID Y j ,t Y jID , jj , t Y j , A, t I j , t C j , h , t for each (j,t); determines p j ,t (17) Capital markets balance: J H j 1 h 1 K j ,t K A,t Kh,t for each t; determines rK ,t (18) Labour markets balance: J H j 1 h 1 L j ,t LA,t Lh,t for each t; determines p L,t 21 (19) Pollution permits markets balance: JH JH H jh 1 jh 1 h 1 EeU, jh,t EeA, jh,t EeU, A,t EeA, A,t Ee,h,t for each (e,t) (20) determines p e ,t . Savings/investments balance: H S h 1 J h ,t p j ,t I j ,t for each t (21) j 1 Indices Label Entries Description j and jj 1,…,J,A Production sectors, including Abatement sector (A) j={Agriculture, Industry, Services, Abatement sector} h 1,…,H Consumer groups h={Private households, Government} jh (JxH) Combination of production sectors and households e 1,…,E Environmental themes e={Climate change, Acidification} vJ 1,…,VJ ‘CES-knots’ in production functions vJ={Economic inputs, Environmental inputs, Production} vH 1,…,VH ‘CES-knots’ in utility functions vH={Goods, Environmental inputs, Consumption} t 1,…,T Time periods t={1998,1999,…,2030} Parameters Symbol Description gL Exogenous growth rate of labour supply apeie ,t Autonomous pollution efficiency improvement; assumed equal across all agents e, jh,t Benchmark share of abatable emissions in total emissions for environmental theme e by production sector j / consumer h in period t K Depreciation rate r Steady-state interest rate IS Benchmark level investments (calibrated to steady-state) KS Benchmark level capital stock (calibrated to steady-state) Lh,t Exogenous labour supply by consumer h in period t Ee,h,t Endowments of pollution permits for environmental theme e by consumer h in period t 22 Symbol Description W' govt ',t Benchmark size of government sector in period t j Input share of good j for investments (by origin) K, j Tax rate on capital demand by sector j L, j Tax rate on labour demand by sector j jj, j Tax rate on input of good jj by sector j j, h Tax rate on consumption of good j by consumer h K ,h Tax rate on the supply of capital by consumer h L, h Tax rate on the supply of labour by consumer h hLS Lumpsum transfer from government to consumer h, H with hLS 0 and h 1 H h 1 LS h tLS 0 SUB Lumpsum transfer from (excess) private households to the subsistence consumer vj Substitution elasticities between inputs combined in knot vJ in production function for sector j e,A j Substitution elasticities between pollution and abatement for environmental theme e in production function for sector j hv Substitution elasticities between consumption goods combined in knot vH in utility function for consumer h (within same time period) e,Ah Substitution elasticities between pollution and abatement for environmental theme e in utility function for consumer h hUtil Intertemporal substitution elasticities in utility function for consumer h (between time periods) Variables Symbol Description Y j ,t Production quantity of sector j in period t Y jjID, j ,t Demand for input jj by sector j in period t L j ,t Labour demand by sector j in period t K j ,t Capital demand by sector j in period t I j ,t Investment originating in sector j in period t I h ,t Investment by consumer h in period t j,t (Net) profits in sector j in period t (equal to zero) 23 Symbol Description EeU, jh,t ‘Unabatable’ emissions of environmental theme e by sector j / consumer h in period t EeA, jh,t ‘Abatable’ emissions of environmental theme e by sector j / consumer h in period t Ae, jh,t Expenditures on abatement of environmental theme e by sector j / consumer h in period t E {note that Ae, j ,t YAID, j ,t and e 1 E A e 1 e , h ,t C A , h ,t } ESe, jh,t Emission services of environmental theme e by sector j / consumer h in period t Wh , t Welfare level of consumer h in period t Uh Total welfare of consumer h over all periods C j , h ,t Consumption of good j by consumer h in period t Sh,t Savings by consumer h in period t K h ,t Capital supply by consumer h in period t (in ‘flow’ terms: capital services) p j ,t Equilibrium market price of good j (including A) in period t rK , t Equilibrium market rental price of capital in period t pL ,t Equilibrium market wage rate in period t pe ,t Equilibrium market price of pollution permits for environmental theme e in period t p hW,t Equilibrium price of the ‘utility good’ (consumption bundle) t Endogenous change in existing tax rates to offset government income from sale of pollution permits in period t tLS Endogenous change in lumpsum transfers to offset government income from sale of pollution permits in period t TRh ,t Endogenous tax revenues for consumer h in period t (only nonzero for Government) 24 APPENDIX A2. DATA FOR THE BASE MODEL Table SAM(*,*) Benchmark accounting matrix (billion NLG) Agri. Indu. Serv. Abat. Priv.hh. Agri. 51.08 -32 -1 0 -18.08 Indu. -12 273.14 -67 -0.09 -194.05 Serv. -5 -45 415.98 -0.07 -315.91 Abat. -0.08 -0.14 -0.09 0.36 -0.05 Labour -8 -99 -176 -0.09 283.09 Capital -23 -74 -127.89 -0.11 225 lab.tax -1.5 -18 -35 0 0 cap.tax -1.5 -5 -9 0 0 Lumpsum 0 0 0 0 20 Rowsum 0 0 0 0 0 Table Y_DATA(*,J) Producer data Agri. Indu. Substit. elast. 0.5 0.5 Climate emis. 0.17 0.44 Acid emis. 0.43 0.26 Serv. 0.5 0.25 0.22 Govt 0 0 -50 0 0 0 54.5 15.5 -20 0 colsum 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Abat. 0.5 0 0 Table HH_DATA(*,H) Household data Priv.hh. Govt Savings 1 0 Substit. elast. 0.5 0 Intertemp. elast. 0.75 0 Climate emis. 0.14 0 Acid emis. 0.09 0 Table E_DATA(*,E) Environmental data Climate Acid Substit. elast. 1.26 1.4 Price 1.89 0.32 APEI 0.015 0.01 Abatable share 0.41 0.66 Tot. emis. 254 40 Note that the column in SAM for the consumers contains not just the consumption expenditures, but also the investments. Investments are calculated as Invsh j I 0 , where I 0 ( g ) K0 , and multiplied by Savshh for distribution over the consumers. Consumption expenditures can then be calculated as the residual of the total consumer’s expenditures. 25