Price Floors for Emissions Trading 1 Price Floors for Emissions Trading Pre-publication version of manuscript for Energy Policy Peter John Wood (Corresponding Author) Resource Management in Asia Pacific Program, Crawford School of Economics and Government, The Australian National University, Canberra, ACT 0200, Australia. Email: Peter.J.Wood@anu.edu.au Phone: +61 2 6125 6284 Fax: +61 2 6125 1635 Frank Jotzo Crawford School of Economics and Government, The Australian National University, Canberra, ACT 0200, Australia. Email: frank.jotzo@anu.edu.au Abstract: Price floors in greenhouse gas emissions trading schemes can guarantee minimum abatement efforts if prices are lower than expected, and they can help manage cost uncertainty, possibly as complements to price ceilings. Provisions for price floors are found in several recent legislative proposals for emissions trading. Implementation however has potential pitfalls. Possible mechanisms are government commitments to buy back permits, a reserve price at auction, or an extra fee or tax on acquittal of emissions permits. Our analysis of these alternatives shows that the fee approach has budgetary advantages and is more compatible with international permit trading than the alternatives. It can also be used to implement more general hybrid approaches to emissions pricing. Keywords: Price floor; hybrid emissions pricing; emissions trading. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 2 1. Introduction This paper examines issues associated with the implementation of price floors in emissions trading schemes. We look in detail at mechanisms for their implementation, and at the interaction with international permit trading. Price ceilings are a widely recognised option to limit the risk that carbon prices exceed acceptable levels if constraining emissions turns out to be more expensive than expected, providing greater cost certainty to emitters, and limiting the overall potential short-term economic cost of mitigation. The mirror instrument is a price floor, which would ensure a minimum price on carbon. Price floors would provide more certainty for investors in low emission technologies, and allow emissions to go lower than a given target, thus providing more abatement if costs are lower than expected. The basic concept of a combined system of price ceilings and floors in allowance trading goes back to Roberts and Spence (1976). Both price ceilings and price floors can reduce risk and price volatility in carbon markets, which has been of concern in the EU emissions trading system or ETS (Grubb and Neuhoff, 2006), and can thus make the introduction of ETS systems more acceptable. However, such ‘hybrid’ instruments also present specific challenges for scheme design and for trading of permits between countries, and in terms of their budgetary impacts. There has been considerable discussion of approaches that include a price ceiling, also known as a ‘safety valve’ (Aldy et al., 2001; Jacoby and Ellerman, 2004; Pizer, 2002; McKibbin and Wilcoxen, 2002; McKibbin et. al., 2009; Philibert 2000). Price ceilings have been proposed for various carbon trading schemes, for example in Price Floors for Emissions Trading 3 Australia (Commonwealth of Australia, 2008)1, and in less direct ways for the US Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI, 2008), and the Waxman-Markey Bill as passed by the United States House of Representatives in June 2009 (H.R. 2454, 2009)2. The academic debate on price floors is much less developed, though the concept of price floors has begun to find its way into policy and legislative proposals. One of the novel aspects of the Waxman-Markey Bill is that it stipulates a reserve price of US$10/tCO2-e when permits are auctioned, which would increase by 5% above the consumer price index each year. This reserve price could function as a price floor. The US Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI) scheme has a reserve auction price in place. In March 2010, approximately 40 million tons of CO2 allowances for the present compliance period (2009-2011) were auctioned at US$2.07 per permit, but approximately 2 million tons of CO2 allowances for the next compliance period were sold at the reserve price of US$1.86 per permit. Unsold allowances may be sold in future auctions according to each state’s regulations (RGGI, 2010). These price levels are substantially lower than prevailing prices under the EU ETS. The ETS that has been proposed for California is expected to have a price floor of US$10, which would be implemented as an auction reserve price that will increase by 5 percent above inflation per year. The Western Climate Initiative (an ETS proposed for 11 US states and Canadian provinces) would also have an auction floor price at a level that is yet to be specified (Hood, 2010). 1 The Australian emissions trading scheme proposal was shelved by government in the first half of 2010. 2 Complementary carbon pricing legislation has not achieved passage through the US Senate. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 4 Calls in early 2009 for a price floor to be introduced to the EU emissions trading scheme, via an auction reserve price, were rejected by the European Commission. The European Commission claimed that “a floor price may unduly interfere with the market” (Gardner, 2009). This argument seems to overlook that permit markets are entirely the product of government regulation in the first place – introducing a feature like a price floor simply means adopting a different design that will result in a different market outcome. The argument also runs counter to stated EU interests to achieve ambitious climate mitigation outcomes. Provisions for an effective floor price are under discussion in the United Kingdom (Rebuilding Security, 2010). By contrast, the ETS earlier proposed in Australia did not include price floor provisions. Analogous policies have also been implemented for renewable energy – Belgium has a minimum price for renewable energy certificates (Belgium Renewable Energy Factsheet, 2007). The next section reviews how a floor price in an emissions trading scheme could interact with various different policy objectives. In Section 3, we compare the different approaches for implementing a price floor. In Section 4, we examine in detail the mechanism where firms pay a tax or extra fee as well as buy permits; and discuss international permit trading, budgetary implications, and political economy considerations. Compared to the alternatives, this mechanism has budgetary advantages and is compatible with international permit trading. In Section 5, we examine how similar mechanisms could be used to implement more general hybrid approaches for putting a price on emissions. One such approach is to use an ‘allowance reserve’, which is similar to a price ceiling, but where the total number of permits remains limited. Section 6 concludes. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 5 2. Cost uncertainty, price volatility, and innovation Price floors would influence price volatility, innovation, and the management of cost uncertainty of greenhouse gas abatement policy. What instrument is chosen by a policy-maker depends on their policy objectives. A common objective is to deliver an economically optimal amount of emission reductions in an efficient manner, in the presence of uncertainty. But policy-makers may have other purposes, such as reducing emissions to a specific level, or promoting a specific technology. If the sole objective is to meet a pre-determined emissions target, then the possibility of the carbon price being lower (or higher) than expected is not a problem. But if the objective is to set a carbon price that approximates the marginal damages of greenhouse gas emissions, or more pragmatically to achieve a balance between abatement costs and emissions reductions, then a carbon price that is much lower (or higher) than expected may amount to policy failure. 2.1. Price floors and the economics of uncertainty At the level of economic theory, uncertainties about abatement costs and benefits affect the relative performance of abatement mechanisms in terms of their expected welfare impacts. Weitzman (1974) showed that there is an efficiency argument for setting the marginal cost of abatement rather than the quantity of abatement, when abatement cost curves are uncertain and the marginal damage function of emissions is relatively flat. It is generally thought that this is the case with climate change for the Price Floors for Emissions Trading 6 comparison between price and quantity instruments. In practice emissions pricing policies have mostly taken the form of cap-and-trade. Hybrid approaches under uncertainty were studied by Roberts and Spence (1976), who examined pollution reduction when the costs of pollution reduction are uncertain, but the benefits are known. It was found that the expected net benefits of using a hybrid approach with both a price floor and a price ceiling are significantly higher than for a purely price or quantity based approach. Quantitative modeling for climate change mitigation (Pizer, 2002; Burtraw et al., 2009; Fell and Morgenstern, 2009) is consistent with this conclusion. Modeling by Philibert (2008, 2009) shows that price ceilings and floors could help design a policy with similar probabilistic climate results at lower expected costs. Further, Philibert argues that price floors must be almost inevitably introduced to maintain the climatic effectiveness of the policy when price ceilings are introduced, on top of some tightening of the emission targets. Another interpretation of this point is that price floors are essential in mitigating the disincentive effects of a price ceiling which would truncate possible upside returns on low-carbon investment. The economics of climate change mitigation under cost uncertainty therefore suggests that hybrid approaches can be superior to both purely price-based schemes (carbon taxes) and purely quantity-based schemes (cap-and-trade); and that such hybrid approaches include price floors. The purpose of a hybrid scheme is not to approximate a price-based system, but to turn it into an approach that is superior to both price- and quantity-based schemes in terms on managing uncertainty. If it turns out that a given short to medium term target can be more easily reached than initially thought, the efficient response is to increase the abatement effort. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 7 Successful technological innovations lower the carbon price for a particular emissions target, or increase the amount of emission reductions achievable at a particular carbon price. The economically efficient response is to increase the amount of abatement, to keep the abatement cost in line with the social cost of emissions. Under a pure capand-trade approach, innovation will only increase abatement if the regulator adjusts emissions targets in response to a lower, or lower than expected, carbon price. A price floor by contrast provides a mechanism for additional emission reductions to be achieved automatically. However, it needs to be recognised that a price floor is no panacea for dealing with all uncertainties pertaining to mitigation policy. For example, a given minimum price may still fail to achieve a given policy ambition for overall abatement or for making specific technologies commercially viable. 2.2. Managing carbon price volatility Price floors (and ceilings) truncate the possible range of permit prices in the market and hence can reduce excess price volatility. Price volatility can also be reduced by banking and borrowing of permits; with short-term market fluctuations tempered through longer term price expectations. But recent experience with the EU ETS suggests that high levels of volatility still remain. The EU permit price ranged between €15 to €25/tCO2-eq from mid-2007 to early 2008, spiked at €30 in mid-2008, declined to a low of €9 in early 2009, and has ranged around €13-16 in the first half of 2010. The steep reductions in permit prices have in large measure been related to the global financial crisis, which contributed to lower emissions and also constrained financial resources for investment. The price falls occurred despite provisions for banking of Price Floors for Emissions Trading 8 permits being in place, which limits short-term downward fluctuation if markets operate properly. Without intertemporal flexibility, the dip in permit prices would likely have been larger. It can be argued that falling permit prices in times of economic downturn are desirable as an economic stabiliser. However, there are two important counterarguments. Firstly, it can be argued that policies should be designed in a way that keeps incentives for long-term investments stable through temporary business cycle effects. A short-term emissions price below the long-term optimum would exacerbate presumed problems of underinvestment in technologies whose costs come down with increased deployment (Sterner and Turnheim 2009). Second, an unanticipated economic slowdown allows emission reductions further than originally targeted at the same cost as originally expected. Under a specific mechanism design (variable extra fee, see Section 3.3) it would also be readily possible to use extra government revenue from implementation of a price floor to finance economic stimulus measures. 2.3. Increasing Certainty for Investors Investment certainty would be improved by price floors. Investments such as power plants, buildings, and infrastructure involve long-term time horizons. Uncertainty about the future carbon price increases costs for both investors in mitigation and investors in polluting technology. Policy design that reduces cost uncertainty can therefore limit the overall effective cost of achieving a mitigation outcome, and is more likely to attract political support from business constituencies. For example, the CEO of the oil and gas company Eni has proposed a combined global carbon tax and cap-and-trade system (Scaroni, 2009), where the carbon tax would function as a price Price Floors for Emissions Trading 9 floor. Coverage could differ between a carbon tax and a trading system, possibly with a broad-based tax and a trading scheme applying to sectors with concentrated emitters. In the light of recent failures or delays to implement carbon pricing policies in the United States and Australia, increasing political support from key constituencies may be a crucial advantage. A price floor gives investors in low-emission assets greater certainty about the minimum return to their investments – it effectively provides insurance against low carbon prices, analogous to the insurance function of a price ceiling against cost blow-outs to owners of existing high-emissions assets. 2.4. Other issues Coverage of a price floor is an additional issue to consider. It would be possible to implement a ‘selective price floor’, covering only some sectors of the economy. 3 Such an approach may be desirable if a price floor with full coverage is politically difficult, or if the objectives that can be met through a price floor apply particularly in selected sectors. However if the main objective is to minimise the net costs from mitigation and from climate change, then a price floor should apply throughout an emissions trading scheme. If objectives such as providing greater investment certainty relate only to specific sectors or activities, then this can be achieved through other policy instruments. Political and bureaucratic realities can lead to a carbon taxes and ETS’s having significantly different coverage. Ireland, which is also part of the EU ETS, introduced a carbon tax of €15 per tonne. This tax applies to fossil fuels, including fuels used for 3 Coverage of an emissions trading scheme may in itself be limited to emissions sources where transaction costs are low, chiefly emissions from fossil fuel use (including through permit liability upstream at the point of fuel distribution to indirectly cover small emissions sources) and industrial emissions. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 10 transport, but does not apply to electricity. This carbon tax meets the policy objective of increasing the coverage of a carbon price to new sectors of the economy (in this case transport). Other distinctions relate to whether a price floor is introduced when initially designing an emissions trading scheme, as opposed to the addition of a price floor to a pre-existing emissions trading scheme. The benefit from a price floor may be greater in a new emissions trading scheme, as the uncertainty in emission reduction costs will be greater. Nevertheless, introducing a price floor to an already existing emissions trading scheme (such as the EU ETS) could also help with meeting some policy objectives, though it must be balanced against concerns about excessive ‘fiddling’ with policy settings. Decisions may also be needed about the possible future removal of price floors and ceilings. The analysis in the rest of this paper starts from the assumption that policymakers want to implement a price floor, possibly in combination with a price ceiling, and examines what mechanisms and design options are best suited to achieve this. We set aside issues of coverage and evolution of policy settings over time. 3. Mechanisms for a price floor We compare three mechanisms for implementing a price floor in an emissions trading scheme: 1. The administrator commits to buy back licenses at the floor price, thereby reducing the amount of permits in the market (Hepburn, 2006). A similar approach is for the administrator to commit to pay a subsidy to firms that Price Floors for Emissions Trading 11 possess more permits than required to cover their emissions, the subsidy being proportional to the number of excess permits (Roberts and Spence, 1976). 2. A reserve price applies when permits are auctioned, again limiting the amount of permits available to emitters (Grubb and Neuhoff, 2006; Hepburn et al., 2006). This approach features in some current US policy proposals, and in an existing US scheme (RGGI). 3. Emitters have to pay an extra fee (or tax) for each ton of carbon emitted, in addition to having to surrender a permit. The effective carbon price then becomes equal to the sum of the permit price and the extra fee. This approach appears to have been largely overlooked in the current debate, though variants of it can be found in earlier academic contributions. 3.1. A commitment to buy back permits A commitment to buy back permits may be theoretically the ‘neatest’ way to implement a price floor, because it allows for the price floor to be implemented exactly with just one instrument. The market price will never go below the threshold price, and the administration of the floor price remains within the cap-and-trade scheme. However, the option would likely be unworkable in practice because of budgetary aspects and because it would stand in the way of international permit trading. A buy-back commitment would create potentially large contingent liabilities to governments, through budgetary costs of buying back permits in the market. This would be especially problematic where large shares of the total permits available are Price Floors for Emissions Trading 12 given out freely to start with, or where revenue from the initial sale of permits is earmarked for other purposes – one or both being the case for most existing and proposed emissions trading schemes. If the contingent budgetary liabilities are large, this might even undermine the credibility of the policy. International trading in permits would exacerbate the budgetary problems faced by any one country, as it would potentially create an unlimited liability for the administrator (Garnaut, 2008, p. 310). Even if the buy-back commitment is limited to domestic permits, international permits could be used by domestic emitters to substitute for domestic permits, effectively extending any one government’s liability overseas. For a commitment to buy back permits to be compatible with international trading, it would be required that all of the schemes involved have the same price floor (PricewaterhouseCoopers, 2009). This would be difficult to achieve in practice because of movements in exchange rates. Another way to address these issues is to not have international permit trading, which has also been advocated for other reasons (McKibbin et. al., 2009). However, this would fly in the face of a general trend and widespread desire by policymakers to link schemes internationally (Tuerk et. al., 2009), and would make it harder to achieve an internationally harmonized carbon price and the associated efficiency gains. 3.2. A reserve price at auction The reserve price approach is the one proposed for the United States under the Waxman-Markey Bill, implemented under RGGI, and considered but rejected by the European Union (see the Introduction). It would imply that there is no strict price Price Floors for Emissions Trading 13 floor, because although there would be a minimum price that firms would pay at auctions, the market price could fall below the reserve price. An advantage of having a reserve price is that independently of its function as a price floor, it is an auction design feature that can protect sellers and in some cases buyers from unexpected outcomes in the auction (Hepburn et al., 2006). To what extent a reserve price translates into a floor price in part depends on the share of permits auctioned. If a large proportion of permits are given out freely, then a situation could occur where few or no permits are in fact auctioned, given the reserve price. In this case, the market price would be above what it would be in a ‘pure’ cap-and-trade scheme with the full amount of permits available to emitters, but below the reserve price. International trade of permits could also result in the reserve auction price no longer being a floor price. If permits from another country’s scheme or offset credits such as from the Clean Development Mechanism can be imported at a price lower than the reserve price, then this will become the source of purchased permits in the domestic scheme rather than permits bought at auction from the government. Under this scenario, there is an important negative budgetary impact for the country attempting (but failing) to uphold a price floor, because rather than contributing to domestic government revenue through purchases at auction, emitters transfer money for permit purchases overseas. Overall, a reserve price will not lead to a strict price floor, but it will lead to a reduction in the quantity of permits when mitigation costs are low. It will limit downward price flexibility, provided that a sufficient share of permits are auctioned. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 14 3.3. An extra fee or tax Under this option, emitters have to pay an extra fee (or tax) for each unit of emissions, independently of or in addition to their permit obligations. We can write the effective carbon price as MC = p + t where MC is the marginal cost of abatement (the effective carbon price), p is the permit price, and t is the extra fee. Firms would be expected to engage in emission reductions if those reductions cost less than the sum of the permit price and the extra fee. There are fundamentally two ways that the price of the extra fee could be set: a) A fixed fee on emissions. The fixed fee is equal to the floor price: tfix = pmin. b) A variable fee on emissions. When the permit price in the market is less than the price floor, the extra fee is equal to the difference of the permit price and the floor price; when the permit price is above the floor, the fee is zero. We can write this as { tvariable = pmin – p if p < pmin, 0 otherwise; where tvariable is the extra fee, pmin is the floor price, and p is the permit price. 3.3.1. Fixed fee Price Floors for Emissions Trading 15 Under the fixed fee approach, the effective carbon price is prevented from falling below the level of the fee, and is always higher than the price of traded permits. The approach is similar to what transpires when both a carbon tax and an emissions trading scheme are in place simultaneously. The fixed fee approach is conceptually similar to the ‘emission permit rental charge’ proposed by Grafton and Devlin (1996), where holders of a permit are required to also pay a fee. Grafton and Devlin noted that this approach has advantages for rent capture in the case that permits are given out for free. The fixed fee approach is similar to having a call option to buy a permit at a fixed price, as described by Unold and Requate (2001). The difference is that what we describe as a ‘permit’ is described as an ‘option’ by Unold and Requate; and the fixed fee here is on emissions, while the fixed fee described by Unold and Requate is the price of what they call a ‘permit’. Under their approach, the carbon price would be equal to the ‘option’ price plus the ‘permit’ price, so the two approaches are equivalent when the fixed fee is an integral feature of the permit being surrendered. In the fixed fee context, it is worth noting that permit trading in any case already interacts with various taxes and subsidies that discourage or encourage activities that incur carbon emissions, for example energy taxes or subsidies. In that sense, the effective carbon price, relative to a hypothetical situation of no taxes and subsidies, can differ from the permit trading price, and it can differ between countries even if they have the same nominal carbon price in place (Babiker et. al., 2004). Several countries that take part in EU emission trading scheme also have a carbon tax, including Sweden, Finland, and the Netherlands (Baranzini et al., 2000; Stavins, 2003). In September 2009, France announced that it would introduce a carbon tax in Price Floors for Emissions Trading 16 2010 (Portail du Gouvernment, 2009), but this was postponed indefinitely in March 2010. 3.3.2. Variable fee The variable fee approach by contrast more closely achieves the effects of a ‘classic’ price floor, as a predetermined minimum price with no effect if market prices are above the threshold. It would be in operation only if and to the extent that the market price falls below the threshold level. A complicating factor is that permit prices fluctuate over time, and consequently the variable fee may have to change over time or be determined at a chosen point in time. There are several options for deciding what permit price is used when determining the extra fee: One option would be to use the permit price in the market on the date of permit surrender. But under this option, firms with market power could have an incentive to influence the market price near the compliance period to minimize fee payments. Another option would be to use the permit price that was paid by the firm when acquiring the permit – this would require that information about permit purchases is stored, possibly affecting transaction costs. An alternative is to use the average permit price over the time period in which emissions are being accounted for (usually a year). Price Floors for Emissions Trading 17 It would also be possible to charge the fee when the permit is bought from the government. This would be largely equivalent to having a reserve price at auction (as discussed above). The UK government is considering the implementation of the variable fee approach (Rebuilding Security, 2010)4. The UK takes part in the EU emissions trading scheme, and a minimum carbon price in the UK would be implemented by charging carbon emitters an extra fee (known as the ‘reformed Climate Change Levy’) at a level yet to be determined. Firms would be able to offset the costs of purchasing ETS allowances against their liability for the Levy. If the EU ETS price is above the level of the Levy no net charge would be payable; if it is below, the difference would be paid through the Levy to the Treasury. 4. Further analysis of the extra fee approach Perhaps the greatest advantage of the fee approach, compared to other methods of implementing a price floor, is that it can be fully compatible with international trading of permits. A fee or tax on domestic emissions can be implemented in any one country without affecting the international tradability of permits. It affects the price of permits in the international market only indirectly. What the fee will do is lower emissions independently of the trading scheme, and so reduce the demand for permits relative to the situation without a fee or tax. In the case of a country that imports permits from overseas, imposing an emissions fee will result in lower emissions and therefore fewer permit imports (Figure 1). This will tend to lower the (international) permit price, but only in line with that country’s share in international permit markets. 4 This is being considered at the time of writing (2010). Price Floors for Emissions Trading 18 Also, an extra fee does not affect arrangements for banking and borrowing of permits. In this section we shall discuss in more detail the issues of international permit trading; budgetary implications; and political economy. 4.1 Interactions with international permit trading When the carbon price is greater than the floor price, an additional fee/tax implemented in a purely domestic scheme (with no international permit trading), and without banking or borrowing, would leave the effective domestic carbon price (the marginal cost of abatement) unaffected (Figure 1a). The reason for this is that for a fixed emissions cap to be met within the system, the required marginal abatement cost remains the same irrespective of the pricing mechanisms applied. The introduction of a fee simply lowers the permit trading price by an amount exactly the same as the fee. By contrast, when there is a fee system in a country that takes part in international permit trading, the fee directly influences the effective domestic carbon price. The fee is in addition to the international permit price, which only partly changes in response, and thereby increases the effective domestic carbon price or marginal cost of abatement. In the case of a ‘small country’ participating in a large international permit market, the domestic fee is simply added to an unchanged international permit price (Figure 1b), so the effective domestic price is increased by the amount of the fee. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 19 Figure 1. We compare a purely domestic permit market with a large scale international permit market. The curved dashed line denotes the marginal cost of abatement. With a purely domestic permit market (a), the government sets a quantity of emissions eD, and an extra fee t. These quantities determine the carbon price (marginal cost of abatement), MC, and the permit price is given by pD = MC – t. Thus, the effective domestic carbon price is unaffected. By contrast, with unrestricted international trading of permits (b), the international permit price pI is determined in international markets. The domestic carbon price is given by MC = pI + t. This relates to a broader feature in systems where the overall system-wide emissions are capped, but distribution of effort between constituent parts (in this case countries) is not determined, as is the case under emissions trading. Imposing an extra fee will increase the effort in that country, and commensurately reduce effort elsewhere, if the global cap is not adjusted. The same is true for ‘supplementary’ measures such as national renewable energy support policies. Such divergence in marginal costs between countries is a source of economic inefficiency. Extra abatement will be undertaken in the country where the extra fee or tax is in place, at costs above what would be the case in countries where no such fee/tax is in operation. The magnitude of the distortion depends on the size of the difference in marginal costs. It also depends on the interplay with other taxes or Price Floors for Emissions Trading 20 subsidies, which may either exacerbate or run counter to the effect of emissions prices, and any differential between countries. Computable general equilibrium models could be used to help assess the likely magnitude of benefits from price floors that apply only in one or some countries, compared to the possible efficiency costs from divergences in effective marginal costs between countries, though it may be difficult to achieve consensus on empirical modelling results. In any event, the theoretical analysis presents a strong argument in favour of not just international harmonisation of emissions prices, but also of design rules of domestic trading schemes. The situation regarding international tradability would be different if the requirement to pay a fee was made an integral feature of the emissions permits. This is the case with the approach discussed by Unold and Requate (2001). If different countries attach different fee conditions to their permits, then emission permits from different countries are no longer the same commodity. International trading could still occur, either with different prices for permits from different countries, or with equal prices achieved through cross-border arrangements between countries on the charging, exempting and remitting of fees. These possible administrative complications present an argument in favour of separating any additional taxes and fees from the underlying permits, and in favour of levying such additional payments at the time of acquittal of the permit rather than at the time of issuing them. In that case, the permits themselves are then perfectly interchangeable between countries, only the conditions accompanying the liability for emissions differ between countries. However, we will see in the next section that making the fee an integral feature of the permit can be used to implement allowance Price Floors for Emissions Trading 21 reserves. If a policymaker decides to implement an allowance reserve in that way, it could be desirable to implement a price floor in that way as well. It could be argued that combining fees with permit trading would increase transaction costs by an unacceptable amount. However, given that general taxation systems for emitters already exist, and that permit trading systems are (or are likely to be) in existence, the extra cost impost is likely to be small. The main transaction costs are associated with measurement, reporting and verification, which are incurred only once for both aspects of carbon pricing. 4.2. Budgetary considerations The budgetary impacts of the fee models are positive or neutral. A fixed fee will yield a highly predictable revenue stream, while a variable fee will yield revenue in the event of low permit prices. Under a variable fee model, unpredictable government revenue from a variable fee poses challenges to fiscal management, however it could be an attractive feature in times of economic slowdown. If the emissions price falls because of a recession, as has recently been the case in the EU, then a variable fee provides additional revenue that could be immediately spent on fiscal stimulus measures. In other words, the extra money levied on emitters could be returned to consumers and industry, but without affecting the incentive effect of higher emissions prices. More generally, in the aftermath of large fiscal stimulus spending in all countries that have or are considering emissions trading schemes, implementing emissions charges in addition to permit trading could become an attractive option to help replenish public finances, though it would no doubt also be subject to hard political bargaining Price Floors for Emissions Trading 22 by concentrated lobby groups, as for example Australia’s recent experience in preparing an ETS has shown (Pezzey et al., 2009; Menezes et al., 2009). 4.3. Political economy The various options for implementing a floor price have distinct differences in the likely political economy that may enable or preclude their implementation. We only sketch some of the issues here. Reserve prices may have a distinct advantage in terms of their political economy, as their effect in upholding permit prices is not made strongly explicit in the marketplace. They also do not impose extra costs on emitters that receive free permits. For fixed emissions fees, the political economy is much the same as for carbon taxes, possibly with an added difficulty that emitters are seen to be charged twice, once through the tax and once through permit liability. A variable fee may generally prove easier to accept for emitters, as it would only apply in cases where the cost of permit liability is below the expected cost. 5. Floors, ceilings, and allowance reserves Some proposals for putting a price on emissions combine both a price floor and a price ceiling (Fell and Morgenstern, 2009), in what has been termed a ‘price collar’ (McKibbin et al., 2009). An alternative to a price ceiling is an ‘allowance reserve’ Price Floors for Emissions Trading 23 (Murray et al., 2009) in which there are extra ‘reserve’ permits, but the amount of extra permits is limited. Under the allowance reserve approach, the ceiling is no longer strict; if all of the extra permits are used, the carbon price could exceed the ‘ceiling price’. The mechanisms described in the preceding section for implementing a price floor can also be used for implementing an allowance reserve. The extra permits could be auctioned with a reserve price that is higher than the price floor; alternatively, firms could be required to pay a higher ‘extra fee’ if they use the extra permits to account for their emissions. Under the latter approach, the requirement to pay a fee would be an integral feature of the permit issued. The Waxman-Markey Bill includes an allowance reserve, known as the strategic reserve. Each year a small amount (1-3%) of permits would be added to the ‘Strategic Reserve Fund’ 5 . Each quarter, there is a strategic reserve auction, which auctions these permits at a higher reserve price than the reserve price of the rest of the permits. Roberts and Spence (1976) show in an appendix that by issuing an arbitrary number of different kinds of permit, it is possible to approximate any convex damage function arbitrarily closely (Figure 2). This could further increase the expected net benefits, by providing a better match between marginal costs and marginal benefits. It would also further reduce price volatility, and could reduce problems with market power (Krysiak, 2008). This could be implemented by auctioning different ‘tiers’ of permit at different reserve prices, or having firms pay different fees when they surrender different types of permit. The second approach is equivalent to the options approach 5 We are referring here to the version of the Bill that was passed by the U.S. House of Representatives on June 26, 2009 (H.R. 2454, 2009). The strategic reserve can also be replenished with unsold permits from auctions, and proceeds from strategic reserve auctions can be used to purchase offsets in order to replenish the strategic reserve. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 24 of Unold and Requate (2001). Under the second approach, extra administrative arrangements would be required for international permit trading, similar to those mentioned above. The proposed ETS for California would set aside approximately 5 percent of allowances as a reserve, that would be offered at fixed price in three price tiers: US$40/tonne, US$45/tonne and US$50/tonne. These prices would increase by 5 percent above inflation each year (Hood, 2010). The effect of a strategic reserve in reducing mitigation cost uncertainty may however be significantly weaker than under pure price ceilings, as indicated by Philibert’s (2009) modeling. But it could be possible to simultaneously have an allowance reserve of a fixed number of permits with a higher extra fee than the ‘normal’ permits, and an unlimited number (or a very large number) of ‘safety valve’ permits with a higher extra fee than the allowance reserve permits. When countries make use of safety valve permits, they should not be net sellers of permits on the international market (Jotzo and Betz, 2009; Philbert, 2000). An allowance reserve could facilitate international cooperation to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. International environmental agreements on issues such as acid rain and pollution of the North Sea have had weak binding commitments, but also have had ministerial level non-binding commitments that are significantly stronger (Victor, 2007). An allowance reserve could have the total number of permits based on a binding commitment, and the number of extra permits based on the difference between the binding and the non-binding commitment. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 25 Figure 2. The curved dashed lines represent alternative marginal abatement cost functions. The marginal abatement cost schedules will be unknown in advance, so two possible curves are shown. The lower curve corresponds to abatement being cheaper. The solid line illustrates the carbon price for different policy options. The carbon price and emissions level are determined by the point where the curves intersect. We illustrate a carbon tax in (a), the carbon price does not Price Floors for Emissions Trading 26 change for different marginal benefit curves but the amount of emissions changes; for cap-andtrade (b), the carbon price varies but the amount of emissions does not change; for cap-and-trade with a price floor (c), if the cost of abatement is sufficiently low, the amount of emissions will be lower than without the price floor; for a price ceiling (d), the upside risk for the carbon price is reduced but the quantity of emissions may be greater than without a price ceiling; a price collar (e) combines a price ceiling with a price floor; the price collar can be modified (f) so that the price ceiling is replaced with an allowance reserve; more general price curves (g), as described in the appendix to Roberts and Spence (1976), can also be implemented. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 27 6. Conclusions Price floors in emissions trading systems can reduce excessive price volatility, and provide better management of cost uncertainty in the event of lower than expected abatement costs, which in turn improves predictability of returns and increases expected returns for low-emissions investments. Price floors are natural complements to price ceilings, which limit price variability at the opposite end of the scale and reduce the incentives for low-carbon investments. Downsides include greater complexity, and the potential to exacerbate inefficiencies in global abatement through differences in effective emissions prices between countries, if price floors are implemented unevenly. Price floors need to be carefully designed to avoid budgetary liabilities, and to avoid barriers to international trade in permits. The most direct approach of a government commitment to buy back permits at a threshold price is unlikely to be viable, especially in the context of international permit trading, because it implies large contingent budgetary liabilities. An alternative approach of a minimum reserve price for auctioned permits, as pursued in the Waxman-Markey Bill, RGGI, and as was earlier considered by the European Union, could yield the desired effect, but only if the share of auctioning is large. An alternative, and possibly superior option is to require the separate payment of a fee or tax on domestic emissions, in addition to cap-and-trade. This approach carries desirable budgetary implications for national governments, and is fully compatible with international permit trading. In fact, this is precisely what governments do where they have a carbon tax of levy in addition to emissions trading. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 28 The fee or tax could be either fixed or variable, giving different results in permit markets and for government revenue, and posing different questions for implementation. A variable fee set equal to the difference between the market price for permits and the floor price allows the exact implementation of a floor price but may pose difficulties in defining the market price, and fiscal yields are difficult to predict. A fixed fee or tax by contrast will deliver predictable revenue streams, but raises the effective carbon price at any level of the traded permit price, which may not be desired by governments. The impact of an additional fee or tax on the effective domestic carbon price and domestic abatement depends on whether permits are traded internationally or not. In a purely domestic cap-and-trade scheme without international linkage, they will simply result in lower permit prices. With international emissions trading, they will result in a higher effective domestic permit price and more abatement in the country in question. The extra fee approach can also be used to implement allowance reserves, as well as more complex hybrid mechanisms. All in all, price floors could fulfil an important supporting role in ensuring effective and efficient climate change mitigation, they can be implemented without compromising vital aspects of emissions trading, and their budgetary properties might be attractive to governments. A final consideration relates to the political economy of carbon pricing. Recent failures and delays to legislate emissions trading in the United States and Australia can in part be traced to the influence of lobbying by highemitting industries and fears about the risk of high economic cost of climate change mitigation. While price ceilings can help address these concerns, price floors address the converse risk of lower than expected mitigation effort, and should thus find the support of industries that own low-emitting technologies and be able to alleviate Price Floors for Emissions Trading 29 concerns by environmental lobbies. These lobbies have however been shown to be generally much less influential in policy formulation, and hence price floors may still have a rocky road ahead before implementation. Acknowledgements We thank Warwick McKibbin, Jack Pezzey, Salim Mazouz, Erwin Jackson and Peter Heindl for helpful comments on earlier versions. Anonymous referees provided very helpful comments. This research was partially funded by the Australian Government Department of the Environment, Water, Heritage and the Arts through the Environmental Economics Research Hub. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 30 References Aldy, J. E., Orszag, P. R., and Stiglitz, J. E., 2001. Climate Change: An Agenda for Global Collective Action. Conference on 'The Timing of Climate Change Policies', Pew Center on Global Climate Change. Babiker, M., Reilly, J. and Viguier, L., 2004. Is international emissions trading always beneficial?. Energy Journal 25 (2), 33-56. Baranzini, A., Goldemberg, J., and Speck, S., 2000. A future for carbon taxes. Ecological Economics 32, 395-412. Belgium Renewable Energy Factsheet, 2007. Energy.EU Europe’s Energy Portal [Retrieved September 7, 2010 from http://ec.europa.eu/energy/energy_policy/doc/factsheets/renewables/renewables_be_en.pdf] Burtraw, D., Palmer, K., and Kahn, D., 2009. A Symmetric Safety Valve. Resources for the Future, [Discussion paper, retrieved October 13, 2009, from http://www.rff.org/News/Features/Pages/A_Symmetric_Safety_Valve.aspx]. Commonwealth of Australia, 2008. Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme – Australia’s Low Pollution Future. [retrieved September 14, 2009, from http://www.climatechange.gov.au/whitepaper/report/index.html]. Fell, H., and Morgenstern, R.D., 2009. Alternative Approaches to Cost-Containment in a Cap-andTrade System. Resources for the Future, Washington , DC. Gardner, S., 2009. Little support for carbon floor price. Ethical Corporation [retrieved 27 May, 2009, from http://www.ethicalcorp.com/content.asp?ContentID=6449] Garnaut, R., 2008. The Garnaut Climate Change Review, Cambridge University Press, Port Melbourne. Grafton, R. Q. and Devlin, R. A., 1996. Paying for Pollution: Permits and Charges. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 98 (2), 275-288. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 31 Grubb, M., and Neuhoff, K., 2006. Allocation and competitiveness in the EU emissions trading scheme: policy overview. Climate Policy 6, 7-30. Hepburn, C., 2006. Regulation by Prices, Quantities, or Both: A Review of Instrument Choice. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 22 (2), 226-247. Hepburn, C., Grubb, M., Neuhoff, K., Matthes, F., and Tse, M., 2006. Auctioning of EU ETS phase II allowances: how and why?. Climate Policy 6, 137-160. Hood, C., 2010. Reviewing Existing and Proposed Emissions Trading Systems. International Energy Agency Information Paper [retrieved November 28, 2010, from http://www.iea.org/publications/free_new_Desc.asp?PUBS_ID=2323]. H.R.2454, 2009. American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 (Waxman-Markey Bill) [retrieved September 14, 2009, from http://thomas.loc.gov/cgi-bin/query/z?c111:H.R.2454:]. Jacoby, H. D., and Ellerman, A. D., 2004. The safety valve and climate policy. Energy Policy 32, 481491. Jotzo, F., and Betz, R., 2009. Australia’s emissions trading scheme: opportunities and obstacles for linking. Climate Policy 9, 402-414. Krysiak, F. C., 2008. Ex-post efficient permit markets: a detailed analysis. Environmental and Resource Economics 39, 397-410. McKibbin, W. J., and Wilcoxen, P. J., 2002. The Role of Economics in Climate Change Policy. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (2), 107-129. McKibbin, W. J., Morris, A., and Wilcoxen, P. J., 2009. A Copenhagen Collar: Achieving Comparable Effort Through Carbon Price Agreements, in: Climate Change Policy: Recommendations to Reach Consensus, The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., 26-34. Menezes, F., Quiggin, J., and Wagner, L., 2009. Grandfathering and Greenhouse: The Role of Compensation and Adjustment Assistance in the Introduction of a Carbon Emissions Trading Scheme for Australia. Economic Papers: A journal of applied economics and policy 28 (2), 82-92. Murray, B.C., Newell, R.G., and Pizer, W. A., 2009. Balancing Cost and Emissions Certainty: An Allowance Reserve for Cap-and-Trade. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 3(1), 84-103. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 32 Pezzey, J. C. V., Mazouz, S., and Jotzo, F., 2009. The logic of collective action and Australia’s Climate Policy. Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports, 24, forthcoming in Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Philibert, C., 2000. How could emissions trading benefit developing countries?. Energy Policy 28 (13), 947-956. Philibert, C., 2008. Price Caps and Price Floors in Climate Policy: A Quantitative Assessment. International Energy Agency, Paris, France. Philibert, C., 2009. Assessing the value of price caps and floors. Climate Policy, 9, 612-633. Pizer, W. A., 2002. Combining Price and Quantity Controls to Mitigate Global Climate Change. Journal of Public Economics 84 (2), 197-216. Portail du Gouvernment, 2009. Le chef de l'Etat fixe la taxe carbone à 17 euros la tonne de CO2 [retrieved 6 October, 2009, from http://www.gouvernement.fr/gouvernement/le-chef-de-l-etat-fixe-lataxe-carbone-a-17-euros-la-tonne-de-co2]. PricewaterhouseCoopers, 2009. Carbon Taxes vs Carbon Trading: Pros, cons and the case for a hybrid approach [retrieved 27 May, 2009, from http://www.ukmediacentre.pwc.com/Content/Detail.asp?ReleaseID=3133]. Rebuilding Security, 2010. Rebuilding Security: Conservative Energy Policy for an Uncertain World [retrieved 18 August, 2010 from http://www.conservatives.com/~/media/Files/Green%20Papers/Rebuilding-Security.ashx?dl=true]. RGGI, 2008. Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative Model Rule [retrieved September 14, 2009, from http://www.rggi.org/docs/Model%20Rule%20Revised%2012.31.08.pdf]. RGGI, 2010. RGGI CO2 Auctions Yield Millions for Investment in Clean Energy, Job Creation. Media Release, RGGI Inc. [retrieved April 6, 2010 from http://www.rggi.org/docs/Auction_7_Release_MM_Report_2010_03_12.pdf] Roberts, M. J., and Spence, M., 1976. Effluent Charges and Licenses under Uncertainty. Journal of Public Economics 5, 193-208. Scaroni, P., 2009. Carbon tax: a global proposal. Oil 8, 16-19. Price Floors for Emissions Trading 33 Stavins, R. N., 2003. Experience with Market-Based Environmental Policy Instruments, in: Mäler, K. G., Vincent, J. (eds), Handbook of Environmental Economics, Volume 1, Elsevier, Amsterdam, 355436. Sterner, T., and Turnheim, B., 2009. Innovation and diffusion of environmental technology: Industrial NOx abatement in Sweden under refunded emission payments. Ecological Economics, 68 (12), 29963006. Tuerk, A., Mehling, M., Flachsland, C., and Sterk, W., 2009. Linking carbon markets: concepts, case studies and pathways. Climate Policy 9, 341-357. Unold, W., and Requate, T., 2001. Pollution control by options trading. Economics Letters 73, 353358. Victor, D. G., 2007. Fragmented carbon markets and reluctant nations: implications for the design of effective architectures, in: Aldy, J. E., Stavins, R. N. (eds), Architectures for agreement: Addressing Global Climate Change in the Post-Kyoto World, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 133-160. Weitzman, M. L., 1974. Prices vs. Quantities. The Review of Economic Studies 41 (4), pp. 477-491.