Comparing Patterns of Re-regulation of Labour in Three Liberal Market Economies Peter Waring, John Lewer and John Burgess University of Newcastle, Australia Abstract In November 2007, the Howard Coalition Conservative Government that had governed for eleven years was decisively defeated in the Australian federal election by the social-democratic Australian Labor Party led by Kevin Rudd. The election campaign was dominated by intense debate over the conservative government’s ‘Work Choices’ industrial relations reforms introduced in 2005 that radically re-regulated employment relations in favour of capital and which the then Rudd-led Opposition promised to dismantle. The removal of ‘Work Choices’ provides the third example of electorates within Anglo Saxon economies rejecting extreme neo liberal industrial relations legislation – the other two countries being the Britain and New Zealand. After waves of conservative reform which saw trade unions marginalised and bargaining structures remodelled in favour of Capital, the election of social democratic parties in these countries has brought increased state intervention and legislative promotion of equity considerations in employment relations. In each of these countries, however, it seems that elements of the legacy of neoliberalism have been retained, albeit tempered by a renewed interest in rebalancing equity and efficiency objectives. Neo liberal changes tend to be “sticky” to the extent that it is difficult to reverse legislation, to rebuild institutions that have been dismantled and move forwards with promised workplace reforms while at the same time demonstrating credentials for sound economic management. This paper analyses and compares the re-regulatory experiences of Britain, Australia and New Zealand as evidence of governmental intent to reclaim some employment relations aspects of the labour market and to strike a more centrist-balance between equity and efficiency objectives. It asks whether there are consistent patterns in the statutory provisions of Britain’s Employment Relations Act 1999, New Zealand’s Employment Relations Act 2000 and the foreshadowed legislation of the Rudd Labor Government. 1 Introduction Britain, Australia and New Zealand are capitalist economies and apart from a shared language, their constitutional and political (pluralist) pedigree is common and as Castles (1996: 234) notes ‘they tend to operate under single-party governments and still share a single head of state’. However, reflecting dynamic variables such as their peculiar social democratic structures and traditions, each has developed its unique approach and institutional mechanisms to managing the employment relationship between Capital and Labour and the inherent relations of power and class. None of each nation-state’s system is fixed, generating a long-standing scholarly pursuit (generally attributed initially to Kerr and Dunlop’s et al, grand theorising in Industrialism and Industrial Man [1962]) as to the degree of the each systems ‘natural’ convergence/divergence (see Bamber and Lansbury, 1998). More latterly, a not inconsiderable theoretical and empirical research agenda has sought to explain how these differing industrial relation systems have been shored up, modified or otherwise disassembled in the face of ‘globalisation’ (Wailes et al, 2008). Wailes and Ramia (2001), for example, tested the robustness of various competing theoretical frameworks by analysing change in the Australian and New Zealand systems since the opening up and deregulation of their economies in the 1980’s. Bray and Walsh (1998: 358) have similarly sought to compare the differing neo-liberal paths pursued in Australia and New Zealand suggesting political and industrial factors best explain ‘the speed of the journey and the destination reached in both countries’. Being located within this familiar field of comparative industrial relations, this paper seeks to, as Bean (1985: 7) drawing on Rose (1983) neatly states: ‘ . . .promote wider understanding of, and foster new insights into, industrial relations, either by showing what is unique about any one set of national arrangements or, equally well, reducing what might appear to be acutely specific and distinctive national characteristics by demonstrating their recurrence elsewhere.’ The purpose in this article is to trace the path back from a prior neo liberal industrial relations regime in each country. In the UK under the Thatcher government (19791996), in New Zealand under the National Party government (1990-1999), and in Australia under the Howard government (1996-2007) there were legislative programs designed to fundamentally transform the industrial relations system. As Tickell and Peck (1995) suggests there were many variants in neo liberalism across countries, each driven by a market ideology and the dismantling of the previous forms of public intervention in the economy. Geddes (2005) places the differences across countries in terms of welfare regimes, where the Australia, New Zealand and Australia are classified as liberal welfare regimes where there are limited forms of welfare support, services are marketised and there is a work focus behind the welfare system. However, Geddes (2005, 369) states that while the anglo Saxon nations of the USA, UK, Australia and New Zealand are core neo liberal welfare regimes, there are differences between them in terms of the extent of the welfare net, the prioritising of programs towards poverty reduction and the linkages between citizenships and responsibilities. 2 At a more general level there is an extensive literature around the varieties of Capitalism theme (Hall and Soskice, 2001), with many deviations and variations of the framework. Wailes et al (2008) discuss the strengths and weaknesses of the framework with one of the issue they highlight being the differences across what they call the liberal market economies. Neo liberalism is generally presented as a system based on market allocations and individualism, with a supporting policy framework of small government, low taxes and a welfare to work regime (George, 1999).The neo liberal system is supported and sustained by an array of well funded think tanks, large parts of the media and national and international institutions such as Treasury departments and the International Monetary Fund (George, 1999). Neo liberal policies are premised on the market being capable and effective for nearly all economic activities, and as a result the public sector requires restructuring and downsizing and an international agenda that supports free trade, free circulation of capital and freedom of investment (George, 1999). Larner (2000, 6) states that “neo liberalism is both a political discourse and about the nature of rule and a set of practices that facilitate the governing of individuals from a distance.” The premises and details of the neo liberal agenda are more extensive and nuanced to be detailed here (see Lloyd, 2008). Our context is the discussion of industry relations policy. Is there a coherent neo liberal industrial relations program? We apply the term neo liberal to each country for the recent period of conservative government in office since there was an emphasis on individualism, and each program was associated with common elements such as privatisation, restructuring the welfare system and the marketisation of many parts of the economy. The details and the processes attached to the neo liberal agenda were different in each country, and the timing of the changes was likewise different across the three countries. There was also a concerted attempt in each country to fundamentally transform industrial relations. Two key issues stand out in the changes to the industrial relations system, reducing trade union influence and participation, and reducing collective bargaining. Alternatively, we could state the aims as being de unionisation and increased individual and non union bargaining. What we are particularly interested in is the path back from this process. In each country opposition parties with strong linkages to trade unions came into office with a mandate to remove the neo liberal industrial relations framework. Is it possible to return to a previous industrial relations regime, particularly when institutions have been transformed and economies have moved on in terms of their structure? One case where this is apparent, as explored by Gough and Ogden (2008), is union management partnerships. While various forms of participation and co operation are encouraged in the co ordinated market economies, they are largely ignored in the liberal market economies with transactional market relationships being regarded as sufficient. However, how do you facilitate or return to forms of co operation and participation after trade union exclusion and individual contacts? A broad description and explanation of the legislative changes adopted post deregulation in each of the three countries is outlined in the first part of the paper. Understandably, given the constraints of this vehicle, the review represents a synopsis at best. The second part endeavours to analyse and evaluate the power of differing variables in explaining the legislative frameworks most recently enacted in Britain, Australia and New Zealand. 3 We use the terms re regulation in a generic sense to describe the post neo liberal phase in each country. This is not to suggest that the neo liberal phrase was exclusively about fewer regulations and the post neo liberal phase is about more regulations. In the Australian case of Work Choices the legislation was extensive and complex, and many aspects of industrial relations were more closely regulated than previously (we subsequently refer to this as command and control regulation). The post 2007 phase will involve the removal of many of these regulations. The Re-Regulation of Employment Relations in Britain British experience suggests a moderate attempt to re-regulate employment relations in that country. Observers have noted that the Blair Government largely won office in 1997 through a successful assault to capture the political middle ground. This strategy involved reconstituting Labor’s image by distancing itself from the British labour movement and promising policies which would only vary rather than replace Thatcher’s conservative industrial relations reforms (see Smith and Morton, 2001). Nevertheless, the enactment of the Employment Relations Act 1999 represents a significant re-balancing of the interests of Labour and Capital, imbued in the ‘social partnership’ philosophy, and a ‘third way’ shift towards the re-regulation of the British labour market (see for example Brown, 2000). For all its hype, the inadequacy of ‘third way’ thinking to properly intellectualise and problematise industrial relations is, in itself, an interesting phenomenon. Whilst key contributors to ‘third way’ thinking such as Giddens (1998) attempt to establish a platform for social democratic renewal, it seems that this platform clearly neglects the workplace (see Waring et al, 2001). Undy (1999:333) has speculated that this failure to focus on industrial relations in a systematic way underscores third way thinkers’ belief that it was no longer a significant issue. Globalisation and the steady disintegration of all forms of collectivism, according to Undy (1999), have meant that third way advocates have pushed industrial relations issues into the realm of the irrelevant. Nevertheless, it seems that the indirect implications of the third way philosophy have filtered down into the Blair Government’s approach to industrial relations in the UK. In particular Undy (1999:332) argues that New Labour’s third way response to Giddens’ dilemmas – globalisation and individualism - can be found within its industrial relations settlement, firstly through the adoption of the EU’s social chapter in 1997, and secondly, through the extension of individual rights at work. In this section, New Labour’s approach to industrial relations is evaluated in the context of its guiding third way philosophy. In particular, it seeks to understand how third way thinking has influenced the development and implementation of industrial relations institutions and policies, especially with respect to the diffusion of ‘partnership’ practices. An important precursor to the development of New Labour’s ‘industrial relations settlement’ was its signing of the EU’s Social Chapter in 1997. McKay (2001:291) has argued that New Labour’s commitment to the social chapter signalled its acceptance that ‘there was a social dimension to European integration’. The signing of the social chapter importantly committed the Blair government to introduce legislation consistent with EU directives on such issues as working time arrangements, parental leave and, perhaps more controversially, works councils. Besides signing the social chapter, the incoming Blair Government also established 4 a Low Pay Commission that was charged with investigating issues associated with the establishment of a National Minimum Wage. The National Minimum Wage was subsequently introduced in June 2000. This development has been responsible for an increase in the real wage for low paid workers, reduced wage inequality and a narrowing of the gender wage gap (Metcalfe, 2008). This has arguably been one of the greatest contributions of New labour towards addressing a social justice agenda and addressing a major gap in the UK industrial relations framework. Central to the Blair governments’ industrial relations reforms though, was the drafting of the Fairness at Work white paper which was subsequently passed, with some amendments, as the Employment Relations Act 1999 (ERA). It is within the detail and values of the ERA, that the influence of third way thinking becomes visible. For instance, the legislative changes incorporated in the Employment Relations Act were mostly focused on the extension of individual rights rather than measures designed to facilitate collectivism at the workplace. Brown (2000:301) notes, for example, that the new Act did not loosen the constraints on industrial action imposed by previous conservative governments. Indeed, the vast bulk of the Thatcher Government’s legislative restrictions on industrial action remain in place, causing Smith and Morton (2001:131) to claim that under the Act ‘the liberty of individual workers to take industrial action remains precarious, in breach of international standards’. Similarly, Undy (1999:330) has argued that the maintenance of restrictions on industrial action means that the ‘existing balance of bargaining power which favoured the employer is seen as appropriate’. Yet the Act also introduced, despite employer opposition, a statutory union recognition system consistent with New Labour’s belief that employees should be granted the right to choose whether they want to be represented by a union or not. Moreover, the mechanism is also consistent with the Blair’s governments’ goal to ‘foster a new culture of partnership in the workplace’ (Wood and Goddard, 1999:204). As explained by Wood and Goddard (1999:204), the statutory union recognition system is supposed to encourage voluntary recognition where there is a clear desire of employees to be represented by a trade union. However, if voluntary recognition is not achieved, a formal ballot can be undertaken requiring a majority vote of at least 40 per cent of those eligible to vote. Wood and Goddard (1999:204) also explain that this ballot will not be necessary where the union can demonstrate that it has majority support from employees. Alternatively Smith and Morton (2001:124) level the charge that the legislative detail of the statutory union recognition mechanism largely embodies the wishes of employers. They point to the restriction of the mechanism to employers of at least 21 workers; the associated reduced bargaining scope and other legislative hurdles as clear indicators that the mechanism is designed to limit the mobilisation of collective power. Despite these legitimate criticisms of the Act’s restrictions on collectivism, it did introduce a number of initiatives consistent with addressing Gidden’s globalisation and individualism dilemmas. In particular, the ERA extended parental leave rights, raised compensation levels for unfair dismissal and extended full-time employees’ rights to part-time employees. It is a moot point as to whether these new rights are the genuine product of a third way approach or simply a result of European Union directives. Brown (2000:304) contends that these new rights simply reflected the pressure of EU directives whilst McKay (2001:291) has claimed that although New Labour committed to the social chapter in 1997, it has ‘complied with European 5 proposals in a minimalist fashion, never exceeding what the European legislation required’. One EU directive that has been implemented more or less in line with European practice, has been the directive on the establishment of works councils. According to McKay (2001:291) the directive on European Works Councils came into force on the 15 January 2000 in the UK. Under UK law, employers with 1000 employees or more are required to establish Works Councils composed of both employee and management representatives. McKay (2001:292) estimates that around 300 UKbased companies will be required to establish these councils. The implementation of the Works Councils directive also seems to be largely in line with the Blair Government’s current enthusiasm for social partnership in the workplace. Guest and Peccei (2001:208) have observed, then-Prime Minister Blair has argued that the Employment Relations Act’s objective is to promote partnership in the workplace – to replace adversarial industrial relations with notions of cooperation and mutual gains. In order to promote partnership at work beyond the introduction of the ERA, the Blair Government has established a partnership fund to ‘stimulate a diverse range of partnership activities and initiatives’. The Trade Union Congress enthusiastically embraced the concept of partnership in its May 1999 manifesto ‘Partners for Progress: New Unionism in the Workplace’. It articulated six principles underpinning its conceptualisation of partnership for trade unions, viz.: (a) Employment Security (b) Commitment to the success of the firm (c) Openness and transparency (d) Recognition that partners have overlapping but distinct interests (e) Enhancing quality of working life (f) Tapping the motivation, commitment and innovation of employees to make work more interesting and to add value to the firm These are also the principles underpinning the UK union movement’s partnership agreements with individual firms which, according to Brown (2000:300), have assisted UK unions to stabilise membership after years of decline. However, the meaning of ‘partnership’, in Guest and Peccei’s (2001) assessment is not settled, and appears to be highly contested in UK discourse. They contend implicit and explicit unitarist, pluralist and hybrid assumptions inform different conceptualisations of partnership. Pluralist conceptualisation of partnership is largely rooted in the European development of industrial relations in terms of accepting the opposing interests of the parties and extending employee representation through works councils and representation rights. Guest and Peccei (2001:209-300) contend the second approach to partnership is informed by an explicit unitarist frame of reference. In this conceptualisation of partnership, employee and employer interests are integrated through profit sharing and or employee share ownership plans (ESOPs) and where employee participation and voice is limited to direct participation. Guest and Peccei claim that because there is more emphasis on the values and objectives of the organisation, this conceptualisation signals an imbalanced approach to partnership. The third approach to partnership is described by Guest and Peccei as a hybrid one which combines features of the unitarist and pluralist perspectives. For instance, 6 they contend that under the hybrid model, progressive human resource management practices are supported through mechanisms for joint governance (p210). It is this approach which Guest and Peccei argue, has underpinned the development of partnership in the UK. The differing perspectives on the notion of ‘partnership’ suggest that it may be simply a convenient vehicle for the industrial parties to pursue their own interests regardless of third way (ill-defined) ideals. This point is brought out by Guest and Peccei (1999:231), the results of an empirical analysis of practices and policies in place within firms that have embraced ‘partnership’. Their results indicate that under partnership agreements, more emphasis has been placed on employee contribution to the firm rather than the ‘promotion of employee welfare, rights and independent representation’. On the basis of this finding, they claim that ‘In many cases management would appear to be gaining more from the practice of partnership’ and that ‘the balance of advantage is skewed towards management’. This finding is also consistent with Smith and Morton’s (2001:120) broad thesis, that New Labour’s approach to industrial relations involves ‘measures that weaken workers’ collective power through the exclusion of autonomous trade unionism and initiatives to regulate the labour market, strengthen worker’s rights within the employment relationship and include enterprise-confined, cooperative unions as subordinate 'partners’. Moreover, the capacity for employers under the ERA to negotiate terms with individual workers enables them to undermine collective bargaining if they so wish. This capacity to ‘derogate’ from collective bargaining has led Smith and Morton (2001:130) to claim that this signals that ‘the logic of social partnership gives way to the flexibility of common law individualism’. One area where New Labour has been reluctant to address EU standards is the lack of protection for temporary workers. While EU directives call for equality of rights across workers, regardless of their employment arrangements, there was reluctance by the UK government to accede these rights to agency workers who constitute a substantial minority of the paid temporary workforce (around 20%) (Stanworth and Druker, 2004; Forde and Slater, 2006). The path back for New Labor has been assisted by the EU social regulations. But even here there can be observed a fairly minimalist approach towards the implementation of the regulations. In the area of trade union recognition and the rights to take industrial action the record has been patchy. The Low Pay Commission can be presented as a genuine innovation and a development that embraces traditional equity objectives. The Re-regulation of Employment Relations in Australia Altering bargaining structures has been a key policy priority of both sides of Australian politics since the election of the Hawke Labor government in the mid1980’s. In more recent years, policy debate over the direction and shape of bargaining structures intensified with the enactment of the Howard Government’s controversial federal Workplace Relations Act 1996 (WRA) and subsequently its Work Choices legislation, 2005. 7 Perhaps the most controversial innovation of the 1996 Act was the further shift towards individualisation through the introduction of statutory individual contracts (AWAs). This measure enabled employers (who were constitutional corporations) to offer individual contracts to their employees which, if accepted, would be registered with the Office of the Employment Advocate (OEA), then a new statutory agency established under the WRA 1996 (see Bray and Waring 1998, van Barneveld and Waring 2002, Peetz 2006). Procedurally, AWAs were required to pass a no disadvantage test in which the Office of the Employment Advocate would compare the contents of a proposed AWA with those of the relevant award and determine whether, on balance, the proposed AWA would result in any uncompensated disadvantage. AWAs were private and secret agreements, in so far as statutory penalties could be incurred if a party to an AWA divulged the contents of their AWAs to third parties. The main benefits of AWAs for employers are their ability to reduce trade union intervention as well as cut certain conditions of employment and expand managerial prerogatives, so long as there was no net financial detriment to employees. Common law individual contracts, by contrast, do not offer a right for employees to trade-off award conditions for financial or other compensation The introduction of statutory individual contracts in the WRA was coupled with a strong focus on ‘freedom of association’. Although both the positive and negative rights of freedom of association (the right of employees to join and the right not to join a trade union) were present within Part XA of the WRA 1996, it was very much the negative right not to join or to leave a trade union which was emphasised in government advertising and ‘education’ campaigns on this part of the Act. The Office of the Employment Advocate, aside from its role in registering AWAs, was also charged with investigating and prosecuting breaches of the freedom of association provisions. Bray and Waring (1998) have commented that when combined with stricter right of entry provisions and the removal of automatic union dues arrangements, the WRA ‘made it both easier to leave and harder to remain a trade union member’. Perhaps ironically, it was the positive right in the WRA which ultimately prevented Patricks Stevedoring Corporation, in the 1998 Waterfront dispute, to carry out its ambition to deunionise its stevedoring operations. Lang Corporation (the parent company of Patricks Corporation) (with the public support of the Howard Government and especially then Minister for Workplace Relations Peter Reith) had transferred the employment of its workforce through an asset sale to several special purpose companies it had established which then supplied labour to Patricks. Then on a single day in 1998, the labour supply contracts with these special purpose companies were severed, which had the consequence of placing these companies into liquidation and their workforces out of work. Patricks then moved in new non-union employees employed under AWAs into their stevedoring operations protected by high security arrangements. The Maritime Union of Australia challenged the company’s actions in the Federal Court and succeeding in arguing that the company’s restructuring was designed to injure the unionised workforce in employment based upon their union membership –a direct breach of the freedom of association provisions. The original decision of Justice North was later upheld by the Full Court of the Federal Court of Australia, and then on appeal by the High Court of Australia (see Dabscheck, 2000; McCallum, 1998; Wiseman, 1998). Apart from freedom of association, there were many other aspects of the Workplace Relations Act that were designed to restrict the power and activity of trade unions 8 include tight rules around union right of entry and the award simplification process that had the effect of removing union meeting time provisions from awards. Two other strong themes emerge in most analyses of the WRA. First, there was a substantial weakening of the powers of the Australian Industrial Relations Commission. The AIRC’s role had been reduced under the earlier Industrial Relations Reform Act 1993, but its arbitral power became much more circumscribed under the WRA – it was only permitted to arbitrate in the most narrow of circumstances when protected industrial action threatened a significant part of the Australian economy or the health and safety of the community. It was also charged with issuing s.127 certificates to prevent industrial action outside of the bargaining period that was ‘threatened, probable, likely or continuing’. The weakening of the AIRC led Dabscheck (2000) to announce the ‘death’ of the Commission, although other commentators (including Justice Kirby of the High Court of Australia) have claimed that news of the death of the Commission was very much overstated (see Bray et al 2005). A second significant theme of the WRA was the narrowing scope of awards. The Keating government had attempted to reform and modernise awards, but the Howard Government went much further by confining awards to just twenty core employment conditions – these were the only matters allowed to be included in awards. Matters deemed to be non-allowable included any award provision which facilitated trade union activity, including preferences clauses, automatic dues arrangements, meeting time and trade union education leave. These matters are important procedural rights for unions which enabled them to represent the interests of members, so removing them from awards weakened union capacity. In 1999, the Howard Coalition unsuccessfully attempted to introduce a raft of amendments to the WRA known as the ‘second wave’ reforms – these were placed before parliament in the Workplace Relations (More Jobs Better Pay) Amendment Bill. The proposals included the government’s wish to exclude small businesses employing 15 or less employees from the purview of unfair dismissal law, a range of harsher penalties for unions engaged in pattern bargaining and reforms designed to facilitate the spread of AWAs. If these proposals had been passed, they would have significantly advanced neo-liberal reform, with a greater focus on ‘command and control’ and individualist regulation. However, these ‘second wave’ reforms did not pass the Senate. In response, the Howard Government broke up the larger bill into smaller single-issue bills and re-presented them to parliament. With few exceptions, they were again unsuccessful. Indeed only 16 of 56 employment relations bills introduced to parliament were passed by the Senate during this period (see Bray and Waring, 2005). Some successful changes with respect to unfair dismissal laws were passed in the 2001 Workplace Relations Amendment (Termination of Employment) Act, which sought to discourage frivolous applications for unfair dismissal remedies, to prevent lawyers from acting for such clients and to extend the categories of employees who were unable to access these remedies. In 2002, the Workplace Relations Amendment (Registration and Accountability of Organisations)(Consequential Provisions) Act also imposed tougher procedural rules on unions. However, much of the Howard Coalition government’s employment relations ambitions remained unrealised until it won control of both houses of parliament in its stunning 2004 electoral victory. 9 The Work Choices Reforms, 2005-2007 In October of 2004, the Howard Coalition government won its fourth successive term with an increased majority and, more importantly, with control of both houses of parliament – a rare occurrence in the history of governance in Australia. This provided the Coalition with capacity to pass legislation unfettered by review from a hostile Senate. This control handed the Howard Government an historic opportunity to pass more radical employment relations legislation than they had foreshadowed in policy proposals in the lead-up to the 2004 electioni. For the Prime Minister John Howard especially, it was an opportunity to realise the achievement of a longstanding ambition (Williams 1997, Norrington 2006). It was not until 2006, however, that the highly anticipated and controversial Workplace Relations Amendment (Work Choices) Act 2005 (Work Choices hereafter) came into effect. The government’s rhetoric when introducing Work Choices focused on giving employers and employees greater ‘choice’ in determining wages and working conditions that best suited their circumstances, but the reality was that Work Choices strongly favoured employers, significantly reduced the influence and capacity of unions, and really only assisted employees with significant bargaining power. State governments (by this time all under Labor control) challenged the constitutionality of the reforms in early 2006, but in a split 5:2 decision (Kirby J and Callinan J dissenting), the High Court upheld the validity of the Work Choices amendmentsii. In essence, the majority confirmed the capacity of s.51xx (the corporations power) to fully regulate industrial relations. The decision validated the significantly extended reach of the new federal jurisdiction. Much has been written about Work Choices including legal analysis of its many provisions (see Stewart, 2006, Fenwick, 2006, Cooney, 2006, Waring and Bray, 2006a), its productivity consequences (see Burgess and Waring, 2005; Peetz, 2006, ch.3), its impact on trade unions (Forsyth and Sutherland, 2006), collective bargaining (Cooper and Ellem, 2007) and state-based employment relations systems (Lee, 2005), its impact on the Australian Industrial Relations Commission (Cooney, 2006) and on women (Elton et al. 2007). Several of these observers noted that Work Choices did not facilitate a deregulatory approach in which there was a return to the common law of contract, rather Work Choices introduced ‘command and control’ regulation in which the state seeks to control actors and bargaining outcomes. In essence however, Work Choices represented an unprecedented attack on trade union and collective bargaining rights. Work Choices, among other things, abolished the ‘no disadvantage test’, sought to expand individual contracting while deemphasising collective bargaining and awards, abolished compulsory arbitration, abolished unfair dismissal protection for workers employed in business with 100 workers or less and introduced new and reduced minimum standards in the form of the Australian Fair Pay and Conditions Standard. Work Choices quickly drew the ire of the trade union movement who responded with a multi-million dollar campaign funded largely through member levies entitled ‘Your Rights@Work’ and involving mass rallies, leaflets, billboards, bumper stickers and print, radio, television and internet advertising. The television advertisements typically featured employees who had been unfairly dismissed without any recourse or whose family life had been disrupted by unfair employer demands. The 10 advertisements clearly struck a chord with the electorate as Brett (2007:74) observed that ‘Opinion polls and survey data consistently showed that WorkChoices was supported by only about 20 per cent of voters’. Throughout the election campaign the Work Choices legislation was a both a divisive and defining issue that clearly differentiated the two major parties (MacCallum, 2007). On the evening of the election held on 25 November, 2007, it quickly became apparent that the Howard Government’s eleven year term of office would come to an end. Moreover, the Prime Minister John Howard would suffer the rare humiliation of losing his own seat of Bennelong in an historical parallel with Prime Minister Stanley Bruce who lost his seat as Prime Minister in 1929 after also introducing controversial employment relations laws. ACTU exit polling at the election showed that 78 per cent of voters rated Work Choices as one of the top three issues while 45 per cent stated that it ‘was their highest priority’ (West, 2007). A consensus of political commentary indicates that employment relations and especially the Work Choices reforms were central to the downfall of the Howard Government in November of 2007 (see Norrington and Hannan, 2007; Mac Callum, 2007; West, 2007; Brett, 2007). Brett (2007:62) summarises this contention arguing that: ‘Work Choices, Howard’s industrial relations revolution was the biggest misjudgement of his political career and goes a long way to explaining why nothing went right for him in 2007. Without the constraint of the Senate, he succumbed to the hubris of power. The reforms were not part of the Coalition’s policy for the 2004 election, and they tilted the balance of power in the workplace decisively towards employers. Opposition to them stubbornly persisted, despite the spin and the massive government advertising campaign, undermining the general credibility of Howard and his government’. On December 3, 2007, the Rudd Labor Government was sworn into office and with this the Hon Julia Gillard was appointed Deputy Prime Minister and Minister of a new ‘super portfolio’ combining education with employment and workplace relations. On the 13 February, Minister Gillard introduced the first legislative steps to dismantling Work Choices with the reading of the Workplace Relations Amendment (Transition to Forward with Fairness) Bill 2008 . The bill is an interim measure before a more comprehensive replacement for the Workplace Relations Act designed to fulfil the policy taken to the election and which has been promised to be introduced late in 2008. The Bill passed Parliament on 19 March 2008 and from this day, no new Australian Workplace Agreements (AWAs) could be made. Instead, the act introduced Individual Transitional Employment Agreements (ITEAS) that are to be made available during the transitional period between the introduction of the Transition to Forward with Fairness Act and 31 December 2009 – the last date before more comprehensive reform is to commence. 11 The act also re-introduces the ‘no disadvantage test’ for ITEAS and for collective agreements and abolishes the Howard Government’s ‘Fairness Test’. Under s346D, ITEAs or collective agreements pass the no disadvantage test if the Workplace Authority Director (the successor to the Employment Advocate) is satisfied that the agreement does not result in balance in a reduction of overall terms and conditions of employment of the employee under any ‘reference agreement’. Reference agreements are defined in the act as any relevant collective agreement or if there is no relevant collective agreement, any designated award. Hence, the new ‘no disadvantage test’ incorporates a critical change from its predecessor in making the basis for comparison a collective agreement rather than an award – an acknowledgement that developments in wages and conditions in collective agreements have outstripped those of awards but also closing a regulatory gap which historically has permitted agreements with less beneficial terms in previous collective agreements on the grounds that they were superior to relevant awards. Moreover, the act repeals the concept of ‘protected award conditions’ since the whole of the designated award would be considered for the purpose of the no disadvantage test in the absence of a relevant collective agreement. The act also removes the capacity for employers to unilaterally terminate collective agreements requiring instead applications for termination to be made to the Australian Industrial Relations Commission. Further, the act introduces new provisions regarding award modernisation. Under the amendments, the Australian Industrial Relations Commission is charged with creating new modern awards which will seek to protect 10 entitlements including penalty rates and overtime. As part of the Rudd Government’s ‘Forward with Fairness’ policy, Minister Gillard released ten draft National Employment Standards (NES) on February . As indicated earlier, the Rudd Government has stated that its safety net will comprise the ten National Employment Standards (which will replace the Australian Fair Pay and Conditions Standard) and modern awards (which will provide industry–specific detail and may contain up to a further ten minimum standards above the NES. The NES are statutory entitlements which cannot be altered or excluded by any industrial instrument or contract of employment. 12 The ten draft NES’s and associated explanation are set out in the table below: Table 1 National Employment Standards National Employment Standard Commentary Maximum Weekly Hours 38 hour week to remain the standard for fulltime. Employees may be required to work reasonable hours in excess of the standard but cannot be required to work unreasonable additional hours. Requests for Flexible Working Arrangements Right of employees to request flexible working arrangements from their employer until their child reaches school age. Employers may refuse on ‘reasonable business grounds’. Parental Leave and Related Entitlements Will allow individual parents to be absent from work for separate periods of up to 12 months of unpaid parental leave. Annual Leave Four weeks paid annual leave in accordance with accepted community standard. Personal/Carer’s Leave and Compassionate Leave Ten days of paid personal/carer’s leave for each year of service. Two days of paid compassionate leave per occasion (eg. Death or serious illness of family member). Two days of unpaid carer’s leave ‘per occasion’ for genuine caring purposes or family emergencies. Community Service Leave Right to be absent from work to engage in prescribed community service activities such as jury service and emergency service duties. Long Service Leave Long Service Leave provisions to be preserved. Public Holidays Right of employee to be absent from work on a day declared a public holiday. Notice of Termination and Redundancy Pay Entitlement of fair notice of termination and redundancy pay in accordance with 13 2004 Redundancy Test Case. Fair Work Information Statement Employees entitled to a statement (published by Fair Work Australia) on their rights and entitlements in the workplace to be distributed by the employer to each new employee upon commencing employment. It is proposed that the ten final NES’s will be fully operational by 1 January 2010 when the other component parts of the Rudd Government’s employment relations system commence. Aside from these developments, the general tenor of the Rudd Labor Government’s approach to employment relations may be viewed in its submission to the Australian Fair Pay Commission’s Minimum Wage Review on 14 March 2008. In the submission, the Government suggests that the Commission should grant an increase in minimum wages to assist the low paid in sharing in economic prosperity but also warns that the Commission should have regard to inflationary pressures in the Australian economy (Australian Government, 2008). The Government does not recommend the quantum of any minimum wage increase but rather provides the Commission with economic data to help its decision-making. This approach signals an effort to convey a balanced approach to employment relations matters but the submission also signals considerable agreement with neo-liberal economic assumptions regarding the negative relationship between wages and employment levels and the potential for minimum wage increases to fuel inflation. An important issue to consider is the extent to which the ALP has followed their British counterparts in adopting third way thinking to industrial relations policy. An explicit point of difference between New Labour and the ALP therefore lies in the party’s different attitudes towards collective bargaining. Although the promotion of collective bargaining forms a key element of the ALP’s ‘Forward with Fairness’ policy, Smith and Morton (2001:123) point out that the Employment Relations Act expressly does not favour collective bargaining. Importantly, Smith and Morton (2001:125) have also argued that the scope of collective bargaining has narrowed with the act confining collective bargaining ‘to market (economic) relations, to the exclusion of managerial relations’. Although it is too early to make a decisive judgement, it seems that the ALP’s industrial relations approach has not been heavily influenced by New Labour’s industrial relations ‘settlement’. More particularly, it seems that Gidden’s thesis of growing individualism in society has not weakened the ALP’s resolve to remove Australian Workplace Agreements – statutory individual contracts – from the Australian industrial relations scene and reinforce collective bargaining as the preferred modus operandi. In this regard, it seems that third way thinking has not 14 filtered down into the ALP’s industrial relations policy setting in the same way it has for Blair’s New Labour government. The differences between the Rudd Labor Government’s reform proposals and that of New Labour may lie in the strong and almost universal belief that the Howard Government’s downfall was caused by Work Choices and the successful trade union campaign against it. Moreover, in the absence of strong evidence of a need for such reform and a relatively robust Australian economy, Work Choices seems to have fallen victim to what has been labeled as ‘reform fatigue’ in the Australian electorate. This phenomenon has also been labeled as a ‘spirit of disengagement’ and ‘strategic withdrawal’ by the renowned Australian social observer, Hugh Mackay (see Mackay, 1999:300). Further, the differences may also lie in the stronger purchase the left wing of the ALP seems to have in Government as a consequence of the perceived authority and status of the Deputy Prime, Julia Gillard. In the immediate aftermath of Labor’s victory, doubts emerged over whether the new government would continue to recognise the importance of the union movement’s campaign in its historic win. Former Treasurer Peter Costello commented that ‘Rudd would seek to rewrite history’ while John Robertson, Secretary of Unions NSW argued that the only difference between John Howard and Kevin Rudd was ‘this guy (Rudd) doesn’t want to kill us’. Similarly, the national secretary of left-wing union, the Construction, Forestry Mining and Energy Union told a forum in July 2008, that ‘On industrial relations policy, the Rudd Labor Government is considerably better than Howard but not as supportive as Labor governments of past eras.’ (Davis, 2008). This concern was also evident in a media release of the ACTU on 15 July 2008 which presented the findings of a Galaxy Poll of a thousand adult respondents commissioned by the ACTU. The poll provided support for the immediate dismantling of Work Choices rather than follow Labor’s plan to introduce comprehensive reforms in 2010 and points to the trade union movement’s frustration with the Rudd Labor Governments transition plans (ACTU, 2008). There remain significant areas of industrial relations regulation from the Howard government that remain in place. Two areas that have attracted attention are first the extensive regulations governing the right of entry and strike activity that remain in place (ACTU, 2008a). Second, the controversial Australian Building and Construction Industry Commission (ABCC) will remain in place until 2010. This organisation was given extensive and special powers for regulating the construction sector, including trade unions (currently one unionist faces imprisonment for not revealing to the authority the details of what was discussed at a union meeting). (Davis, 2008) The third issue on which there appears to be little progress are the gaps that are present in the regulatory framework that allow many workers to be excluded from employment rights and protections (see the paper by Iain Campbell at this conference). In general, the peak union body, the ACTU, has expressed a sense of frustration at the slow pace of industrial relations reforms with the window for significant change (2010) being long enough to allow for the institutionalisation of union exclusion processes and the continuation of individual agreement making (ACTU, 2008b; ACTU, 2008c). 15 In summary, the Rudd Government’s transitional legislation and its promises for more comprehensive reform in 2010 suggest that while measures to protect equity are high on its agenda, there will not be a return to twentieth century arbitration or extensive privileges for trade unions. Rather, there will be a stronger safety net in the form of a revitalised ‘no disadvantage test’ and national minimum standards, and greater emphasis on collective bargaining and the workplace rights this implies. Only time will tell whether Work Choices represented the ‘high watermark’ of neo-liberal reform and whether the Rudd Government’s reforms will indeed ‘get the balance right between fairness and flexibility’ or simply moderate the path taken by earlier governments. The Re-regulation of Employment Relations in New Zealand Of all the OECD countries, New Zealand implemented the most radical set of neoliberal ‘reforms’, in the process diverging markedly from its ‘sister’ Australian industrial relations system and discarding conciliation and arbitration institutions which had operated continuously from the late nineteenth century. A Labour government, elected in 1984 established the foundation of the reform agenda. Initially by rejecting any form of corporatist cooperation with the industrial wing, the government set out to partially deregulate the labour market by enacting the Labour Relations Act 1987. It did determine though to maintain a number of union security mechanisms. These included exclusive bargaining rights and compulsory unionism provisions in awards. Chief driver of change was the abolition of compulsory arbitration that the government anticipated would generate substantially decentralised bargaining structures. However, through a number of trade union coping strategies, especially by emphasising awards rather than enterprise agreements as the preferred source of employment conditions, the deregulation policy outcomes were frustrated. The interests of Capital, particularly embodied in groups such as the New Zealand Business Roundtable railed against the government for not securing change consistent with the deregulation achieved in New Zealand’s product and financial markets. Their message promoted the proposition that the labour market continued to be beset by employment reducing rigidities, inflexibilities and in dramatic need for radical reform (Bray and Walsh: 1998). Employer militancy and dissatisfaction with the trade unions’ resistance meant that after its electoral success at the October 1990 election, the conservative National Party was unswervingly focussed on a market ideology mandate and radical deregulation. This it achieved by enacting the Employment Contracts Act 1991 (ECA) which cast off a century’s set of union security rights and dramatically refocussed the ‘web of rules’ from collectivism (standardised, union-based awards) to individualism (especially non-union individual contracts). Unlike the earlier legislation which emphasised providing procedures for the ‘orderly conduct of relations between workers and employers’, and accountability by the parties, the ECA’s purpose was to promote an efficient labour market, freedom of association and employee choice of who (if anyone) should represent them. In summary the Act: discontinued trade unions’ rights to exclusive representation by providing workers with the capacity to unilaterally decide their bargaining agents, abolished compulsory unionism and created an individual bargaining stream with provisions designed to encourage its adoption. Section 18(2) of the ECA, for example, specifically prohibited 16 an employer from being required to become involved in any negotiations for a multiemployer agreement. The state, ironically given their ideological passion for deregulation, did continue to maintain a role by enacting a minimum employment code (including a minimum wage, annual leave entitlements and prohibition on certain forms of discrimination) and by creating industrial relation tribunals with widespread jurisdiction to interpret and enforce employment contracts. In response to a New Zealand Council of Trade Unions (NZCTU) complaint lodged in 1993, an ILO Committee on the Freedom of Associationiii found that the ECA was in contravention of a number of ILO Conventions which New Zealand had ratified, viz Convention 87 (rights of workers to organise freely) and Convention 97 (workers organisations are separate and protected against employer retribution). The Committee determined, inter alia, that the Act did not promote collective bargaining, provided inadequate protection for workers against employer discrimination when undertaking union activities, unduly limited the right to strike and placed undue limitation on the rights of unions to organise. It recommended the legislation be amended to satisfy the requirements of both Conventions, but given the nonmandatory status of ILO determinations, the New Zealand government took no action. The President of the CTU commented, ‘the recommendations . . . were a strong attack on the credibility of the Employment Contracts Act’ and suggesting ‘it is very relevant at the end of the this decade that international agencies are warning against the infatuation with globalisation, the obsession of competitiveness and the casting aside of values’ (Wilson, 2000: 87 and 80. See also, Honeybone, 1997). Unlike the earlier Labour Relations Act, the ECA overcame resistance and highly marginalised New Zealand’s industrial relations system from the OECD mainstream. By 1997, as a result of both pieces of legislation, the internationally distinctive and previously durable system of compulsory conciliation and arbitration had been abolished with single employer collective agreements and individual contracts all but supplanting multi-employer agreements and awards. Evidence cited in Honeybone (1997) for example demonstrates the proportion of workers covered by collective, multi-employer, unionised awards/agreements collapsed from 59 per cent in May 1991 to only 6 per cent in August 1993. The number of unions declined from 227 to 83 (in part through amalgamation) and density dramatically declined to 20 per cent of the workforce from over 44 per cent in the mid 1980’s (Honeybone: 1997 and Bray and Walsh: 1998). Industrial stoppages fell from 193 with 366,000 working days lost in 1986 to 42 and 24,000 working days lost in 1997 (Bradford, 1999: 160). In Boxall’s assessment the ECA heightened the bifurcation of the labour market around skill with the talented ‘rewarded’ and ‘comfortable’ whilst the less skilled and less organised experiencing ‘greater difficulty exercising appropriate voice and accessing their employment rights generally’ (Boxall, 2001: 27). Overall, Fryer and Haynes (2000: 122) conclude that the ‘ECA swept away the vestiges of the old system and replaced it with a decentralised, contract-based system founded on the individualisation of the employment contract . . .the impact of the ECA was dramatic.’ In November 1999 a Labour/Alliance coalition government, committed to repealing the ECA was elected. Max Bradford, the Minister for Labour in the National Party government had sought to defend the ECA as being a ‘model for flexible labour market legislation’ by generating jobs, creating flexibility, reinforcing individualistic freedom of choice and by empowering business with the right to develop workplace 17 arrangements best suited to their unique needs (Bradford, 1999). Whilst the Labour Party plainly indicated their dissatisfaction with the deregulatory assault of the ECA, they were equally keen to dispel any fears of a reinstating a pre-reform set of industrial relations arrangements. Their labour relations spokesman, responding to some NZ Employers Federation ’mischief’, starkly pronounced that ‘Labour will not return, directly or indirectly, to compulsory unionism, compulsory arbitration or national awards’ (Hodgson, 1999: 174). Explaining the Employment Relations Bill to a forum of the N.Z. Employers’ Federation, the Minister dismissed the then ECA legislative framework as embracing the seductiveness of ‘simplicity’, being ‘a poor foundation for progressive business management’ and for ‘failing to deliver the increase in productivity that (was) promised by its advocates’. The new legislation would be framed on the overarching theme that the employment relationship ‘is a human relationship . . . (which) functions best in an atmosphere of mutual trust, confidence and fair dealing’ and that ‘most employers will recognise that an employee who is committed to the enterprise . . able to make full use of their skills, and willing to contribute ideas is a more valuable one’ (Wilson, 2000). The new act would attempt to restore balance in the employer employee relationship and recognise the rights to union membership and collective bargaining (Wilson, 2004). In the first year of office, the new government repealed the ECA and enacted the Employment Relations Act 2000 (ERA) The detail of the major changes introduced by the ERA are explained in Appendix 1. The law set out a number of key objectives, including; to build productive employment relationships through the promotion of mutual trust and confidence in all aspects of the employment environment . . ., by recognising that employment relationships are built on good faith behaviour, by acknowledging and addressing the inherent inequality of bargaining power in the employment relationship, and by promoting collective bargaining. The broad thrust and specific new institutional arrangements demonstrate the ERA represents a shift back to a more regulated, collectivised but not centralised system. The Act returns the monopoly right to unions to collectively bargain (although individual agreements are still allowable), reinstates unions’ rights to organise (for example by right of entry provisions), requires employers to bargain in good faith and facilitates multi-employer bargaining with worker assent. This mix of strategies will generate a renewed legitimacy for collectivism. ‘Free-riding’ is less likely and unions gain a psychological fillip from being rewritten into the employment relationship as making a positive contribution. This is the principal discontinuity from the ECA. Walsh and Harbridge (2001:355) conclude: ‘…the bargaining provisions of the ERA provide a basis for unions to repair some of the damage done to their movement during the last decade. The Act 18 proceeds from the premise that employment relationships involve inherent inequality and that collective organisation by trade unions is the most effective way to redress this inequality’. In the subsequent evaluations of the Employment Relations Act there are three features that stand out. The first is that the dramatic decline in the trade union density that occurred under the ECA has not been able to be reversed under ERA. While the number of trade unions has increased and the decline in density has stopped (May, 2004), it will not be returning to pre ECA levels. Trade union membership remains concentrated in the public sector and in manufacturing (may, 2004). There has been no coming back for trade unions in many workplaces and in many sectors. May (2004) discusses an incumbency effect whereby a whole generation of workers commenced employment in the context of trade union absence and an individual bargaining regime. Second, and related, union bargained collective agreements have also been slow to return. Non union and individual bargaining remains an important feature of the New Zealand system. Third, the free rider problem remains, the coverage under union collective agreements exceeds the trade union density, and the extent of free riding has not been appreciably been reduced under ERA (Wilkinson et al, 2003). In the New Zealand case the re regulation of industrial relations did not bring about a revival in either trade union membership or collective bargaining. Authors such as may (2004) acknowledge the far reaching impact of the ECA on New Zealand workplaces and industrial relations. While the aim of the ECR was not to return New Zealand to the pre ECA era (Wilson, 2004), it is apparent that in practice the ECA has a enduring presence. In this context it is not surprising that the New Zealand path is towards legislative rights in such areas as parental leave, holiday leave and OH&S standards (Howarth, 2004). Comparing Re-regulation in Britain, Australia and New Zealand Perhaps not unusually, it appears that those countries that had highly deregulated labour markets, have only partially, re-regulated, or at least returned to the regulations that were present in the pre neo liberal era. Again, in all three cases the elected Labor party governments announced that they would not be returning to the past. The discussion was generally put within a context of modernisation and developing strategies to cope with globalisation (Wilson, 2004). Table 2 seeks, in the form of a taxonomy, to summarise the key shifts in the industrial relations systems operating in Britain, Australia (including the states) and New Zealand. he variables on the y axis, degree of collective bargaining and the like, have been chosen as they perhaps best reflect the principal measures of a government’s approach to how employment conditions will be determined, the degree of encouragement of individualism, whether trade union are tolerated or despised and how workers may seek relief against unfair dismissal. Each factor is measured in terms of the degree to which the most recent legislative change has shifted (if at all) the pre-existing regulatory environment. In New Zealand, for example, the Employment Relations Act has clearly reinstituted a number of trade union rights. The table should be regarded as an aid to the analysis rather than as a 19 definitive template. Plainly, to distil complex legislation and bargaining arrangements into a single cell necessitates broad tolerances and a degree of subjective measurement. Also, the impact and actual operation of these institutional frameworks needs to be mitigated against the ‘realities’ of organisational and personal power relationships, the capacities and resources of all the actors (especially the regulatory agencies) to achieve their objectives and relevant social norms such as community tolerance of failure by unions and employers to comply. Table 2 Comparing Britain, Australia and New Zealand post Conservative Governments Employment Relations Dimensions Policy Britain Collective Bargaining Individual Contracts Australia New Zealand Moderate facilitation via trade union recognition Encouraged (central bargaining mode but nonunion collective agreements permitted) Retained Will be Abolished in 2010 – Retained but retained 2008-2009 deemphasised Encouraged Regulation of Industrial Neo-liberalist (ie. little Action change) Limited Right to Strike Moderate weakening of Neo-liberalist policy Trade Union Recognition Statutory system (complex) Strengthened Right of Entry Strengthened Right of Entry Encouraged through partnership Encouraged Encouraged Strengthened Strengthened Strengthened Euro-Works Trade unions Councils/Trade Unions Trade unions Good faith bargaining Unfair Dismissal Employee Representation 20 From table 2 there are similarities and differences attached to the post Conservative industrial relations agendas in the three countries. The degree of change and the speed of change also differ. Each country (to different degrees) seeks to facilitate collective bargaining; each moved away (to different degrees) from individual contracts; industrial action remains regulated in each country; good faith bargaining is strengthened as is unfair dismissal protection. Conclusion – Accounting for the Presence of Convergence and Divergence Whilst the general trend towards re-regulation is unusually consistent across the three countries compared, there remain significant differences in form that regulation has taken. This raises the important question of how to account for the co-existence of these similarities and differences. One potential explanation for the parallel experiences in the three countries is the influence of third way type thinking on government policy. The argument is perhaps most persuasive in the British case, where New Labour’s entire political platform has been informed by third way thinking. Although, as previously contended, third way advocates have rarely contemplated industrial relations issues, the acceptance and facilitation of growing individualism at the workplace is a feature of the UK’s Employment Relations Act 1999. In Australia, third way ideas have been promulgated by current and former office-bearers of the ALP such as Tanner (1999) and Latham (1998), both of whom have said little about the translation of third way ideas into the industrial relations arena. Indeed, most discussion seems to dwell on changing the welfare system to reflect the third way principle of mutual obligation. Similarly, there is little evidence to suggest that third way thinking has influenced the industrial relations policy of NZ Labour in government. Indeed it would be drawing a very long bow to argue that key principles of third way politics have filtered down into, and significantly influenced, the reregulation policies of the antipodean labo(u)r parties. A more persuasive account of the simultaneous finding of similarities and differences in Britain, Australia and New Zealand lies in new institutionalist theory, which Wailes (2000) has argued is characterised by the methodology of ‘common pressure, divergent response’. Wailes and Ramia (2001:133), for example cite Locke and Thelen (1995) who have argued that whilst globalisation has created ‘uniform economic pressures for increased flexibility, the types of flexibility sought and the degree of success achieved differ from country to country, state-societal differences being the main explanatory differences’. During the 1980s and 1990’s in the three countries under analysis, similar economic and ideological pressures were addressed through de-regulatory economic policies. But, although these policies were similarly inspired by neo-liberalism, their impact on the type and extent of de-regulation differed according to the countries various institutional arrangements and history. For instance, New Zealand’s unicameral as opposed to Australia’s bicameral parliamentary system has been identified by Bray and Walsh (1998) as a significant factor in facilitating New Zealand’s radical labour market deregulation in 1991. Similarly, in Britain the absence of a compulsory arbitration system to provide institutional legitimacy to trade unions perhaps made it easier for the Thatcher conservative government to crush the mineworkers union in 1984-5. 21 If it is accepted that institutional arrangements and history help explain the three nation’s divergent responses to prevailing economic pressures in the 1980’s and 1990’s, the question remains as to what common pressure(s) has facilitated a general trend towards re-regulation? Part of the explanation appears obvious – political cycles in Britain and New Zealand have more or less tracked each other, with Australia as the laggard, such that Labo(u)r parties in government have moved to re-regulate labour markets. Underlying Labo(u)r’s electoral success however, is perhaps a more fundamental phenomenon which has emerged as a result of rationalism – that is, a general cynicism of neo-liberalist policies and associated reluctance to countenance further de-regulation. This is somewhat speculative but there is some evidence to support this position. In Britain, for instance, the popularity of cultural epithets to the Thatcher years such as the film ‘Brassed-off’, and in the title of Blair’s ‘Fairness at Work’ policies, are a reflection of community experience of neo-liberalism. Similarly, in Australia the rationalisation of Work Choices did not fit with the everyday work experiences of Australians and was largely seen as an act of hubris by a government unconstrained by the Senate. In New Zealand, continuing economic weakness in spite of radical neo-liberalist policies has depleted any goodwill the electorate may have had towards further de-regulation. There are a range of institutional factors which help explain the type and extent of reregulation evident in each country. The significant contribution of the trade union movement to Rudd Labor’s success signalled that a Federal Labor government would re-regulate the Australian labour market to a greater extent than has been the case in Britain. However, even here the speed and the extent of change remains an issue. “Your Rights at Work” campaign that was influential in the 2007 election still retains its website and continues to highlight what it sees as the ongoing abuse of employee rights and conditions associated with the retention of the Work Choices legislation (Your Rights at Work, 2008). New Labour’s conscious decision to distance itself from the British labour movement has meant that the British trade union movement is unable to exert as much influence as it once enjoyed. Similarly the influence of supra-national institutions such as the European Union, has clearly been pivotal to the form that re-regulation has taken in Britain. Why is it difficult to remove or to turn back neo liberal industrial relations programs in a post conservative era? In all three countries the newly elected governments had strong ties with trade unions and a commitment to fairness and rights at work. We would suggest that there are three reasons for the neo liberal resilience. First, the various Labor party’s were and remain adherents to a globalisation and a modernisation agenda. In Australia many of the major neo liberal and deregulation programs were introduced through the government of the Australian Labor party (Ramsay and Battin, 2005). Second, the ability of the neo liberal agenda to transform industrial relations cannot be understated. In New Zealand whole sectors were de unionised and a whole generation of employees worked without trade union contact (May, 2004). Third, Labor parties are anxious to develop their economic credentials with the electorate and the business community (Ramsay and Battin, 2005; Waring, 2005), as a result radical reforms are avoided or eschewed in favour of gradualism. 22 References ACTU (2008a), Employers are taking advantage of restrictions on union entry to cut rights at work. http//:www.actu.asn.au/media/mediareleases accessed August 24th ACTU (2008b), Big employers continue to snub labor government by using Work Choices to deny worker’s rights. http//:www.actu.asn.au/media/mediareleases accessed August 24th ACTU (2008c), Time to deliver on new workplace laws. http//:www.actu.asn.au/media/mediareleases accessed August 24th Bamber, G.J. and Lansbury, R.D. (eds.) (1998) International Comparative Employment Relations: A study of industrialised market economies, 3rd edition, Allen and Unwin, Sydney. Bean, R. (1985) Comparative Industrial Relations, Routledge, London. Beazley, K. (2000) Inaugural Fraser Lecture, Canberra Labor Club, 31 May, http://www.alp.org.au/media/0500/kbspifl310500.html. Boxall, P. (2001) ‘Evaluating Continuity and Change in the Employment Relations Act 2000’, New Zealand Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 26, No. 1, pp. 27-44. Bradford, M. (1999)’National Labour Market Policy’, New Zealand Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 24, No. 2, pp. 155-165. Bray, M. and Walsh, P. (1998) ‘Different Paths to Neo-Liberalism? Comparing Australia and New Zealand’, Industrial Relations Vol. 37 No. 3. pp.358-87. Brown, W. (2000) ‘Putting Partnership into Practice in Britain’ British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 38, No.2 June. pp. 277-299. Buchanan, J. and Watson, I. (2001) ‘The failure of the third way in Australia: implications for policy about work’, ACIRRT, University of Sydney. Castles, F.G. and Pierson, C. (1996) ‘A New Convergence? Recent Policy Developments in the United Kingdom, Australia and New Zealand’, Policy and Politics, Vol. 24, No. 3, pp. 233-246. 23 Davis, M. (2008), Backbench Revolt Looms for Labor Over Building Watchdog. Sydney Morning Herald. August 22. Department of Productivity and Labour Relations (DOPLAR) (2001) The Changing Industrial Relations System: what to expect, DOPLAR, Western Australia. Forde, C. and Slater, G. (2006), The nature and Experience of Agency Work in Britain: What are the Challenges for Human Resource Management? Personnel Review. 35, 2, 141-157. Fryer, G. and Haynes, P. (2000) Takeaway Fueds? Labour Relations in the New Zealand Fast Food Industry under the Employment Contracts Act 1991, Proceedings of the 15th AIRAANZ Conference, Wollongong January 31 – February 3rd. Geddes, M. (2005),. Neoliberalism and Local Governance: cross national perspectives and speculations. Policy Studies. 26, 3-4, 359-377. George, S. (1999), A Short History of Neo Liberalism. Conference on Economic Sovereignty in a Globalising World. Bangkok, March. Glover, D and Patmore, G (eds) The Future of Social Democracy, Pluto Press, Sydney. Gough, R. and Ogden, M. (2008), Partnership, Bargaining and Production in Liberal Market and Co ordinated market Economies. In S. Marshall, R. Mitchell and I. Ramsay eds. Varieties of Capitalism, Corporate Governance and Employees. Melbourne University Press, Melbourne, 39-59. Green, R. and Wilson, A. (1999) Labor’s Trojan Horse: The ‘Third Way’ on Employment Policy, in Guest, D. and Peccei, R. (2001) ‘Partnership at Work: Mutuality and the Balance of Advantage’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 39 No. 2, June, pp. 207-236. Haworth, N. (2004), Beyond the Employment Relations Act: the Wider Agenda for Employment Relations and Social Equity in New Zealand. In E. Rasmussen ed. Employment Relationships. Auckland University Press, Auckland, 190-205. Hodgson, P. (1999) ‘Labour’s Labour Relations’, New Zealand Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 24, No. 2, pp. 173-180. 24 Honeybone, A. (1997) ‘Introducing labour flexibility: The example of New Zealand’, International Labour Review, Vol. 134, No. 4, pp. 493-507. Kerr, C, Dunlop, J.T., Harbison, F.H., and Myers, C.A. (1962) Industrialism and Industrial Man, Heinemann, London. Larner, W. (2000), Neoliberalism: policy, ideology, governmentality. Studies in Political Economy. 63, 5-25. Latham, M. (1998) Civilising Global Capital, Allen & Unwin, Sydney. Lloyd, C. (2008), Australian Capitalism Since 1992: A New Regime of Accumulation? Journal of Australian Political Economy. 61, June, 30-55. MacCallum, M. (2007), Poll Dancing: the Story of the 2007 Election. Black Inc, Melbourne. McKay, S. (2001) ‘Between Flexibility and Regulation: Rights, Equality and Protection at Work’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 39 No. 2 June, pp.285-303. May, R. (2004), Trade Unions and the Employment Relations Act. In E. Rasmussen ed. Employment Relationships. Auckland University Press, Auckland, 159-172. Metcalf, D. (2008), Why has the British National Minimum Wage had Little or No Impact on Employment? Journal of Industrial Relations. 50, 3, 489-512. Peetz, D. (2006), Brave New Work Place. Allen & Unwin, Sydney. Ramsay, T. and Battin, T. (2005), Labor party Ideology in the Early 1990s: Working nation and paths Not Taken. Journal of Economic and Social Policy. 9, 2, 143-160. Rose, M. (1983) Review, British Journal of Industrial Relations, XXI, cited in Bean, R. (1985) Comparative Industrial Relations, Routledge, London. Smith, P. and Morton, G. (2001) ‘New Labour’s Reform of Britain’s Employment Law: The Devil is not only in the Detail but in the Values and Policy Too’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 39 No. 1 March. pp.119-138. Stanworth, C. and Druker, J. (2004), Temporary Agency labour in the UK. In J. Burgess and J. Connell eds. International Perspectives on Temporary Agency Work. Routledge, London, 54-71. Tanner, L. (1999) Open Australia, Pluto, Sydney. Tickell, A. and Peck, J. (1995), Self Regulation after Fordism: regulation theory, neo liberalism and the global-local nexus. Economy and Society. 24, 3, 357-386. 25 Undy, R. (1999) ‘New Labour’s ‘Industrial Relations Settlement’: the Third Way?’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol 37 No. 2. Wailes, N (2000) ‘Economic Change and Domestic Industrial Relations Institutions: Towards a Theoretical Model’, Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol 24, No. 2 pp. 214233. Wailes, N., Kitay, J. and Lansbury, R. (2008), Varities of Capitalism, Corporate Governance and Employment Relations Under Globalisation. In S. Marshall, R. Mitchell and I. Ramsay eds. Varieties of Capitalism, Corporate Governance and Employees. Melbourne University Press, Melbourne, 19-38. Wailes, N. and Ramia, G. (2001) Comparativism and globalisation: An integrated framework for comparing Australian and New Zealand industrial relations, Proceedings of the 15th AIRAANZ Conference, Wollongong January 31 – February 3rd. Walsh, P. and Harbridge, R. (2001) ‘An Assessment of the Bargaining Provisions in the Employment Relations Act 2000’, in Kelly, d (ed) Proceedings of the 15th AIRAANZ Conference, 31 January to 3 February, Wollongong, Australia. pp. 349356. Waring, P. (2000) ‘The Future of Bargaining Structures in Australian Employment Relations’ Work Futures Conference, Cardiff Business School 15th Annual Employment Research Conference Cardiff, Wales September 6-7th. Waring, P. (2005), Labour Market Programs versus Industrial Relations Reform. The Rhetoric and Reality of Working Nation. Journal of Economic and Social Policy, 9, 2, 55-72. Waring, P., Ostenfeld, S., Lewer, J. and Burgess, J.(2001) ‘The Third Way, Employment and the Workplace in Australia’, Economic and labour Relations Review. 12, 2, 174-192. Wilkinson, D., Harbridge, R. and Walsh, P. (2003), Labour Market Re-regulation and its Effects on Free riding in New Zealand. Journal of Industrial Relations. 45, 4, 529538. Wilson, M. (2000) Address to the Employers’ Federation, 24 May 2000, http://www.labour.org.nz/ Wilson, M. (2004), The Employment Relations Act: a Framework for a Fairer Way. In E. Rasmussen ed. Employment Relationships. Auckland University Press, Auckland, 9-20. 26 Wilson, R. (2000) ‘The Decade of Non-compliance: the NZ Government record of Non-compliance with International Labour Standards 1990-98’, New Zealand Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 25, No. 1, pp. 79-94. Wood, S. and Goddard, J. (1999) ‘The Statutory Union Recognition Procedure in the Employment Relations Bill: A Comparative Analysis’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 37 No.2, June, pp. 203-245. Your Rights at Work (2008), http//:www.rightsatwork.com.au/ Accessed August 25th. 27 Endnotes i For this reason, the opposition parties would later argue that the Howard Government had no mandate to introduce Work Choice. ii New South Wales v Commonwealth of Australia; Western Australia v Commonwealth of Australia [2006] HCA 52 iii Case No. 1698 in 292nd Report of the Committee on Freedom of Association (1994) reported in Wilson, R. (2000) ‘The Decade of Non-compliance: the NZ Government record of Non-compliance with International Labour Standards 1990-98’, New Zealand Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 25, No. 1, pp. 79-94. 28