Multinational corporations control structure choices under uncertainty environment Ma Jianhua1, Ai Xingzheng2 1. Management and Economics, University of Electronic Science and Technology of China, Chengdu, China 2. Management and Economics, University of Electronic Science and Technology of China, Chengdu, China 1. majianhuamail@126.com, 2. aixz@uestc.edu.cn Abstract: For a multinational corporation manufacturing and selling two kinds of substitute products under the price as well as exchange rate uncertainty, what control structure would be chosen is tied closely to the corporation performance. By calculating the equilibria and performance of both horizontal integration and disintegration structures, we indentify the dominant control structure of the two-product multinational corporation. We furthermore analyze the impact of the degree of risk-aversion, substitute coefficient and risks on control structure choice. Keywords: uncertainty environment; risk aversion; control structure 1 Introduction Multinational corporations often locate facilities all over the world, and products flow across national boundaries, managers face the uncertainties and complexities of the global environment. Exchange rate and price uncertainties are two of the complicating factors faced by the multinational corporations. In particular, the fluctuations of price as well exchange rate can be significant with drastic impact on multinational corporations control structure choices. Multinational corporations often produce multi kinds of substitutable or complementary products instead of only one kind. The horizontal centralized control structure means only one manager is employed to manage the production and sale of all kinds of products, and the horizontal decentralized control structure means each kind of product is dominated by one special manager. Then which one control structure should be chosen by the headquarters? It is a matter of importance, because the correct control structure is tied closely to the firm performance. Usually, centralized structure features the system with redundancy and inefficiency,but can copes with risks effectively, while decentralized structure just features contrarily. Hence, under the uncertainty environment, to reveal which control structure can trade off the risks and the efficiency is very important and practical for the multinational corporations. There is a vast literature on the choice of the firm’s internal control structure. One could start from the classical paper of Severinor[1], in which three organizational forms- centralization, decentralization and delegation -are compared, and it is found that the optimal organizational form depends on the degree of complementarity/substitutability between the inputs in the final use. Hart and Moore[2], focusing on specialized assets, anaGrant from:Major Program of National Natural Science Foundation of China (70932005); National Natural Science Foundation of China (70772070) lyzed the conditions under which the decentralized organization has the advantage over the centralized organization. Alonso etal [3] compared the centralized and the decentralized coordination when managers are informed privately and communicate strategically, and concluded that decentralization dominated centralization if the divisions are not too biased towards their own divisions and the divisions are not too different from each other. Rankakari[4] investigated the impact of environment volatility and the cost of information on organization structure, with stable environments generally populated by tightly integrated and centralized organizations and volatile environments generally populated by loosely integrated and decentralized organizations. Organization economics analyzed how the firms design cross-functional coordination strategies, which needs to pool the decentralized and incomplete information(Aoki[5]; Hart &Moore[2]; Alonso etal[3];Dessein et al[6]). These literatures set focus on vertical control structure of different echelons in the internal supply chain, and considered the impact of internal organization management costs caused by uncertainty environment, delay costs, private information, degree of diversification of resources on choice of control structure. It is considered that the performance of centralized coordination under stable environment is dominant, while decentralized coordination is dominant under volatile environment and different opportunities of employing business units. The interaction of influence factors on the horizontal control structures of the same echelon is scarcely studied. Whether centralized or decentralized structure can result in effective communication and coordination is always a focus in Organization Economics, and there are some literatures (Shapiro[7];Montgomery&Hausman[8];Karmarkar&Lele[9] ) analyzed the necessity of the coordination to the potential conflict between different departments. Another kind of literatures aimed at designing compensation mechanism in order to achieve more precise demand forecast(Gonik[10]; Rao[11]; Celikbas et al[12]; Chen [13]), which can help to design operational projects more effectively. These studies simply put Principal-agent theory into the vertical incentive mechanism design in different echelons between headquarters and department units, ignoring the super-additives effect on firm performance set by the interaction relation of the different department units. This paper will study the horizontal control structures of internal supply chain, in order to make up for the sparseness of the study on internal supply chain control structure. This paper constructs the model of a multinational corporation which product and sell two kinds of substitutable products, that is, two-product corporation. Depending on the controlling and management model of two types of products, two horizontal control structures of centralization and decentralization are classified. Under the price and exchange rate risks environment, by comparing and calculating the equilibria and performance of centralized and decentralized structures, we reveal the dominant control structure which can improve the system performance. Meanwhile, we also analyze the integrated impact of degree of risk aversion, risks and substitutability on the choice of internal horizontal control structure, by which we provide the theory basis for the multinational corporation to choice the internal control structure. The random variables in this paper are independent to each other, all information is common knowledge, and the risk is represented by the variance of the corresponding random variable. pi a qi bq3i , i 1,2; a a0 e, e ~ N (0, va ), a , following the normal distribution with the mean value of a 0 and the variance of va , can be where explained as the value of customer acceptance of the product, va represents the degree of volatility of the market price , and can be called the price risk for short. b (0,1) is the degree of product substitution, and the bigger is the value of b which equivalently means the higher is degree of substitution, the severer is the competition between two types of the product. pi and qi are the retail price and the quantity for the product i , respectively. For convenience and without loss of generality, the marginal cost of each kind of product is the same and with the sign of c , which is measured in the domestic currency. r is the foreign market currency exchange rate in stage 2, that is, the value of one unit of the foreign currency measure in the domestic currency, and r is a random variable with the mean value of r0 and the variance of vr . We assumed that a0 r0c , which is reasonable and can assure the marginal profit of the product is positive. presents the firm’s profit. The utility functions of the manger(s) and the headquarters are denoted by U M ( ) and U H ( ) , respectively. 2 The model E () and V () present the expectation and variance Consider a firm that produces two types of substitutable goods domestically, while sets production facility in a foreign country because of the lower manufacturing cost. We use a two-stage stochastic program to model the firm’s decisions. In the first stage, a “product-production” plan for the production facility is developed by the manager(s). Under centralized control structure, there is a single manager who manage the production and the sale of two kinds of products; while under the decentralized control structure, each type has one special manger who exclusively manage the production and the sale of the special type consequently, hence, there are two managers employed by the shareholders. The payment to the manager(s) depend on the revenue(s) of the type(s) managed by him, and the manager(s) is(are) under the administration of the headquarters which is controlled by the shareholders of the corporations. The headquarters has the right to decide which control structure to conduct. The manager(s) and the shareholders(headquarters) are all risk aversion, and they are all the Mean-Variance optimizers, while have the different risk aversion attitudes. The market price is given by the inverse demand function operator respectively. The superscript c and d indicate the centralized and decentralized control structure, respectively. 3 The performance of the internal control structure 3.1 The performance of the horizontal centralized control structure Under the centralized structure, the production and sale of two types of product are both managed by only one manager. At the stage 1, the manager decides the quantity of all products to produce in the foreign facility to maximize his utility, which is the expectation-variance utility function 1 U M ( ) E ( ) k MV ( ) , 2 where k M ( 0) denotes the degree of the manager’s risk aversion. (a q1 bq2 cr )q1 (a q2 bq1 cr)q2 , and E ( ) (a0 q1 bq2 cr0 )q1 (a0 q2 bq1 cr0 )q2 , U M ( ) d V ( ) (va vr c 2 )( q1 q2 ) 2 . The quantity decision hence is q1 q2 a0 cr0 . 2(b k M vr c 2 k M va 1) The expectation-variance utility function of the headquarters is 1 U H ( ) E ( ) kV ( ) , 2 where k ( 0) denotes the degree of the headquarters’ risk aversion. At stage 1, the expectation profit of the system is (a cr0 ) 2 (2k M v r c 2 b 1 2k M v a ) , E ( c ) 0 2(b k M v r c 2 k M v a 1) 2 and the expectation utilities of the manager and the headquarters are (a 0 cr0 ) 2 c , U M ( ) 2(b k M v r c 2 k M v a 1) (a cr ) 2 (2k M vr c 2 kvr c 2 b kva 2k M va 1) . U H ( ) 0 0 2(b k M vr c 2 k M va 1) 2 c U H ( ) d (a0 cr0 ) 2 (2 k M vr c 2 k M va ) , ( 2 b k M vr c 2 k M va ) 2 2(a0 cr0 ) 2 (k M vr c 2 kvr c 2 1 kva k M va ) . (b k M vr c 2 k M va 2) 2 3.3 The choice of the internal control structure Let b 3 9b 2 14b 9 , 4k M c 2 vr 0 1 b2 1 v r1 ( v r 0 ) , kM c 2 va 0 b 3 9b 2 14b 9 vr c 2 , 4k M va1 1 b2 1 v r c 2 (v a 0 ) , 4k M A 3vr c2b 3vab 6vr c2kM va 3va kM 2 4vr c 2 4va 3vr c 4 kM , 2 B b 2 b bvr c 2 kM bkM va 2vr kM c 2 M 3.2 The performance of the horizontal decentralized control structure 3vr c4kM 2kM va 4k M vavr c2 3kM va 。 Proposition 1 For va va 0 or vr vr 0 , if Under the decentralized structure, the production and sale of each type of product has one special manager. The subscripts 1 and 2 denote the first type and the second type of product, respectively. At the stage 1, the manager i (i 1,2) decides the quantity of product 0 k B / A , there is U H ( ) U H ( ) , else if i to maximize his expectation-variance utility function U M i ( i ) (a qi bq3i )qi crqi 1 2 k M (va vr c 2 )qi , 2 where i denotes the profit of the type i , and 1 2 . k M represents the degree of the manager i ’s risk aversion, which for convenience is the same to each other as well as the same to that of the manager’s under centralized structure. The quantity decision hence is a0 cr0 q1 q2 . 2 b k M vr c 2 k M va At stage 1, the expectation profit of the system is E ( d ) 2(a0 cr0 ) 2 (1 k M v r c 2 k M v a ) , (2 b k M v M c 2 k M v a ) 2 and the total expectations utilities of the two managers and the headquarters are 2 2 2 2 2 c d k B / A there is U H ( ) U H ( ) ; for 0 va va 0 and 0 vr vr 0 , there is c d U H ( ) U H ( ) . c d Proof U H ( ) U H ( ) c d (a0 cr0 ) 2 (b k M vr c 2 k M va )( Ak B) , 2(b k M va k M vr c 2 1) 2 (b 2 k M va k M vr c 2 ) 2 the signal of the equation above is equivalent to Ak B . Obviously, A 0 , and B is a concave quadratic polynomial of va . It is easy to prove that v a 0 is the positive solution of the equation B 0 . If va 0 , there is B b 2 b bv r c 2 k M 3v r k M c 2 2v r c 4 k M , which is negative when 0 vr vr 0 , and is positive 2 when 2 vr vr 0 . The proposition 1 hence can be con- cluded by the property of the quadratic polynomial. The proof is completed. Proposition 1 shows that when the price risk and exchange risk are both less than the corresponding thresholds, the utility of the headquarters under the centralized structure is dominant than that under the decen- tralized structure. If the price risk or the exchange risk is higher than the corresponding threshold, then if the degree of risk aversion of the headquarters is smaller enough, the utility of the headquarters under the decentralized structure is dominant than that under the centralized structure, otherwise the utility of the headquarters under the centralized structure is dominant. Hence, the headquarters will choose the best internal control structure in term of the circumstances. Proposition 2 For va va 0 or vr vr 0 , there is E ( c ) E ( d ) ; 0 va va 0 and for 0 vr vr 0 , there is E ( c ) E ( d ) . The proof is similar to that of proposition 1, hence is omitted here. v a 0 , v r 0 are the thresholds of the price risk and the exchange risk, respectively, and are both increasing with the substitute degree b , decreasing with k M and c . v a 0 is also decreasing with vr . Proposition 2 indicates that when the price risk and exchange risk are both less than the corresponding thresholds, the expectation profit of the system under centralized structure is better than that under the decentralized structure, and when If the price risk or the exchange risk is higher than the corresponding threshold, the expectation profit of the system under decentralized structure is better than that under the centralized structure. Proposition 1 and proposition 2 imply that If condition va va 0 , 0 k B / A , or vr vr 0 , 0 k B / A , or 0 va va 0 , 0 vr vr 0 is satisfied, then the control structure chosen by the headquarters can bring firm dominant expectation profit, else the control structure chosen by the headquarters can’t bring the firm dominant expectation profit. Proposition 3 For va va1 or vr vr1 , there is U M ( ) U M ( ) c d ; for 0 va va1 (v a , v r ) is in the set (0, va1 ) (0, vr1 ) , then the control structure chosen by the headquarters is just the dominant control structure of the manger(s) , else, the control structure chosen by the headquarters is just not the dominant control structure of the manager(s). 4 Conclusion For a two-product multinational corporation under the price as well as exchange rate uncertainty, the headquarters will choose the internal control structure to maximize their utility. If the price risk and exchange rate risk are lower than the corresponding thresholds, the centralized control structure will be chosen. If the price risk or exchange rate risk is higher than the corresponding thresholds, the decentralized control structure will be chosen for the case of the lower headquarters risk aversion degree, while the centralized control structure will be chosen for the case of higher headquarters risk aversion degree. Consequently, we get to the conclusion that the decentralized control structure will be dominant under the higher risk or the lower headquarters’ risk aversion; whereas, the centralized control structure will be dominant under the lower risk or the higher headquarters’ risk aversion. References [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] and [8] The proof is similar to that of proposition 1, hence is omitted here. By proposition 1 and proposition 3, we know that for if (v a , v r ) is in the set 0 k B / A , [9] (0, va1 ) (0, vr1 ) set [11] (va 0 ,) (vr 0 ,) , then the control structure cho- [12] 0 vr vr1 , there is U M ( ) U M ( ) . c or d in the sen by the headquarters is just the dominant control structure of the manger(s) , else, the control structure chosen by the headquarters is just not the dominant control structure of the manager(s). For k B / A , if [10] [13] Severinov S. The value of information and optimal organization[J]. The RAND Journal of Economics, 2008, 39(1): 238-265. Hart O, Moore J. On the design of hierarchies: coordination versus specialization[J]. Journal of Political Economy, 2005, 113: 675-702. Alonso R, Dessein W. When does coordination require centralization? Working Paper, Northwest University, 2008. Rantakari H. Organizational design and environmental volatility. Working Paper, University of Southern California, 2008. Aoki M. Horizontal vs. Vertical Information Structure of the Firm[J]. The American Economic Review, 1986, 76(5): 971-983. Dessein W, Garicano L, Gertner R. Organizing for synergies[J]. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2010, 2(4): 77-114. Shapiro P. Can marketing and manufacturing coexist?[J]. Harvard Business Review, 1977, Sept-Oct, 55(5): 104-114. Montgomery D B, Hausman, W F. Managing the marketing manufacturing interface[J]. Gestion2000: Management and Perspective, 1986, 5(2): 69-85. Karmarkar U S, Lele M M. The marketing/manufacturing interface: strategic issues. Working Paper,William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration, university of Rochester,1989. Gonik J. The salesmen's bonuses to their forecasts[J]. Harvard Business Review, 1978, May-June, 56: 116-124. Rao R. Compensating heterogeneous salesforces: some explicit solutions[J]. Marketing Science, 1990,9(4):319-341. Celikbas M, Shanthikumar J G, Swaminathan J M. Coordinating Production Quantities And Demand Forecasts Through Penalty Schemes[J]. IIE Transactions, 1999, 31(9):851-864. Chen F. Salesforce Incentives, Market Information, and Production/Inventory Planning[J]. Management Science, 2005, 51(1): 60-75.