WEB APPENDIX Proof of Corollary 1 We use the proof by contradiction method. Suppose d L d H . Since MD Price to L-Types d L MD Price to H-Types d L 0 and 0 , the highest value of MD ND in the region where d L d H is obtained when d L d H . Substituting d L d H , we arrive at: MD ND 1 Max 0,d H d H vLF vLF vLF d H vLF 2vLF 1 d H 1 0 MD ND Thus, a necessary condition for 0 is dL dH . Proof of Corollary 2 We use the proof by contradiction method. Suppose vHU 1 vLF vLU . Using equations (1) and PS ND 1 vHU vLF vLU vLF vLU (7), we find: PS ND Min . Since ,1 2 v 0 , in the LF 2 2 vHU vHU 1 vLF vLU , the highest value of PS ND is obtained when 1 vLF vLU . Substituting vHU 1 vLF vLU , we arrive at: region where vHU 1 (1 vLF vLU ) vLF vLU vLF vLU PS ND Min ,1 2vLF 2 2 3v 2v v Min LF ,1 LU LF 2 2 2 v v LU LF 0 2 PS ND Thus, a necessary condition for 0 is vHU 1 vLF vLU , or rearranging, vLF vLU 1 vHU . Proof of Proposition 1 Part (a) asserts that there is a subset of parameters such that MD ND PS . Using equations (1), (4), and (7), these inequalities will hold if: 1 vHU vLF vLU vLF vLU 1 Max dH dL vLF ,0 dL vLF 2vLF Min ,1 2 2 (A1) The regions in Figures 1 a) and b) denoted as “Only PS is advantageous to ND” show that the subset denoted by (A1) is non-empty. Part (b) is a direct calculation of PS MD using equations (4) and (7). Part (c) is based on the following calculations: PS MD vLU 1 if vLU 1 vHU vLF 2 1 if vLU 1 vHU vLF 1 (A2) d vLF if d L H PS MD vLF d L 2v if d d H L LF vLF PS MD vHU PS MD d H (A3) 1 if vHU vLU vLF 1 2 0 if vHU vLU vLF 1 (A4) 1 if d H d L vLF 0 if d H d L vLF (A5) Proof of Lemma 2 In this proposed equilibrium, the firm select prices such that H-type consumers purchase their favored product and L-type consumers purchase the probabilistic good. To induce such segmentation, prices much be set according to equation (6). Substituting in vLU vHU 0 , we have P1PS 1 vLF and P0PS vLF . At 2 2 2 1 these prices, total demand for the popular good is and the total demand for the unpopular good is 2 3 2 . To meet this demand, the seller must purchase 2 1 units of each product. Such an inventory 2 2 1 v v 2 1 1 PS , DU LF LF decision results in a profit of 2c vLF 2 1 c . 2 2 2 2 It is obvious that ordering more that 2 1 units of each product cannot be optimal since this would 2 increase costs without impacting revenue. Thus, the key to proving Lemma 2 is showing that it is not optimal for the seller to reduce its inventory orders below 2 1 . It is important to note that, to induce price 2 discrimination under PS, prices must be set according to equation (6) regardless of the inventory order (and without price discrimination, PS is equivalent to ND). Let K be the number of units ordered for each product and X be the number of units held back of each good to use for buyers of the probabilistic good. There are three parameter regions of K to consider: 1. If K 1 , the firm sells out of both products at the regular price P1PS . Profit is 2 P1PS c K , which is increasing in K. Thus, there is no interior solution for K 1 . 2. If 1 K , profit equals 1 K X P1PS 2 X PoPS 2cK s.t. 0 X K 1 . Since profit is linear in X, only corner solutions can be optimal. At X=0, profit is linear in K, so we have a corner solution: K 1 or K . If X K 1 , profit is linear in K, which implies the maximum on this range would be achieved at either K 1 or K . Note that if K 1 , then X K 1 0 . Thus, there are three relevant corner solutions: (1) X=0& K 1 , which yields a profit of (1) 1 1 vLF 2c ; (2) X=0& K , which yields a profit of 1 vLF (3) 2 c ; and (3) X 2 1 & K , which yields 1 vLF 1 2c . 2 2 1 If K , all H-types can purchase their favored product, and thus the amount of the popular 2 (2) 3. good remaining is X K . This can be used to create 2 X units of the probabilistic good. Profit is P1PS 2 K PoPS 2cK . This function is linear in K. The profit at the corner solution with 2 K is (2) . The profit at the corner solution with K 2 1 is given by PS , DU as defined in part 2 (b) of Lemma 2. Comparing the four candidate solutions, we find v 2c PS , DU (2) LF 0 and (3) (1) 2 1 vLF 2c 0 , where these differences are positive since 2 v 2c 2 11 vLF v v c LF . Furthermore, PS , DU (3) LF 0 since c LF and vLF 1 . 2 2 2 PS , DU Thus, is the maximum profit available under PS when there is demand uncertainty. Proof of Proposition 2 For the parameter region given in the text, in the absence of demand uncertainty (as analyzed in Section 3.2), under PS, we have P1PS 1 vLF , P0PS vLF , and PS vLF 1 2c . Lemma 2 gives the profit 2 2 2 under PS when demand uncertainty is present. Thus, the magnitude of the profit decrease caused by demand uncertainty is: (A6) PS , DU PS PS , DU 2 1 c 0 Profits decrease because revenue is unchanged, but inventory costs rise with demand uncertainty. In particular, without demand uncertainty, the firm is able to match inventory orders to sales. But under demand uncertainty, 2 1 3 2 2 1 units of the ex post unpopular good will go unsold. Finally, with and 2 2 without demand uncertainty, all consumers purchase, and thus total sales equal 2. In the absence of demand uncertainty, equations (3) and (4) give the prices and profit under MD. For the parameter region under consideration, we have: P1MD 1 , P2MD dL vLF , and MD 1 dL vLF 2c . With demand uncertainty, the retailer can either mimic the prices and allocation that were used when there was no demand uncertainty or it can sell fewer units. First, suppose the firm retains the same prices and allocation. Since the H-type consumers purchase their favored product in Period 1 and the L-type consumers purchase their favored product in Period 2, total demand for the popular good equals 2 and total demand for the unpopular good equals 2 1 . With demand uncertainty, in order to meet this demand, the seller must purchase 2 units of each product (which will result in 2(2α - 1) units going unsold). The profit to the seller is: (A7) aMD , DU 1 d L vLF 4 c Second, suppose the retailer reduces its inventory orders so that fewer units go unsold. Let MD , DU K 2 be the number of units ordered of each product. Note that, since the value of the L-type’s less favored good is zero, the seller cannot benefit from inducing the L-types to purchase their less-preferred product.1 Thus, as long as it is profitable to make second period sales, the prices charged will be the same as in the case without demand uncertainty. The seller earns a profit of: (A8) bMD, DU Min , K MD, DU 1 1 Max K MD, DU , 0 dL vLF 2 K MD, DU c 1 Therefore, prices in the second period are the same for both the popular good and the unpopular one. Symmetric prices are consistent with much of current retail practice. For example, major department stores often offer the same markdown percentage on all color-patterns of a particular product even when demand differs across these color patterns. 3 2 1 so that the seller can meet the entire demand for the Equation (A8) assumes that K unpopular good. Since demand for the popular good is strictly higher than the demand for the unpopular good, it cannot be optimal for the firm to produce such limited units that it sells out of the unpopular good. MD , DU Notice that bMD , DU is linear in K . Thus, there is no interior solution and we must have a corner MD, DU MD, DU 2 1 , K MD , DU , or K MD , DU 2 . The profit when K MD , DU 2 is given by solution at K aMD , DU as defined by (A7). For the other two corner solutions, we consider two parameter regions separately. 2 , then 2 1 . In this range, both additional corner solutions are feasible. 3 MD , DU , DU 2 1 , then bMD If K 3 1 1 dL vLF 4 1 c . Here, there are just enough units ,2 If of the unpopular product to meet the demand from both the H-types and the L-types. However, the popular MD , DU , then product sells out in the first period before meeting the entire demand from the H-types. If K , DU bMD 1 1 dL vLF 2 c . Here, there are just enough units of the popular good to meet the demand ,3 in the first period from the H-types. Thus, no L-types who favor the popular good are able to purchase in the second period. Furthermore, after both first period and second period sales of the unpopular product, units of , DU , DU inventory will remain unsold. Furthermore, we calculate bMD bMD 3 21 2c 0 . Thus, it is ,3 ,2 never optimal to choose K MD, DU 2 1 when 2 . 3 2 MD, DU 2 1 , , then 2 1 . In this range, the only feasible corner solution is K 3 , DU which yields a profit of bMD 1 3 4 dL vLF 4 1 c . Here, all H-types are able to purchase their ,4 favored product in the first period, all L-types who favor the unpopular product can purchase in the second period, but the popular good stocks out during the second period. All units of both goods will be sold. The seller chooses the corner solution which yields the highest profit: If MD , DU 1 d L vLF 4 c 1 3 4 d L vLF 4 1 c 1 1 d L vLF 2 c d L vLF 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 c (A9) The profit decrease caused by demand uncertainty when the seller employs the MD strategy is: MD , DU MD MD , DU 2c 2 1 2 2 1 d L vLF c d L vLF 2c 1 c d L vLF 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 (A10) Without demand uncertainty, under MD, the firm is able to match inventory orders to sales. But, when there is demand uncertainty, some units of the unpopular good go unsold: Unsold MD , DU 2 2 1 0 3 - 2 c d L vLF 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 4 (A11) In the absence of demand uncertainty, all consumers purchase under MD, and thus total sales equal 2. However, when there is demand uncertainty, the market may not be fully covered. In particular, sales are: Units Sold MD , DU 2 4 1 2 c d L vLF 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 (A12) Using (A6) and (A10), we can compare the profit loss caused by demand uncertainty under MD versus PS: MD , DU PS , DU c 2 1 0 2 1 2d L vLF 3c d L vLF c c d L vLF 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 (A13) The difference in profit decrease is positive unless costs are too large. In particular, the first line of (A13) is positive. The second line is positive if c < 2(dL vLF)/3. The third line is positive if c < α dL vLF . Thus, a sufficient condition for ΔMD,DU > ΔPS,DU is c < 2(dL vLF)/3. Comparing the number of unsold inventory under MD versus PS: Unsold MD , DU Unsold PS , DU 2 1 0 1- 2 0 -1 0 d L vLF 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 c (A14) Comparing total sales under MD versus PS: Units Sold MD , DU Units Sold PS , DU 0 2 2 1 0 0 5 d L vLF 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 d L vLF c d L vLF & 2 3 2 c (A15)