There are six kinds of theory building

advertisement
Some notes on case study methodology for Action COST project
Draft (06-08-08)
Salvador Parrado
Table of contents
CASE STUDIES AND THEIR RATIONALE .................................................................................... 1
CASE STUDY DESIGN ..................................................................................................................... 2
Research question ............................................................................................................................ 2
Research objectives .......................................................................................................................... 4
Specification of variables ................................................................................................................. 5
Case selection ................................................................................................................................... 6
Describing the variance in variables ................................................................................................ 8
Formulation of data requirements and general questions ................................................................ 8
CONSIDERATIONS FOR CASE STUDY DESIGN ......................................................................... 8
Causal mechanisms and process tracing: clarification notes ........................................................... 8
Typological theory: clarification notes ............................................................................................ 9
APPENDIX - RESEARCH QUESTIONS FROM COST ACTION PARTICIPANTS...................... 9
LITERATURE ................................................................................................................................... 15
CASE STUDIES AND THEIR RATIONALE
This note sets some options for discussing a case study methodology for COST Action project CRIPO. The note is subject to discussion (COST session in Rotterdam 5- September 2008) not only
on the methodological aspects to be followed but also on the applied options for COST project. This
section is devoted to justify the usefulness of case studies. Those who are already persuaded may
skip it.
Case studies are helpful in numerous ways. The definition offered by (Seawright and Gerring, 2008
p. 296) is useful: “the intensive (qualitative or quantitative) analysis of a single unit or a small
number of units (the cases), where the researcher’s goal is to understand a larger class of similar
units (a population of cases). There is thus an inherent problem of inference from the sample (of one
or several) to a larger population. By contrast, a very different style of case study (so-called) aims to
elucidate features specific to a particular case. Here the problem of case selection does not exist (or
is at any rate minimized), for the case of primary concern has been identified a priori.” (Barzelay,
2007) identifies the first group as instrumental case studies (they are used to understand a bigger
sample) and the second group is considered as intrinsic (or atheoretical driven and aimed at
focusing on the richness of the case per se). This note focuses on the instrumental case studies, not
on the intrinsic case studies.
The use of case studies can be suited for well quantitatively explored areas (i.e. analysis of agencies
through COBRA methodology) and for less statistically explored areas (i.e. role of agencies in
policy-making). Firstly, in areas where statistical analysis has been undertaken (for instance,
relation between agency autonomy and performance or agency autonomy and meritocracy of staff
recruitment in Latin American countries), case studies may serve several purposes. In some
instances, one might select deviant cases in order to understand their anomaly and their contribution
1
to theory. For example, Mexico has not a meritocratic general civil service; however, unlike all
Latin American countries, four regulatory Mexican agencies are fully meritocratic. The question
here would be: Why is this deviant case happening? And what does it tell of the general theory
from which it derives?
In other instances, one might select the most typical case (following the terminology by (Seawright
and Gerring, 2008)in order to explore and understand causal mechanisms that are not apparent in
the quantitative analysis. For instance, one might state that there is a causal (varying in degree)
relationship between autonomy and agency performance. A typical case would be a representative
case in relation to any kind of used cross-model. Basically, as the case is explained by the model
(causal relationship between autonomy and performance), the researcher wants to dig into the case
study in order to explore and understand the causal mechanisms at work (autonomy allows for
selecting and paying more qualified staff / autonomy allows for using the best performing
contractors… / autonomy allows for the use of more managerial techniques …). Those causes can
be arranged in a single path (less likely) or in multiple paths (equifinality or multiple causes) (see
some paragraphs on this below in the section Causal mechanisms and process tracing). Deviant and
typical cases are just illustration of the use of case studies; there are other possibilities not explored
here.
Secondly, in an area not very well explored from the quantitative point of view, case studies can be
useful in order to generate hypotheses or to test hypotheses derived from theoretical frameworks
aimed at other research topics. For instance, cases studies on the role of agencies in policy-making
could be crafted as generating hypotheses out of well selected cases or as testing hypotheses from
frameworks of policy-making stemming from other areas (i.e. politicians-bureaucrats relationships;
intergovernmental relationships…).
A case study typically covers three phases: design, carrying out the empirical work and drawing the
implications of case findings for theory. This note focuses on the first phase and it draws materials
from (George and Bennett, 2005). For more practical questions on sampling cases and the empirical
work, (Gerring, 2007) and (Seawright and Gerring, 2008)will be selected. While the focus is on
design, the text will also refer some theoretical aspects and concepts to be used in the case study.
The materials are organised as follows. For each task to be undertaken in the case study design there
is a distinction between what is meant in this task (inserted in a Table) and what options or
application of that meaning can be found for the COST Action project.
CASE STUDY DESIGN
Research question
What is the research question (RQ) or puzzle to be solved? This is common to any methodology. In
this case, the application will try to take into account what has already been done by COST Action
participants.
The participants of COST Action project have focused implicitly or explicitly (see also APPENDIX
for more specific questions) on research questions related to the agencification process, the degree
of autonomy, the control-coordination exerted by the parent ministry, the impact of agency
autonomy on performance, and issues of accountability (also combined with control). For the case
study, some of these research questions could be pursued in order to find the underlying causal
mechanisms or process tracing (see the concepts below in the section on Causal mechanisms and
process tracing).
Derived from the research from COST Action participants, other research questions related to trust
between parent ministry and agency (see Van Thiel and Yesilkagit 2008) or the influence of public
agencies in policy making could be explored. Other items could be added to this additional list. For
the sake of simplicity and only as an illustration, this note will focus on one research question
2
related to the role of agencies in policy-making that has been under explored. If the final selected
RQ is different, some adjustments will be needed for the different parts of the case study
methodology.
The background for the research question on the role of agencies in policymaking is very similar to
the literature on the relationships between politicians and bureaucrats and the role of bureaucrats in
policy making. The rationale behind the implementation of agencies sets a more or less clear cut
division between operations or delivery (agencies) and policy or decision making (parent ministry
and? Parliament), although (Pollitt, 2004) argue that there are doctrinal and practical examples
showing that this is not a universal trend. In any case, there is a widely shared view whereby
agencies should not have an important role in policy making. This issue has not been intensively
researched.
A research question related to this could be:
What is the role of agencies in policy making and how can it (or the different roles) be explained?
This research question is relevant because it deals with:

Accountability, transparency and legitimacy issues

The role played not only by the agencies themselves, but also by parliament, professionals,
interest groups, and civil servants from the ministry is highlighted

Likely influence that agencies will have in how their performance and operations are
undertaken, controlled, measured…

Other arguments?
What is the phenomenon or type of behaviour that is being singled out for examination? As
(Barzelay, 2007) suggests, case studies should focus on processes (operating the Brazil in Action
programme) and not on entities (tax agency). Further efforts should be devoted to define scoped
(not to broad) “class” or subclass of phenomenon.
The case studies would be of “the role of agencies in policy-making”. Probably, more specification
would be required here to distinguish between policies related to the internal organisation of the
agency and policies related to the field in which the agency operates.
Is the goal to explain the lack of or an observable variation in the dependent variable?
Depending on the ambition of the project, there are at least two options here:
a) An expected lack of variation in the dependent variable should be found in agencies that are
operating in: the same policy field, the same functions, with the same tasks, or belong to the
same category according to different classifications. This implies in practical terms to select
one field, function or task and analyse that role in different countries. In this case, the State
tradition will have the explanatory burden.
b) An expected variation of the dependent variable should be found in agencies belonging to
different milieu (as described in a).
What theoretical framework will be employed? If not, what provisional theories will be formulated
by the researcher or what theory-relevant variables will be considered?
There are also several possibilities here for which already implicit (or explicit) selection of
independent and dependent variables are already made.
a) One theoretical framework refers to the impact of types of policies on policy-making. Lowi
(1964) and Wilson (1973, 1980) establish a classification of policies according to their
purposes and consequences. They further argue that particular types of policies determine
3
the way in which decision-making and implementation of those policies are made. In Lowi’s
typology distributive, redistributive, constitutional and regulatory policies are distinguished.
In Wilson’s typology, the focus is on the dispersion or concentration of costs and benefits of
different policies. There are other applications and even mergers of those typologies. Cases
studies should be selected in relation to the cells produced by a table with types of policies
and policy-making style.
b) Another theoretical framework is referred as ‘bureau-shaping’ crafted by (Dunleavy, 1991
pp. 183-188). In this framework, agencies are classified as regards to their core and bureau
budget into: delivery, regulatory, transfer and contract agencies. Dunleavy’s argument
focuses on the relevance of the core budget for the maximization strategy of bureaucrats. In
our case, the budget could be argued to have influence in the way in which the role of
agencies in policy-making changes.
c) A third theoretical framework has been recently labelled as Task-Specific Path Dependency
by (Pollitt, 2004). In this collective effort there is a mixture between functions (forestry,
meteorological services, prisons, social security benefits) and tasks using the typology from
(Wilson, 1989). Wilson offers a typology of agencies as regards to the tasks that an agency
performs. He takes into account the degree to which the outputs and outcomes of an agency
can be observed giving birth to production organisations (tax agency), craft organization
(inspection agencies), and procedural organizations (mental health counselling service). The
implications of this could be derived from how the agency is managed and how they play a
role in decision-making.
Other possible theoretical frameworks could be added to this. The case study could either use one
specific framework to be tested or use at least two of them as alternatives. If alternatives are chosen,
it would require further care in the selection of the cases. Finally, some additional independent
variables will have to be included in the framework (see below).
From the specified theories, what aspects will be singled out for testing, refinement, or elaboration?
This issue should be decided once a theoretical framework has been chosen.
Research objectives
There are at least six kinds of theory building-research objectives using (Lijphart, 1971) and
(George and Bennett, 2005 75-76).
A.- Descriptive or intrinsic
(1) Atheoretical case studies / configurative idiographic. These cases provide thick description
to be used for other studies for theory building
(2) Interpretative case studies / disciplined configurative. These cases are selected because of
the relevance or interest of the case and they use theories to explain it. The theory is used to
shed light on the case rather than improve the generalization. The case study can be used to:
a. Impugn the theory
b. Highlight the need of new theories in some areas
B.- Theory-building or instrumental case studies:
(3) Hypothesis-generating case studies / Heuristic. In this type, new variables, hypotheses,
causal mechanisms, and causal paths can be drawn out of the case study.
4
(4) Theory-confirming-infirming case studies / Theory testing. Case studies “assess the validity
and scope conditions of single or competing theories”. According to (Lijphart, 1971 p.
692), the theoretical value of both types of case studies is enhanced, however, if the cases
are, or turn out to be, extreme on one of the variables: such studies can also be labeled
"crucial experiments" or crucial tests of the propositions.”
(5) Plausability probes are used in order to check whether untested theories and hypotheses
require more intensive testing.
(6) Deviant case studies. These cases show why some cases deviate from the theory. (Lijphart,
1971 692) adds that “they weaken the original proposition, but suggest a modified
proposition that may be stronger. The validity of the proposition in its modified form must
be established by further comparative analysis.”
A case study design could aim at achieving two or more purposes in some cases.
The exemplified RQ for this note would be placed between point (4) Theory-confirming and point
(3) Hypothesis-generating case studies
Specification of variables
The classical question of any research will be answered here.
The dependent variable to be explained
There are several options in order to analyse and make typologies of the dependent variable.
Typologies would be of value if the case study aims at drafting typological theories (see the section
below on Typological theory). A set of options stems from the analogy of distinguishing between
decision making (policy) and delivery (operations) functions among ministries and agencies and the
distinction between policy (ministers) and implementers (civil servants). Two possible frameworks
are the following ones: “images” from (Aberbach, Putnam and Rockman, 1981) and “public service
bargains” from (Hood and Lodge, 2006). In these cases, we should adapt the typologies replacing
politicians through ministries and civil servants through agencies.
a) (Aberbach, Putnam and Rockman, 1981 pp. 4-23) reduce the universe of possible relations
among politicians and bureaucrats to four images: “policy-administration (politicians make
policy; civil servants administer; facts-interests (both groups participate in policy making,
but civil servants bring facts and knowledge and politicians values and interests); energyequilibrium (both groups engage in policy making and are concerned with politics, while
politicians articulate broad, diffuse interests of unorganized individuals, bureaucrats mediate
narrow, focused interests of organized clienteles); and, pure hybrid (virtual disappearance of
the Weberian distinction between the roles of politician and bureaucrat”).
b) (Hood and Lodge, 2006) use public service bargains. They are simply understood (p. 6) as
the “explicit or implicit agreements between public servants – the civil or uniformed
services of the state- and those they serve”. The authors identify 8 types of public service
bargains (p. 21) out of the two main types: ‘trustee’ bargains and ‘agency’ bargains. These
in turns are duplicated in two pairs (representational, tutelary) and (delegated, directed
respectively). This framework could be adapted to the relationships between the ministry
and the agency.
Other different ways to look at the dependent variable come from policy analysis.
c) The work on policy styles from (Richardson, 1982) offers one possibility for this.
Richardson and co-authors focus on the likely convergence of “standard operating
procedures for policy-making” (and also for implementation). They tried to capture the
5
universe into four different styles: (consensual, imposition relationship); (anticipatory-a
active, reactive problem solving).
d) A more dichotomous option is offered by (Gehring, 2004) when analysing regulatory
agencies using Habermasian theory of communicative action. The author distinguishes
between interest-based bargaining interactions and deliberative arguing.
Of course there are other options that could be explored. The listing has stopped here until an
agreement is made on the RQ. A crossing between the theoretical framework and the likely effects
will produce numerous cells (depending whether variables are dichotomous or not). Most variables
considered here are not dichotomous. This implies that the number of cells for which a case study
can be made increases. However, there are techniques for reducing the number of cells, and we
should also consider the trade-off between parsimonious explanations or more rich explanation
including equifinality or multiple causes. Furthermore, the proposed typology will not be final until
some preliminary empirical work has been undertaken. After a preliminary stage, the typology
should be refined.
The independent (intervening) variables considered in the theoretical framework.
The independent variables will depend on the selected framework from above. Additionally, other
variables should be considered like the role of Europe, the role of particular communities of
professionals, just to name two clear examples that are absent from the theoretical frameworks from
above. In general terms, the case studies should be selected on the independent variable (different or
same sector; different or same function or task) and not on the dependent variable (instances in
which policy-making is consensual according to the typology of (Richardson, 1982)) because it
could otherwise lead to selection bias.
Variables that will be held constant serving as parameters across case studies in different settings
(countries, sectors…) and variables that will vary across cases.
This issue is to be decided. One could set as constant the fact that all agencies comply to a similar
degree with the three features that an agency might have according to (Pollitt, 2004). This degree of
autonomy should be constant across countries and sectors; otherwise, they cannot be chosen for the
study. Another different way to look at it is to choose sectors for which there are quasi-autonomous
delivery units (agencies) and dependent units (ministries) in order to track differences in their role
in policy making.
Case selection
The cases should be selected:

On the basis of their relevance to the research objective of the study: theory development,
theory testing, or heuristic purposes.

On the variation- non-variation of the subclass to which case studies belong to.

On a typology of processes to be researched. This will help to identify how many
subclasses are available and whether all case studies should belong to one subclass or all
subclasses should be analysed through a case study.
For this section, the typology of (Seawright and Gerring, 2008) will be used. They distinguish the
following case studies as being typical, diverse, extreme, deviant, influential, most similar, and
most different cases. Each one entails a different quantitative or qualitative selection procedure.
For instance, in order to select a typical case study, they look “for the smallest possible residual—(
the distance between the predicted value and the actual (measured) value) —for all cases in a
multivariate analysis.” (p. 299). A typical case can also be qualitatively identified.
6
Let’s imagine, for the sake of illustration, that we would like to select the most diverse cases.
According to (Seawright and Gerring, 2008 p. 300), these case studies have the objective of
achieving the maximum variance along relevant dimensions in the independent variable (X) or the
dependent variable (Y) or a particular relationship between X/Y. If the focus is on one of the
variables (it would be hypothesis seeking and exploratory), and if the focus is the relationship (it is
hypothesis testing and confirmatory). According to this, one design would be of exploratory nature
by trying to link agencies operating policies of distributional, redistributive and regulatory nature
with policy styles. One caveat should be born in mind. It is almost impossible to categorize an
agency, given the vast array of their tasks in many of them, according to a single category.
Therefore, if a category is given, the particular task should be applied. For instance, the tax agency
behaves in a domain with concentrated costs and diffused benefits (VAT) and in another domain
with diffused costs and diffused benefits (income tax). So, the tax agency would fit two cells in
Wilson’s typology (this labelling could also be controversial).
In a very simplified way, in option 1, (hypothesis seeking), case studies should help to generate
hypotheses about the relationship between policy types and policy style in the way in which
agencies interact with ministries. After the case study, one may say that in distributive policies style
of policy making is consensual (this should be tested – and hopefully confirmed - in other agencies
within the same distributive type of policies) between the agency / ministry / parliament… while in
regulatory areas it is an “imposition relationship”. Cells will be filled after the case study. Option 1:
RQ: What is role of agencies in policy-making? How can differences be explained?
Policy domain
Distributive
Example of an agency
Tax agency
special taxes)
Policy style
Redistributive
Regulatory
(VAT, Agency in charge of Regulatory agency on
social benefits
telecommunications
Consensual
Imposition
relationship
Fictional example. Attribution of examples is controversial..
In option 2, the theoretical framework already gives the options for other arenas (intergovernmental
relations, for instance) and one has to confirm the hypotheses for the ministry-agency relationships.
Cells are filled previous to the study. In both cases, the theoretical implications of the model as well
as the likely results of crossing the independent variable with the dependent variable should be
refined after a primary familiarisation with the case study materials.
Option 2: RQ: What is role of agencies in policy-making? How can differences be explained?
Policy domain
Distributive
Redistributive
Regulatory
Example of an agency
Policy style
Tax agency
special taxes)
Consensus-imposition
Consensual
Consensual
Imposition
Action-reaction
Active
Reactive
Active
(VAT, Agency in charge of Regulatory agency on
social benefits
telecommunications
7
Fictional example. Attribution of examples is controversial.
Describing the variance in variables
The description of the variance is useful for furthering the development of new theories or the
assessment or refinement of existing theories. The process of describing the variance could be
iterative and be modified after some preliminary research has been undertaken. Some relevant
dimensions are:

The variance can be described in quantitative and qualitative terms. In any case, a decision
should be made in order to establish dichotomous or multi-category variables.

The differentiation of types can be applied to the independent or the dependent variable
It has not been applied to the Action COST project.
Formulation of data requirements and general questions
Data requirements should take the form of general questions to be asked for each case. Questions
should not be crafted in specific terms that are only relevant to the case study in question. In
addition to this, the researcher should bring to the case those idiosyncratic that help to explain the
case, to be of interest for theory development or for future research.
In order to look for adequate data and to frame general questions, the following concepts might be
of help.
It has not been applied to the Action COST project.
CONSIDERATIONS FOR CASE STUDY DESIGN
Causal mechanisms and process tracing: clarification notes
The definition of (Mahoney, 2001 p. 580) suggests that “a causal mechanism is an unobserved
entity that-when activated-generates an outcome of interest.” Casual mechanisms will be of interest
in case studies because these unobserved entities (distribution of power for instance) will be
responsible for outcomes. Ideally, we should be able to identify a difference in the outcome
previous and after the causal mechanism took place. For that reason, it is important to define first
the causal effect or outcome. The causal mechanism works as “X leads to Y through steps A, B, C”.
Among the numerous problems linked to causal mechanism, one of them is to decide at what
(micro) level stops the search for the causal mechanism (rational choicers stop at the individual
level!).
Causal mechanisms depend on the presence of other mechanisms or on the context. Context, then,
should be specified in order to understand when a particular causal mechanism is taking place.
A change of outcome might be produced by different causal mechanisms, and not always by a
single causal pattern. This is known as equifinality (or multiple causality): when different causal
patterns can lead to similar outcomes.
(George and Bennett, 2005 206) also define process tracing as an important way to dig into case
studies. “Process tracing is a method that attempts to identify the intervening causal process – the
causal chain and causal mechanism- between an independent variable (or variables) and the
outcome of the dependent variable.” (p. 207) “Process-tracing forces the investigator to take
8
equifinality into account, that is, to consider the alternatives paths through which the outcome could
have occurred, and it offers the possibility of mapping out one or more potential causal paths that
are consistent with the outcome and the process-tracing evidence in a single case. With more cases,
the investigator can begin to chart the repertoire of causal paths that lead to a given outcome and the
conditions under which they occur- that is, to develop a typological theory.” “In process tracing, all
the intervening steps in a case must be as predicted by a hypothesis, or else that hypothesis must be
amended- perhaps trivially or perhaps fundamentally- to explain the case. It is not sufficient that a
hypothesis be consistent with a statistically significant number of intervening steps.”
Typological theory: clarification notes
(George and Bennett, 2005 pp. 235-ff.) maintain that, “in contrast to a general explanatory theory of
a given phenomenon, typological theory provides a rich and differentiated depiction of a
phenomenon and can generate discriminating and contingent explanations and policy
recommendations.” Typological theory is “a theory that specifies independent variables, delineates
them into categories for which the researcher will measure the cases and their outcomes, and
provides not only hypotheses on how these variables operate individually, but also contingent
generalizations on how and under what conditions they behave in specified conjunctions or
configurations to produce effects on specified dependent variables.” “These categories of the
variables for which the cases are to be measured could be nominal (such as democracy or
nondemocracy), ordinal (such as high, medium, or low ranking of states in their protection of
human rights), or interval (such as ranking percentiles of states by GNP per capita).”
(p.238) “In a typology, in contrast to a typological theory, the constituent characteristics or
combinations of factors are not necessarily theoretical variables. This is likely to be the case when
the typology has not been developed within a theoretical framework. Nor does a typology itself link
independent and dependent variables in a causal relationship. Types and typologies are at best only
implicit theories or starting points for theory construction.”
(p. 239) Case studies can contribute to the inductive development of typological theories in the
early stages of a research program by identifying an initial list of possible theoretical variables.
(p. 244) “In contrast to the inductive method, the deductive approach requires that the investigator
first construct a theory-based map of the property space by defining variables and the types these
variables constitute through all their mathematically possible configurations. Such a framework can
then be reduced to the most useful types for the purposes of research design, case selection, and
theory development”.
APPENDIX - RESEARCH QUESTIONS FROM COST ACTION PARTICIPANTS
1. When was the ‘autonomous agency model’ introduced in the country under study? How can we
explain the adoption of this model in this country, at that time? For example, what was the political
and economic context at the time? Did NPM ideas play a role? To what extent does agencification
fit with existing politico-administrative traditions?
2. Why and under which conditions do politicians choose to create autonomous agencies? How can
their decision be explained, e.g. is it a paradigm shift, or was it induced by self-serving motives?
3. How many and what type of autonomous agencies exist in the countries under study? And at
which levels of government do agencies exist?
4. How can the institutional design of autonomous agencies be described, for example in
comparison to other countries? For example, what is their legal status, hierarchical subordination,
legal position of staff, way of financing, supervision arrangements, etc.?
9
5. What types and degrees of autonomy are attributed to autonomous agencies? How can this be
measured? Are there different types and degrees of freedom for different types of agencies (task,
size, policy sector, legal status), and if so how can these be explained?
6. How do politicians and parent departments steer/control/manage autonomous agencies? What
kind of steering instruments are used or have been developed for this purpose (ex ante, ex post,
performance indicators, contracts, and so on)?
7. How do agencies and parent departments balance the trade-off between autonomy and control
(accountability, steering, audit, board, patronage)? What (new) instruments are developed for this
purpose (e.g. new forms of accountability)? How do agencies cope with the actors and pressures of
their environment (‘fit’)?
8. What coordination trajectories have been followed in several countries?
9. How specialisation affects coordination?
10. What is the impact of autonomy on performance?
Most questions above can be summarised in the three questions that (Pollitt, 2004) have used for
their research:
Why has the agency form become so popular?
How can agencies be best steered?
Under what conditions do agencies perform best?
10
Main research questions and more specific subquestions of the Cost Action
Table 1 presents the broader research framework and refers to the 5 basic research questions. In
table 1 we have tried to elaborate these research questions in more specific subquestions for the two
basic themes (autonomy and control on the one hand and proliferation and coordination on the other
hand).
General and specific research questions General and specific research questions
on
Autonomy,
control
and on Proliferation, coordination and
organisational performance (WG1)
systemic performance (WG2)
1. Descriptive WHAT-question: What is happening ?
 over time, space and tasks.
1.1. On the level of ideas
1.1. On the level of ideas
When was the ‘autonomous agency model’ (or
models) introduced in the country under study?
What are the characteristics of this model? On what
kind of normative ideas is this model based? What
are the normative ideas about autonomy and control
of public sector organisations?
What are the normative ideas about proliferation
and coordination of public sector organisations?
(e.g. Is there a preference for more hierarchical
ways of governance and coordination, or rather
market- or network-based ways?). How does this
evolve over time?
 document and discourse analysis, interviews with
key respondents …
 document and discourse analysis, interviews with
key respondents …
1.2. On the level of general mapping of agencies
and agency-related reforms
1.2. On the level of general mapping of agencies
and agency-related reforms
How many and what types of autonomous agencies
(or more general public sector organizations) exist
in the countries under study? How does their
institutional design look like1? In which policy
fields and with which tasks? What is their
importance in the state apparatus?
What is the proliferation of public sector
organisations and agency-like bodies (in general, in
different policy fields, with different tasks) ?
What is the evolution of agencies over time?
 document
respondents …
analysis,
interviews
with
key
 document
respondents …
analysis,
interviews
with
key
 answers to these questions can be largely based
on
the
mapping
van
public
sector
organisations/agencies (see question 1.2. within the
theme on autonomy and control)
1.3. On the level of individual agencies
1.3. On the level of groups of agencies
What is the level of autonomy of these bodies? How
are these bodies controlled by their political
How are these bodies coordinated by their political
principals/parent department/ central departments/
other actors (vertical coordination)? How do they
1
How can the institutional design of autonomous agencies be described, for example in comparison to other countries?
For example, what is their legal status, hierarchical subordination, legal position of staff, way of financing, supervision
arrangements, etc.?
11
General and specific research questions General and specific research questions
on
Autonomy,
control
and on Proliferation, coordination and
organisational performance (WG1)
systemic performance (WG2)
principals/parent department/ other actors?
How does this change over time, policy fields and
tasks?2
 survey (e.g. COBRA) or case studies …
coordinate and collaborate among themselves
(horizontal coordination)? What instruments and
mechanisms of coordination are used to join up
actors in a specific policy field?
How does this change over time and tasks?
 survey (e.g. COBRA) or case studies …
2. Explanatory WHY-question: Why is this happening? – Why is this like that?
2.1. On the level of ideas
2.1. On the level of ideas
How can we explain the adoption of the
‘autonomous agency’ model in this country, at that
time? For example, what was the political and
economic context at the time? Did NPM ideas play
a role? To what extent does agencification fit with
existing politico-administrative traditions?3 
document and discourse analysis, interviews with
key respondents …
How can we explain the adoption of a specific
coordination model in this country, at that time? For
example, what was the political and economic
context at the time? Did NPM ideas play a role? To
what extent does the type and shift of coordination
fit with existing politico-administrative traditions?
2.2. On the level of general mapping of agencies
and agency-related reforms
-
 document and discourse analysis, interviews with
key respondents …
Why and under which conditions do politicians
choose to create autonomous agencies? How can
their decision be explained, e.g. is it a paradigm
shift, or was it induced by self-serving motives4?
 document analysis, interviews
respondents, case studies …
with
key
2.3. On the level of individual agencies
2.3. On the level of groups of agencies
Which factors (e.g. task, date of creation, policy
field...) help to explain the level of autonomy and
the kind of control of these bodies ?
Why are specific instruments and mechanisms of
vertical/horizontal coordination used in specific
circumstances (e.g. in different policy fields)? How
2
What types and degrees of autonomy are attributed to autonomous agencies? How can this be measured? Are there
different types and degrees of freedom for different types of agencies (task, size, policy sector, legal status), and if so
how can these be explained? (See review note of WG leaders on autonomy and control for the meeting in Madrid
written by van Thiel, Barbieri and Yesilkagit)
How do politicians and parent departments steer/control/manage autonomous agencies? What kind of steering
instruments are used or have been developed for this purpose (ex ante, ex post, performance indicators, contracts, and
so on)?
How do agencies and parent departments balance the trade-off between autonomy and control (accountability, steering,
audit, board, patronage)? What (new) instruments are developed for this purpose (e.g. new forms of accountability)?
How do agencies cope with the actors and pressures of their environment (‘fit’)? (See review note of WG leaders on
autonomy and control for the meeting in Madrid written by van Thiel, Barbieri and Yesilkagit)
3
See review note of WG leaders on autonomy and control for the meeting in Madrid written by van Thiel, Barbieri and
Yesilkagit.
4
See review note of WG leaders on autonomy and control for the meeting in Madrid written by van Thiel, Barbieri and
Yesilkagit.
12
General and specific research questions General and specific research questions
on
Autonomy,
control
and on Proliferation, coordination and
organisational performance (WG1)
systemic performance (WG2)
 survey (e.g. COBRA) or case studies …
can we explain shifts over time with regards to the
mechanisms and instruments of coordination used?
 case studies or survey …
3. Evaluative EFFECT-question: What are the effects of this?
3.1. What is the effect of agencification on the
functioning and performance of agencies? What is
the effect of autonomy and specific ways of control?
What are strengths and weaknesses?
 survey (e.g. COBRA) or case studies (document
analysis, interviews) …
3.1. What is the effect of proliferation and
coordination on the performance at the level of
policy sectors or groups of organisations? What is
the effect of specific ways of coordination? What
are strengths and weaknesses?
 case studies (document analysis, interviews) or
surveys…
3.2. How to measure organizational performance?
3.2. How to measure systemic performance?
Elements like
COBRA)5:
Elements like (see e.g. literature on coordination
and on network performance):
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
(see
Boyne
2002/2003;
see
Internal management
Outputs: quantity and quality of services
Efficiency: input/output ratios
Effectiveness: achievement of formal goals
Responsiveness: including satisfaction by users,
citizens, staff
Democratic outcomes: accountability, equity,
probity, participation
Impact
•
•
•
•
•
•
Degree of actual level of cooperation and
collaboration between actors
Strengths of networks
Extent of well-coordinated policy / uniformity
in implementation
Policy impact and effectiveness....
Accountability at the level of policy sectors
Stability / flexibility of the system
4. Normative question: How should it optimally be? What can we learn for practice?
4.1. What lessons can we learn for the practice of
agencification, agency autonomy and control?
4.1. What lessons can we learn for the practice of
agency coordination?
5. Conceptual and theoretical question: What theories have most explanatory power in this regard?
5.1. What concepts and theories are appropriate to
interpret and explain
5.1. What concepts and theories are appropriate to
interpret and explain
- changes in ideas
- changes in ideas
- creation of agencies
- proliferation of agencies
- level of autonomy and control
- (changes in) level and kind of coordination
- effect of agencification, autonomy and control
- effect of proliferation and coordination
Table 1. detailed research questions
5
See the review note on performance related research by Hammerschmidt and Randma for the meeting in Madrid
13
14
LITERATURE
Aberbach, J. D., Putnam, R. D. and Rockman, B. A. (1981) Bureaucrats and politicians in western
democracies. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Barzelay, M. (2007) 'Learning from Second-Hand Experience: Methodology for ExtrapolationOriented Case Research', Governance, 20 (3), 521.
Dunleavy, P. (1991) Democracy, bureaucracy, and public choice : economic explanations in
political science. London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Gehring, T. (2004) 'The consequences of delegation to independent agencies: Separation of powers,
discursive governance and the regulation of telecommunications in Germany', European Journal of
Political Research, 43 (4), 677-698.
George, A. L. and Bennett, A. (2005) Case studies and theory development in the social sciences.
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Gerring, J. (2007) Case study research : principles and practices. Cambridge ; New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Hood, C. and Lodge, M. (2006) The politics of public service bargains : reward, competency,
loyalty - and blame. Oxford ; New York: Oxford University Press.
Lijphart, A. (1971) 'Comparative Politics and the Comparative Method', The American Political
Science Review, 65 (3), 682-693.
Mahoney, J. (2001) 'Beyond Correlational Analysis Recent Innovations in Theory and Method',
Sociological Forum, 16 (3), 575.
Pollitt, C. (2004) Agencies : how governments do things through semi-autonomous organizations.
Hounmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire ; New York, N.Y.: Palgrave Macmillan.
Richardson, J. J. (1982) Policy styles in Western Europe. London ; Boston: Allen & Unwin.
Seawright, J. and Gerring, J. (2008) 'Case Selection Techniques in Case Study Research: A Menu of
Qualitative and Quantitative Options', Political Research Quarterly, 61 (2), 294.
Wilson, J. Q. (1989) Bureaucracy : what government agencies do and why they do it. New York:
Basic Books.
15
Download