The Favorable Impact of Index-Based Livestock Insurance (IBLI): Results among Ethiopian and Kenyan Pastoralists Christopher B. Barrett, Cornell University Seminar at USAID Headquarters, Washington, DC February 10, 2015 Motivation: Poverty Traps And Catastrophic Risk There is strong evidence of poverty traps in the arid and semi-arid lands (ASAL) of northern Kenya and southern Ethiopia. These put a premium on risk mgmt. Catastrophic herd loss risk due to major droughts identified as the major cause of these dynamics. Source: Lybbert et al. (2004 EJ) on Boran pastoralists in s. Ethiopia. See also Barrett et al. (2006 JDS) among n. Kenyan pastoralists, Santos & Barrett (2011 JDE) on s. Ethiopian Boran. Motivation: Increased Risk From Climate Change Pastoralist systems adapted to climate regime. But resilient to a shift in climate? Many models predict increased rainfall variability (i.e., increased risk of drought). Herd dynamics differ b/n good and poor rainfall states, and so change with drought (<250 mm/ year) risk. In southern Ethiopia, doubling drought risk would lead to system collapse in expectation in the absence of any change to prevailing herd dynamics. Source: Barrett and Santos (EcolEcon 2014) Motivation: Standard Responses to Drought Standard responses to major drought shocks: 1) Post-drought restocking 2) Food aid Key Problems: - Slow Expensive (in part, because it’s slow) Targeting challenges Food aid can reinforce sedentarization/foster dependency Core issue: If transfers go only to the poor who are already in the poverty trap, the numbers of poor will grow as shocks knock others below the poverty trap threshold. In the longrun, the ex ante poor worse off as others join their ranks and compete for scarce social assistance resources. (see Barrett, Carter & Ikegami 2012 for more general theory/illustrations) Alternative Responses: Insurance? Commercially sustainable insurance can: • • • • Prevent downward slide of vulnerable populations Crowd-in investment and accumulation by the poor Induce financial deepening by crowding-in credit Let us focus humanitarian resources on the needy But can insurance be sustainably offered in the ASAL? Conventional (individual) insurance unlikely to work, especially in small scale pastoral/agro-pastoral sector: • Very high transactions costs, esp. w/little financial intermediation among pastoralists • Moral hazard/adverse selection The Potential of Index Insurance Index insurance is a variation on traditional insurance: - Do not insure individual losses. - Instead insure some “index” measure that is strongly correlated with individual losses. (Examples: rainfall, remotely sensed vegetation index, area average yield, area average herd mortality loss). - Index needs to be: - objectively verifiable - available at low cost in real time - not manipulable by either party to the contract The Potential of Index Insurance Index insurance can obviate the problems that make individual insurance unprofitable for small, remote clients: - No transactions costs of measuring individual losses - Preserves effort incentives (no moral hazard) as no single individual can influence index - Adverse selection does not matter as payouts do not depend on the riskiness of those who buy the insurance Index insurance can, in principle, be used to create a timely, financially sustainable, self-targeting safety net to protect pastoralists against catastrophic drought shocks. Could also accelerate herd recovery, altering herd dynamics and averting system collapse if drought frequency increases. Perhaps crowd in value-adding investments, too! The Major Challenges of Index Insurance 1. High quality data (reliable, timely, non-manipulable, longterm) to design/price product and to determine payouts 2. Minimize uncovered basis risk through product design. Is it insurance or a lottery ticket? All turns on basis risk!!! 3. Innovation incentives for insurers/reinsurers to design and market a new product and global market to support it 4. Establish informed effective demand, especially among a clientele with little experience with any insurance, much less a complex index-based insurance product 5. Low cost delivery mechanism for making insurance available for numerous small and medium scale producers Index-Based Livestock Insurance: Design The signal: Normalized Difference Vegetation Index (NDVI) collected by satellite Response function: regress historic livestock mortality onto transforms of historic cumulative standardized NDVI (Czndvi) data. In Borana, just NDVI. Designed to minimize household-level basis risk. Indemnity payments: In Kenya,(Jensen, predicted livestock Barrett &2014)mortality >15% according to: πππ₯ πππππ₯π,π‘ (πΏπ,π‘ , ππ,π‘ ) − 0.15, 0 ∗ π£πππ’π ππ πππ£ππ π‘πππ πππ π’πππ 1 year contract coverage Temporal Structure of IBLI contract: 12 month contract sold during 2month sales windows just prior to usual start of seasonal rains. Payouts March 1 and/or October 1. Chantarat et al. JRI 2013 LRLD season coverage Jan Feb Sale period For LRLD Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug SRSD season coverage Sep Oct Nov Dec Jan Feb Period of NDVI observations for constructing LRLD mortality index Sale period For SRSD Period of NDVI observations For constructing SRSD mortality index Predicted LRLD mortality is announced. Indemnity payment is made if IBLI is triggered Predicted SRSD mortality is announced. Indemnity payment is made if IBLI is triggered Index-Based Livestock Insurance: Implementation Commercial underwriters: In Kenya: UAP, APA, Takaful. In Ethiopia: OIC International reinsurers: Swiss Re, Africa Re Lots of implementation challenges IBLI team developed extension/(Jensen, Barrett &2014) financial education programs to (randomly) inform prospective buyers. IBLI team (randomly) distributed discount coupons to induce uptake and to establish price elasticity of demand. Payouts in Kenya in Oct 2011, Mar 2012 Payouts in Ethiopia in Nov 2014 IBLI Pilots in Ethiopia and Kenya IBLI products (surveys) launched in Marsabit, Kenya in Jan 2010 (Oct 2009) and in Borana, Ethiopia, in Aug 2012 (Mar 2012). (Jensen, Barrett &2014) Kenya sampling overlaid with HSNP coverage as research design. IBLI: Significant Basis Risk Remains Covariate risk is important but household losses vary a lot … and the index does not perfectly track covariate losses. (Jensen, Barrett & Mude 2014) Notes: The left figure illustrates the covariate (average) loss rate in each season. The right figure illustrates the distribution of losses within each seasons. The boxes depict the interquartile range, the upper and lower adjacent values are either 3/2 the interquartile range or the value furthest from the median. The remaining observations fall outside the adjacent values. Notes: Covariate loss-index observations are seasonal division average mortality paired with the index value for that divisionseason. Fitted lines and confidence intervals are generated by regressing livestock mortality rates on the index. - IBLI hhs still hold most risk: 62-77% of total risk exposure remains - Most basis risk is idiosyncratic and random, not targetable or correctable. - Significant spatial variation in covariate share – geographically target IBLI? Jensen, Barrett & Mude 2014 IBLI: A Highly Imperfect Product Because of basis risk, esp. false negatives, IBLI cannot stochastically dominate no insurance. (Jensen, Barrett & Histograms of livestock survival rate and net livestock survival rate with full insurance. Tally to the left of zero, between zero and one, and to the right of one are in green. Survival rate w/o insurance (L) and net of prem/indemnity payments w/IBLI (R). Note: - small probability of negative survival rates! - increased dispersion of outcomes due to false payments>losses Jensen, Barrett & Mude 2014 IBLI Uptake Significant … But So Is Disadoption In HH surveys , in Borana (Ethiopia)/Marsabit (Kenya): - 54/44% ever purchased IBLI within first 4 sales periods - But repurchase rates low: 18-68%/16-27% - High rates of disadoption : 26/41% within 2 years IBLI Uptake Is Also Predictable … Capacity to predict uptake patterns is reasonably strong: Unconditional observed / predicted (Cond. FE) likelihood of buying IBLI Observed / predicted (Cond. FE) level of purchases (|buying IBLI) Key determinants of IBLI uptake General uptake findings — robust across specifications and surveys Price: Responsive to premium rate (price inelastic). Price elasticity grows w/design risk. Design Risk: Design error reduces uptake; greater effect at higher premium rates. Idiosyncratic Risk: Hh understanding of IBLI increases effect of idiosyncratic risk Understanding: Extension/marketing improves accuracy of IBLI knowledge but no independent effect of improved understanding on uptake. Herd size: Likelihood of uptake increasing in HH herd size Liquidity: IBLI purchase increasing w/HSNP participation Intertemporal Adverse Selection: HHs buy less when expecting good conditions. Spatial Adverse Selection: Divisions with relatively more covariate risk see higher uptake and level of coverage increases with variation in division average losses. Gender: no gender diff in uptake. Women more sensitive to risk of new product. Bageant 2014; Jensen, Mude & Barrett 2014; Takahashi et al. 2014 IBLI’s Impacts: Herd mortality risk Proportion of households for whom IBLI improves their position with respect to each statistic Statistic Proportion Loaded Subsidized Proportion of households that are better off with IBLI& than without (Simulated utility analysis) Mean Variance Skewness Semi-Variance Unsubsidized 0.232 0.359 0.817 0.374 1.000 0.359 0.817 0.609 Jensen, Barrett & Mude 2014 IBLI’s Impacts: Livestock productivity/income Dependent Variable Production strategies: Herd Size Veterinary Expenditures (KSH) Household is Partially or Fully Mobile Production outcomes: Milk income (KSH) Milk income per TLU (KSH) HSNP Cumulative Past Current Participation Client IBLI Cumulative Current Coverage Past Coverage (TLU) 0.0583 (0.470) -2.531 (2.963) [4.693] -5.634*** (1.970) -0.270 (0.693) [3.543] 48.22 (57.48) 261.6 (363.9) [13.78] 584.8* (324.7) -46.21 (127.2) [15.17] 0.0376** (0.0172) 0.251*** (0.0686) [17.76] -0.0669 (0.111) 0.0386 (0.0481) [14.86] 193.6 (275.6) 307.0 (1,039) [11.94] 1,688* (970.0) 840.6* (473.6) [11.46] 63.65*** (20.14) -97.35 423.5*** 63.81 (79.24) (118.1) (47.23) [14.72] [13.05] A complete list of covariates, coefficient estimates, and model statistics can be found in Jensen, Mude & Barrett (2014). Clustered and robust standard errors in parentheses. Model F-stat in brackets. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. HSNP Participation: •Improves the likelihood that target type (poor, old, many dependents) households remain mobile, an important characteristic for pastoralists IBLI coverage: •Increases investments in maintaining livestock through vet expenditures •Increases total and per TLU income from milk. Note: TLU veterinary expenditures are pos/sign related to milk productivity Jensen, Barrett & Mude 2014 IBLI’s Impacts vs. HSNP: Normalized by cost Cost structure Total Program Cost/Participant Marginal Cost of an Additional Participant Income from Milk Impact Impact/ KSH 992 0.021 2,631 0.067 992 2,631 0.031 1.667 Income per AE Impact Impact/ KSH1 394 0.083 263 0.070 394 263 0.124 1.666 MUAC Impact Impact/ KSH2 1.097 0.022 0.337 0.026 1.097 0.337 0.033 0.623 All in real 2009 Kenya Shillings. Impacts are estimated using the average client value and costs provided below, and parameter estimates in the previous two slides. 1Results are multiplied by 10. 2Results are multiplied by 1,000. Average values (final survey round, clients) VOI Mean VOI in Final Period HSNP 0.86 HSNPC 3.76 IBLI 0.60 IBLIC 1.26 Values are calculated for the subset of clients in each program. Average cumulative cost/client by the final round (KSH) HSNP Total Program 47,600 Cost/Participant (2.7BN/57,811 HH) Marginal Cost of an Additional Participant 31,700 (13.9 transfers) IBLI 43,200 (99MM/3,297 contracts*1.44 contract/HH) 1,580 (3.25 TLUs) Jensen, Barrett & Mude 2014 IBLI’s Impacts vs. HSNP: Normalized by cost Total Program Cost/Participant Income from Milk Impact/ Impact KSH 992 0.021 2,631 0.067 Marginal Cost of an Additional Participant 992 2,631 Cost structure 0.031 1.667 Income per AE Impact Impact/ KSH1 394 0.083 263 0.070 394 263 0.124 1.666 MUAC Impact Impact/ KSH2 1.097 0.022 0.337 0.026 1.097 0.337 0.033 0.623 All in real 2009 Kenya Shillings. Impacts are estimated using the average client value and costs provided below, and parameter estimates in the previous two slides. 1Results are multiplied by 10. 2Results are multiplied by 1,000. Average values (final survey round, clients) VOI Mean VOI in Final Period HSNP 0.86 HSNPC 3.76 IBLI 0.60 IBLIC 1.26 Values are calculated for the subset of clients in each program. Average cumulative cost/client by the final round (KSH) HSNP Total Program 47,600 Cost/Participant (2.7BN/57,811 HH) Marginal Cost of an Additional Participant 31,700 (13.9 transfers) IBLI 43,200 (99MM/3,297 contracts*1.44 contract/HH) 1,580 (3.25 TLUs) Jensen, Barrett & Mude 2014 IBLI’s Impacts: Less adverse post-drought coping Marsabit HHs received IBLI indemnity payments in October 2011, near end of major drought. Survey HHs with IBLI coverage report much better expected behaviors/outcomes than the uninsured: - 36% reduction in likelihood of distress livestock sales, especially (64%) among modestly better-off HHs (>8.4 TLU) - 25% reduction in likelihood of reducing meals as a coping strategy, especially (43%) among those with small or no herds IBLI appears to provide a flexible safety net, reducing reliance on the most adverse behaviors undertaken by different groups. Janzen & Carter 2013 NBER IBLI’s Impacts: Household subjective well-being Borana survey HHs report overall life satisfaction. In principle, insurance helps risk averse people even when it doesn’t pay out. But an imperfect product with commercial loadings might not. There had been no payout in Ethiopia (pre-11/14). So use subjective well-being measures to assess welfare gains even w/o indemnities. To deal with potential heterogeneity problems associated with SWB (attitudinal measures), we correct our SWB measures using hypothetical vignettes, using current best practice, and verify with alternative measures to ensure robustness of findings. Hirfrot , Barrett, Lentz and Taddesse. 2014 IBLI’s Impacts: Household subjective well-being Use randomized treatments to instrument for IBLI and then estimate: πππ΅ππ£π‘ = πΌ + π½ πΌπ΅πΏπΌππ£π‘ + π ππΏπππ£π‘ + ππΌπ΅πΏπΌππ£π‘−1 + πΏ`πππ£π‘ + πΎπ + π π£ + πππ£π‘ There are at least two ways IBLI can influence SWB: 1) Non-monetary (psychological) benefits or costs • Insurance may give peace of mind about adverse outcomes (π½ > 0) • Insurance could increase stress if basis risk is high (π½ < 0) • Buyer’s remorse: π < 0 2) Monetary benefits or costs – effect on net income/wealth • Since premium payment reduces net income/wealth, indemnity payment increases it, net indemnity payments will influence SWB. • This effect is captured by π. Hirfrot , Barrett, Lentz and Taddesse. 2014 IBLI’s Impacts: Household subjective well-being Ordered logit regression estimates (extensive margin) Dependent variable: Vignette corrected SWB Predicted IBLI uptake Model (1) 0.825*** (0.288) -0.453*** (0.157) 0.015** (0.007) Model (2) Model (3) 0.746*** 0.894*** (0.235) (0.269) Predicted lapsed IBLI -0.463*** -0.469*** (0.166) (0.170) Number of TLU owned 0.013* 0.013* (0.007) (0.007) Asset index 0.287*** 0.243*** (0.066) (0.067) Annual income (‘000 Birr) 0.003 0.003 (0.005) (0.005) Controls No No Yes Reera fixed effect No No Yes Observations 1,530 1,530 1,530 Number of groups (households) 550 550 550 Clustered standard errors in Parenthesis; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Controls : Household head gender, age, age squared, schooling, household size, and household composition. •IBLI has +++ effect on SWB •Sig. buyer’s remorse effect •But + peace of mind effect >> - buyer’s remorse effect Hirfrot , Barrett, Lentz and Taddesse. 2014 IBLI’s Impacts: Household subjective well-being Ordered logit regression estimates (intensive margin) Dependent variable: Vignette corrected SWB Predicted TLUs insured Model (1) 0.126*** (0.035) -0.073*** (0.022) 0.015** (0.007) Model (2) Model (3) 0.131*** 0.136*** (0.033) (0.033) Predicted lapsed TLUs -0.071*** -0.074*** (0.023) (0.023) Number of TLU owned 0.012* 0.013* (0.007) (0.007) Asset index 0.331*** 0.295*** (0.066) (0.066) Annual income (‘000 Birr) 0.003 0.003 (0.005) (0.005) Controls No No Yes Reera fixed effect No No Yes Observations 1,530 1,530 1,530 Number of groups (households) 550 550 550 Clustered standard errors in Parenthesis; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Controls : Household head gender, age, age squared, schooling, household size, and household composition. •IBLI has +++ effect on SWB •Sig. buyer’s remorse effect •But + peace of mind effect >> - buyer’s remorse effect Hirfrot , Barrett, Lentz and Taddesse. 2014 IBLI’s Impacts: Household subjective well-being • IBLI has a positive, statistically significant effect on HH wellbeing, even after premium payment and w/o any indemnity payments • IBLI coverage for 3 TLU moves a HH 1 step up the SWB scale • Insuring 15 TLU (roughly baseline sample mean) shifts HH from lowest to highest SWB category • Ex post of contract, purchasers exhibit some buyer’s remorse in the absence of indemnity payments. • But the positive effect of IBLI coverage is significantly higher than the negative effect of buyer’s remorse. Even with prospective buyer’s remorse, IBLI purchase improves subjective well-being. Hirfrot , Barrett, Lentz and Taddesse. 2014 Although IBLI offers incomplete coverage against herd loss and will not help all people, uptake is solid and IBLI has clear favorable impacts on purchasers. IBLI offers a promising option for addressing poverty traps that arise from catastrophic drought risk … and impacts/$ > cash transfers Thank you for your time, interest and comments! For more information visit www.ilri.org/ibli/