ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013 David S. Evans University of Chicago, Global Economics Group TOPIC 9: Date Elisa Mariscal CIDE, Global Economics Group CARTELS AND COORDINATED EFFECTS Topic 9 | Part 2 5 September 2013 Your CPI teaching team Professor David S. Evans devans@globaleconomicsgroup.com Professor Elisa Mariscal emariscal@competitionpolicyinternational.com Teaching assistant Mr. Alexis Pirchio apirchio@competitionpolicyinternational.com Course Support Ms. Meara Hamidiani CPI Community Manager mhamidiani@competitionpolicyinternational.com Overview 3 Part 1 Part 2 Replicating the monopoly outcome with a Cartel Explicit collusion: Detecting cartels The incentives to cheat Discouraging cartels: Leniency programs Methods to detect and punish cheaters Punishment and damages Factors that make collusion easier Cooperating for procompetitive reasons Guest Speaker: Screening techniques 4 Explicit Collusion: Detecting Cartels Explicit vs. Tacit Collusion 5 Explicit collusion is the result of an agreement to fix price, divide markets, or otherwise achieve a non-competitive outcome. It requires direct communication between the cartel members. Tacit collusion refers to market interactions between firms that encourage them to keep prices high and discourages them from competing. For example, if all firms believe that a reduction of price will trigger a price war in which they will lose, none will reduce price. In the US and most jurisdictions only explicit collusion is unlawful. In effect, the law doesn’t prohibit “collusion” so much as it prohibits the use of explicit communication to facilitate that collusion. We focus on explicit collusion but some of the economic analysis is equally applicable to tacit collusion. Caught in the Act 6 YAMAMOTO: Sales meeting, huh? (Laughs). CHAUDRET: Well, it's easy to know the price, so everything's clear. MIMOTO: And one from FBI. (Laughs). YAMAMOTO: (ui) joke. WHITACRE: And seven from the FTC. MIMOTO: Yeah. FTC. (Laughs). WHITACRE: FBI. MIMOTO: Seven from FTC. (Laughs). SHINOHARA: Well, I also feel cautious in the way I came into this, uh, hotel. I actually... (Laughs). (ui). CHAUDRET: In Europe, we... SHINOHARA: You know and, uh, (ui). CHAUDRET: Even in Europe now, they're cracking down. WHITACRE: Everyone has to be careful. SHINOHARA: Oh, yes. WHITACRE: When we leave, we're better off to leave separately Detection of Explicit Collusion In Practice 7 An entrant who hasn’t been part of the cartel is solicited and reports this to the authorities. Customers become suspicious about the prices they are being charged or the bids they are getting. Disgruntled employees who know about the cartel report it. The authorities become suspicious because of institutions or contract features that encourage collusion or punish cheaters. Members of cartel approach authorities as part of a “leniency program” which reduces penalties on those who report it. What Can Competition Authorities Do? 8 Head them off at the pass •Forbid/limit practices that facilitate cartels (Information exchange, MFNs, RPM— but are these practices ever efficient?) •Prohibit mergers that will facilitate collusion (e.g. ones that eliminate a maverick player or increase the likelihood of coordinated effects) Hunt them down •Focus investigative efforts on industries that have features that facilitate cartels—but are these cartels the most damaging or the easier ones to detect? •Screening technologies (our guest speaker will elaborate)* •Dawn raids when enough suspicion—requires specialized know-how and can be legally challenging in some jurisdictions Get them to squeal •Encourage cartel members to report each other (leniency programs) •Get employees to be “whistleblowers” Carry a big stick •Fines •Jail •Debarment Head Them Off At The Pass: Facilitating Practices 9 A facilitating practice is an activity that makes collusion more likely or more effective, either by making coordination easier or making it easier to sustain a collusive agreement. A facilitating practice may be prosecuted either as an anticompetitive agreement in and of itself or as circumstantial evidence of price fixing. Some examples include: • Information exchange of current individual firm sales or prices • Announcements of future price changes • List (or posted) pricing with no discounts • Most favored consumer clauses, meeting competition clauses • Delivered or basing point pricing Information Exchange Agreements Help Collusion 10 Exchanging future pricing intentions help coordinate price Exchanging past prices help police price agreement Exchanging demand and cost data so that firms have: • A more common set of beliefs (this makes it more likely that, without express communication, they can settle on the same collusive price) • More precise estimates of demand Information Exchange Agreements: Cons 11 They can circumvent cartel prohibition • In the UK Cartels became illegal with the Restrictive Trade Practices Act of 1956… Subsequently, as much as 50% of British industry adopted information exchange agreements. They can be a creative way of monitoring and enforcing a price fixing agreement, e.g. Maple Flooring Association (US) • 1916-21: MFA establishes a minimum RPM for the sale of maple and birch flooring supported by severe financial penalties for deviators. • Jan 1921: After a government investigation, MFA abandons the price floor policy, and institutes an information sharing system. • Supreme Court ruled in favor of the defendants– the DOJ did not prove the companies used information to collude in prices and production. Information Exchange Agreements: Pros 12 Sharing past sales and profits can be used for benchmarking and establishing relative performance contracts. Sharing past prices and sales allow firms to more accurately estimate current demand. •Industry profit and welfare effects are ambiguous. Knowledge of past prices may assist consumers in bargaining with firms. •Positive welfare effect as prices are reduced •Not in the best interest of firms to make this information public Hunt Them Down: Detecting Cartels 13 Stages in the process: screen, verify, prosecute • Screening: Identifying markets where collusion is suspected. • Verification: Systematically distinguish between collusion and competition. • Prosecution: Developing economic evidence to determine guilt. Two empirical methods for screening: structural, behavioral • Structural: Identifying industry traits conducive to collusion. • Behavioral: Identifying collusive behavioral patterns. Structural Approaches 14 Structural approaches identify markets with traits conducive to the formation of a cartel. Problem of too many false positives • Imagine the “ideal” market for collusion: Two firms, homogeneous products, stable demand, etc. • In practice, only a small fraction of such markets probably have cartels. • The reason is that there are many omitted (unmeasured) factors that influence whether a cartel forms or not. Behavioral Methods 15 Is behavior inconsistent with competition? Does a collusive model fit the data better than a competitive model? Is there a structural break in behavior –i.e. statistically distinguishable change? Empirical methods will vary according to: • The type of data that is required • The need for prior information about collusion • Reduced form or structural estimation methods 16 Discouraging Cartels: Leniency Programs Leniency Programs 17 A leniency program offers reduced penalties to corporations and/or individuals involved in collusion, in exchange for cooperating with enforcement authorities. U.S. Department of Justice • 1993: Revised corporate and individual leniency program • Three major revisions: • Amnesty is automatic if there is no pre-existing investigation • Amnesty may still be available even after and investigation has started • All officers, directors, and employees who cooperate are protected from criminal prosecution. • Annual number of leniency applications increased 20-fold. European Commission introduce leniency programs in 1996, revised in 2002. More than 50 jurisdictions have leniency programs (Feb, 2010) The Economics of Leniency Programs 18 A cartel shares common characteristics with organized crime •Cooperation within an illegal environment means that there is a corporate governance problem at its core •Repeated interaction, monitoring, threats and reactions against cheaters, means that participants acquire important information about all their co-conspirators A viable cartel requires that 2 conditions be fulfilled •Participation Constraint: E(Profit from participating in the cartel) – E(Cost of Punishment)>0 •Incentive Compatibility Constraint: Under incomplete information and different types of agents, the participant will find it in its interest to act in accordance with the cartel rules. A successful leniency program weakens a cartel by maximizing conflict of interest among its members and reducing the compatibility of interests A Model for Using Leniency in the Post-Cartel Environment 19 Scenario: auction houses where collusion has stopped. Should they apply for leniency? Model: Each auction house chooses the option that minimizes expected penalties • f is the penalty avoided by receiving leniency (government fine). • d is the penalty not avoided by receiving leniency (customer damages). • p is the probability of a conviction when neither applies for leniency Sotheby’s Christie’s Apply Do not Apply Apply d + f/2 ; d + f/2 d;d+f Do not Apply d+f;d p(d + f) ; p(d + f) A Model for Using Leniency in the Post-Cartel Environment 20 Sotheby’s Christie’s Apply Do not Apply Apply d + f/2 ; d + f/2 d;d+f Do not Apply d+f;d p(d + f) ; p(d + f) Equilibria when the probability of being convicted is low: • p (d + f) < d or p < d/(d+f) [so expected cost of being caught is less than certainty of paying damages] • Two possible equilibrium: Both apply for leniency; both do not apply for leniency • It is a coordination game. (Firms want to coordinate on “do not apply”). Equilibrium when the probability of being convicted is high: • p (d + f) > d or p > d/(d + f) • Unique equilibrium: Both apply for leniency. • It is the Prisoners’ Dilemma game. (The dominant strategy is “Apply”) 21 Punishment and Damages Simple Theory of Cartel Fines 22 Deterrence and Fines • Theory is that fines should be set so that the expected fine is greater than the benefits of cartel • Set properly, fines should eliminate cartels; a higher fine can offset a lower probability of detection Assumptions • M = monopoly profits from cartel (divided among members) • p = probability of detecting the cartel • F = fine imposed on cartel (assume one period for simplicity) Expected fine for cartel = p x F (divided among members) • If expected fine is greater than expected monopoly profits then firms will not join cartel. Therefore p x F > M will deter cartels. • Therefore, firms will choose not to join the cartel when F>M/p Fine Questions and Puzzles 23 Corporate versus individual liability • For publicly traded companies fines reduce shareholder value. • Will punishing shareholders reduce cartel formation? What’s the role of jail terms • Why not just fines? • Why jail for cartels and not for other antitrust offenses? • What is more effective, jail versus debarment? Fines vs. detection • Why not just increase fines and reduce resources on detection? Is cartel enforcement optimal? • Does the continuing uncovering of cartels evidence that penalties are still too low? Punishment: the Fine Arts Auction Houses Case 24 Customer Damages: Purpose 25 Compensation to harmed consumers Deterrence and resistance of cartels • Additional financial penalties to fines levied by the government. • Create added incentives for customers to monitor, report, and investigate. Customer damages – US • Treble damages: Multiplier serves deterrence since the probability of being caught and paying penalties is well below one. • Indirect purchasers cannot sue for damages except in some states. • Class action suits used for when many customers each incur a small loss. The Economics of Damages 26 Damages inflicted by firm i from colluding in period t are calculated to be: • [ Pic(t) – Pibf(t) ] * Qic(t) Pic(t) is the observed (collusive) price charged by firm i in period t. Qic(t) is the number of units sold by firm i in period t. Pibf(t) is the “but for” (or counterfactual) price for firm i in period t. Pic(t) – Pibf(t) is the overcharge Customer Damages 27 Customer damages EU (White Paper, April 2008) • Single damages. • Indirect purchaser suits are allowed. • If an illegal overcharge is passed on to consumers who are not direct buyers then those consumers are harmed. • Those harmed consumers can claim compensation. Comparison of US and EU • EU is focused on compensation. • US is primarily concerned with deterrence and resistance. Allowing indirect purchasers to sue weakens enforcement • Direct purchasers have the best information when it comes to detecting collusion. Weakening their incentives will reduce the likelihood that they report and sue, thereby reducing enforcement. • Damage calculation becomes more difficult and could effectively reduce penalties. 28 Cartels vs. Cooperation Firms Often Cooperate For Pro-Competitive Reasons 29 Joint facilities to obtain scale economies (e.g. Computer Reservation Systems). Standard setting to obtain network economies and reduce transactions costs for consumers (see Lecture 4) (DVD standards). Solving various market imperfections (e.g. Portobello Road Antique Dealers). Exchanging information (costs, best practices, etc.) for procompetitive reasons (e.g. all trade associations). Cooperatives, joint ventures, standard setting organizations, and other horizontal combinations pose difficult problem for antitrust. Engage in obvious efficiency enhancing activities. Efficiencies from Cooperation 30 Sharing of facilities and reduction in duplicative costs Realization of network effects through e.g. standardization Cooperation may be essential to the creation of a product (sports leagues, payment cards) Other efficiencies Key Economic Issues for Cooperation 31 Effect of competition law on choice of organizational form—if mergers are lawful but cooperation isn’t then we will get more mergers. That may lead to inefficient organizational forms and perhaps less competition than with cooperation short of mergers. Is efficiency justification legitimate or a sham? Is it possible to obtain efficiencies in less restrictive ways (relative to competition)? US courts deal with these issues by treating cooperative agreements for which there is an efficiency justification under the rule of reason (since the BMI case which involved a music collecting society). EC law deals with these issues under Article 81(3). Coordinated behavior may be exempt if it is objectively justified. Music Collecting Societies 32 Composers have copyright protection • But cost of enforcing is too high for individual composers • Would need to negotiate with many venues • Would need to invest in detection Music collecting societies form to represent composers • Negotiate with venues • File enforcement actions • Note these are two-sided platforms But cooperation increases market power when compositions are substitutes • Where do we draw the line between efficiencies from cooperation and increased market power? • How have courts/competition authorities resolved this? 33 Guest Speaker: Rosa M. Abrantes Metz Collusion, Screening and LIBOR End of Topic 9, Next Class Topic 10 34 Part 1 Part 2 Market power Supply side Demand side Measurement Multisided platforms