Jonathan Haughton Suffolk University, Boston Jonathan.haughton@suffolk.edu For the World Bank. May 11, 2011 1. 2. 3. 4. Who bears the burden of taxes? Who benefits from government spending? What are the net effects? Who would gain/lose under different possible tax reform packages, and by how much? May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 2 Central government tax revenue 11.6% of GDP in 2004 Buoyant since 2002 71% of revenue from indirect tax ▪ Vat: 19% rate; but yields just 4.9% of GDP Income tax: 3.4% of GDP May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 3 30.0 Revenue + Grants as % of GDP 25.0 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 (e) All other taxes, 0.91 Grants, 0.00 Fees, charges, and non-tax revenues, 2.36 Corporate income tax, 7.96 Taxes on trade, 1.93 Natural resources tax, 1.44 Excise taxes, 1.46 Individual income tax, 0.60 Value-added tax, 7.11 Revenue/GDP: 20% to 2000, now 25% VAT: 7% of GDP (at 10% rate!) Trade: from 4% to 2% of GDP, despite explosion of imports All income tax: Peaked at 10% GDP in 2006, but dependent on SOE sector NB: PIT raises 2% of revenue; surprisingly, not rising Revenue Results of the Simulation Budget revenues, million baht 2006 2007 2008 2009 1,502,423 1,690,494 1,623,052 1,557,898 1,536,615 of which: Revenue Department 969,966 Personal income taxes 153,514 Corporation taxes 339,325 Petroleum income taxes 41,019 Value added taxes 400,967 Specific business taxes 27,887 Stamp duties 6,991 Others 264 Excise Department 394,760 Oil taxes 107,641 Tobacco taxes 52,207 Liguor taxes 41,777 Beer taxes 62,317 Car taxes 85,412 Beverage taxes 14,363 Electronic appliance taxes 5,290 Motorcycle taxes 2,688 Battery taxes 1,095 Telecommunication taxes 19,634 Others taxes 1,715 Miscellaneous 621 Customs Department 107,662 Import duties 104,095 Export duties 278 Miscellaneous 3,289 Other 200,977 Other government agents 85,626 Treasury Department 5,254 State Enterprise Reforms 1,484 State Enterprises 108,613 Total (Gross) 1,673,365 Deduct Tax rebates of Revenue Department 150,626 VAT 128,675 Other taxes 21,951 VAT allocation for PAO (Provincial Administration Organizations) 7,889 Export duties compensation 12,428 49,825 Total (Net) 1,502,423 1,142,926 188,697 394,024 57,442 459,822 34,882 7,803 257 418,039 106,316 53,021 47,622 69,561 88,919 16,675 5,200 2,947 1,769 23,278 1,770 961 100,526 98,151 362 2,014 239,362 105,490 4,372 647 128,853 1,900,853 175,356 142,314 33,042 9,399 11,766 1,690,494 1,212,640 211,043 408,934 66,569 480,497 37,418 7,920 259 283,987 76,969 42,372 32,008 52,817 56,290 11,596 3,757 1,580 1,562 3,564 1,191 281 99,434 96,676 390 2,368 208,292 67,720 3,661 10,659 89,301 1,836,939 196,258 169,023 27,235 10,879 11,420 1,623,052 1,271,371 204,000 462,134 75,379 501,743 20,220 7,647 249 264,118 54,081 41,844 36,779 52,316 57,944 12,394 3,743 1,789 1,627 111 1,169 321 98,961 96,250 474 2,237 167,412 81,887 5,386 80,138 1,801,862 220,660 186,480 34,179 11,471 11,833 33,229 1,557,898 1,141,817 199,090 392,339 87,799 437,038 17,578 7,747 225 334,723 123,445 46,348 39,477 51,974 53,200 12,747 2,749 1,602 1,580 1,068 532 81,527 77,923 340 3,263 182,787 83,718 3,574 95,495 1,740,853 183,567 141,128 42,439 9,183 11,488 45,181 1,536,615 Total Net Revenue after Deductions 2005 Step 1. Make assumptions about incidence Statutory incidence ≠ Effective incidence See Table May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 8 VAT: on consumers Excises: on consumers PIT: on earners Business profits: on earners Other taxes: ▪ Property transfer; local fees and contributions: on payers. ▪ In this study, CIT, trade taxes, natural resource taxes, not included. Incidence covers half of revenue. S(1+t) price supply Pd2 P1 Ps2 demand Q2 Q1 quantity price What elasticity? Pd2 S(1+t) P1=Ps 2 supply demand Q2 Q1 quantity Table 4. Incidence Assumptions Tax Personal income Value Added Tax Incidence Assumption Borne by earners (because their take-home pay would rise if there were no tax). Shifted onto consumers. Fuel excise Shifted onto consumers because of horizontal supply curve. Alcohol excise Shifted onto consumers because of horizontal supply curve. Shifted onto consumers because of horizontal supply curve. Shifted onto consumers. Incidence Assumption Benefits accrue to households whose children are currently enrolled in publicly-supported schools. Benefits accrue to households whose sick members sought help at a publicly-supported hospital or clinic. Benefits accrue to households to the full extent of the subsidies. Tobacco excise Car excise Subsidy/spending Education Health Social subsidies May 11, 2011 Comments on operationalization Uses amounts paid as reported in the ENNIV-2000 survey, and grosses these up to get an appropriate total yield. Assumed to be 0% on exempt items – which understates the tax – using 57 expenditure lines. No adjustment was possible for the source of purchases (e.g. supermarket, street market, etc.), which overstates tax, especially on poorer households. Allocated in proportion to reported household spending on energy. [This is an overstatement, as some effects work via transport, electricity, and individual use, where the incidence pattern is different.] Reported spending on alcohol is typically highly understated. Allocated in proportion to reported household spending on tobacco; also typically highly understated. Allocated in proportion to car value. Comments on operationalization Applied average budgetary cost per enrolled student, differentiated by main level of education (primary, secondary, tertiary). Survey provides information on costs in public and private facilities; subsidy was taken to be the differential between the amount actually paid and an appropriate private-sector norm. This overstates the benefits, given that labor supply is not completely inelastic, but probably not by much. JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 12 Step 2. Quantify the effects Trace effect of a tax, spending change on every household in a survey ENNIV 2000. 3,997 households, 19,957 people, LSMS template NB. Assumes equal sharing within household May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 13 Operationalize the analysis Excel spreadsheet Stata dataset and programs. Change spreadsheet; it invokes Stata, returns the results. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 14 9,189 households, including 4,298 from 2004 round. Two visits per household; 93% of interviews in June, Sept or Oct. Some explicit tax information (e.g. business taxes); otherwise has to be inferred (e.g. VAT, PIT). Socio-economic survey, 2009 47-page data dictionary 139,590 individuals From 43,844 households ▪ Aside: US 1% IRS file plus non-filers: c. 150,000 filers. 19% rate. Fairly stable since 1992. Exports zero rated Exemptions include clothing, rice, milk, fish, vegetables, ed. fees, home consumption, housing In 2000: 42% of central gov. tax revenue Collected 7.3% of household expenditure. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 17 Table 11. Reconciling Survey with Budget Data Tax revenue, based on VHLSS-2006 Based on budgeted Per capita, VND ‘000 Nationally, VND trn national receipts, VND trn VAT 0.522 43.9 54.8 Excise taxes 0.085 7.1 17.1 Personal income tax 0.006 0.5 5.2 Business profits tax 0.121 10.2 100.8 Fees 0.212 17.8 3.9 Source: VHLSS-2006 data from Table 7; budgetary information from Table 1. Categories Tax Rates Wide base of goods, 2004 Wide base of goods, 2000 Exports Most services, some goods Revenue Tax revenue, 2004, m soles Tax revenue, 2000, m soles, net of refunds Tax revenue as % of total tax revenue, 2000 Actual tax revenue / estimated revenue Distributional effects, 2000 Gini coefficient Quasi-Gini coefficient, tax/capita RS1 measure (>0 = progressive) RS2 measure (>0 = progressive) Kakwani measure (>0 = progressive) A 19.0% 18.0% 0.0% Exempt D D D D D D D D D D 13,206.9 9,550.6 41.5 85% Expend/cap 0.470 0.455 -0.00116 -0.00125 -0.015 Inc/cap 0.535 0.358 -0.01145 -0.01207 -0.176 L A R Note: RS1 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measure of disproportionality and RS2 is the Reynol Source: Based on ENNIV-2000. More complete results are shown in Appendix 1. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 19 Regressivity probably overstated, if poor are more likely to buy in informal sector By expenditure/cap: slightly regressive By income/cap: highly regressive May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 20 Income: Easy to measure Widely used in developed countries Overstates regressivity: “lifetime income” Expenditure Less underreporting than income Closer to “permanent income” May understate regressivity May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 21 In 2000, summarized: Alcohol, especially beer (t=27.8% of 84% of rec. prodr. price) Soft drinks (t=17% ex factory) Cigarettes (t=37.2%) New vehicles (t=10%) Motor fuel ▪ Gasoline (S/.2.90 per gallon) ▪ Diesel S/.2.29 per gallon) May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 22 May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 23 May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 24 Expend/cap: Kakwani (>0 Income/cap: Kakwani (>0 = progressive) Revenue as % of all tax revenue Actual revenue as % of estimated Alcohol 0.057 -0.110 3.6 213 Soft drinks -0.105 -0.283 0.6 127 Tobacco -0.003 0.5 170 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru = progressive) Note under-reporting of expenditures May 11, 2011 Page 25 May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 26 Expend/cap: Kakwani (>0 Income/cap: Kakwani (>0 = progressive) Revenue as % of all tax revenue Actual revenue as % of estimated Motor fuel 0.378 0.246 9.3 732 Vehicles 0.412 0.288 1.0 225 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru = progressive) Notes: Fuel numbers overstate progressivity, because of the “bus and truck problem” Vehicle numbers assume purchases in proportion to ownership, which is awkward Ideal is to run this through an input-output table May 11, 2011 Page 27 Distributional Results of the simulation Expenditure/cap Est. tax/capita Est. tax/expenditure 2009 2009 2009 Expenditure per capita deciles 1 (poorest) 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 (richest) 14,536 20,212 24,473 29,099 34,391 41,082 49,595 61,650 82,146 163,833 809 1,221 1,564 1,944 2,400 2,987 3,897 5,100 7,173 15,511 5.6% 6.0% 6.4% 6.7% 7.0% 7.3% 7.9% 8.3% 8.7% 9.5% 102,720 60,462 41,138 37,126 53,224 8,020 5,163 3,289 2,897 4,715 7.8% 8.5% 8.0% 7.8% 8.9% 76,862 46,010 6,334 3,328 8.2% 7.2% 52,102 4,261 8.2% Regions 1: 2: 3: 4: 5: Bangkok Metropolis Central (excluding Bangkok) North Northeast South Areas Urban Rural Thailand overall Average Categories Tax Rates 0 – 27 UIT (i.e. 0 – S/.86,400 p.a.) 27 UIT – 54 UIT (i.e. S/.86,400 – 172,800 p.a.) > 54 UIT (i.e. > S/.172,800 p.a.) Wages & salaries, # of UITs deductible 15% 21% 30% 7 Revenue Tax revenue, 2003, m soles Tax revenue, 2000, m soles, net of refunds Tax revenue as % of total tax revenue, 2000 Actual tax revenue as % of estimated revenue 2,669 2,117 9.2 467 Distributional effects, 2000 Gini coefficient Quasi-Gini coefficient, tax/capita RS1 measure (>0 = progressive) RS2 measure (>0 = progressive) Kakwani measure (>0 = progressive) Expend/cap 0.470 0.627 0.00257 0.00217 0.157 Inc/cap 0.535 0.582 0.00065 0.00031 0.047 Note: RS1 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measure of disproportionality and RS2 is the Reyno Source: Based on ENNIV-2000. More complete results are shown in Appendix 1. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 30 Categories Tax Rates Includes: Personal income tax Excises on alcohol, tobacco, beer, cars, soda Fuel excise tax Revenue Tax revenue, 2003, m soles Tax revenue, 2000, m soles, net of refunds Tax revenue as % of total tax revenue, 2000 Actual tax revenue as % of estimated revenue Distributional effects, 2000 Gini coefficient Quasi-Gini coefficient, tax/capita RS1 measure (>0 = progressive) RS2 measure (>0 = progressive) Kakwani measure (>0 = progressive) Expend/cap 0.470 0.545 0.00971 0.00831 0.075 15116 65.7 120 Inc/cap 0.535 0.460 -0.00801 -0.01087 -0.075 Note: RS1 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measure of disproportionality and RS2 is the Reyn Source: Based on ENNIV-2000. Progressive or not? More complete results are shown in Appendix 1. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 31 In cid en ce of M ain Taxes 0 .1 .2 .3 P e ru, 20 00 0 10 000 20 000 30 000 Expenditure p er cap ita, S/. Fitted values May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru 40 000 50 000 ta xburd Page 32 Tax as a % of expenditure, by decile, 2006 VAT as a % of expenditure, by decile, 2006 10.0 Taxes paid as % of expenditure Taxes paid as % of expenditure 16.0 14.0 12.0 10.0 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 9.0 8.0 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 - 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 Expenditure per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Overall 5 6 7 8 9 10 9 10 VAT Excise Tax as a % of expenditure, by decile, 2006 Educational Fees as a % of expenditure, by decile, 2006 1.6 2.5 Taxes paid as % of expenditure Taxes paid as % of expenditure 4 Expenditure per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 - 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 - 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 Expenditure per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Excises 4 5 6 7 Expenditure per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Educational fees 8 Agricultural Fees as a % of expenditure, by decile, 2006 Other Fees as a % of expenditure, by decile, 2006 1.4 Taxes paid as % of expenditure Taxes paid as % of expenditure 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 - 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 - 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 Expenditure per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Agricultural fees 5 6 7 8 9 10 9 10 Other fees Tax on business income as a % of expenditure, by decile, 2006 Personal Income Tax as a % of expenditure, by decile, 2006 3.5 0.3 Taxes paid as % of expenditure Taxes paid as % of expenditure 4 Expenditure per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 - 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 - 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Expenditure per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Business income 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Expenditure per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Personal Income Tax 8 Tax as a % of income, by decile, 2006 VAT as a % of income, by decile, 2006 7.0 Taxes paid as % of income Taxes paid as % of income 14.0 12.0 10.0 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 - 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 - 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 Income per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Overall 5 6 7 8 9 10 9 10 VAT Excise tax as a % of income, by decile, 2006 Educational Fees as a % of income, by decile, 2006 1.2 1.8 Taxes paid as % of income Taxes paid as % of income 4 Income per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 - 1.6 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 - 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 Income per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Excises 4 5 6 7 Income per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Educational fees 8 Other fees as a % of income, by decile, 2006 0.8 1.0 0.7 0.9 Taxes paid as % of income Taxes paid as % of income Agricultural fees as a % of income, by decile, 2006 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 - 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 - 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 Income per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Agricultural fees 5 6 7 8 9 10 Other fees Personal income tax as a % of income, by decile, 2006 Tax on business income as a % of income, by decile, 2006 0.3 Taxes paid as % of income 3.0 Taxes paid as % of income 4 Income per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 - 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Income per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Business income 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Income per capita decile (poor = 1, rich = 10) Personal Income Tax 8 9 10 In Vietnam, incidence pattern by expenditure/cap decile similar to that by income/cap Contrast with Peru These taxes are progressive overall Heavier, more progressive, than 1998 VAT is generally progressive – mainly due to home production (1/3 at bottom, 1% at top); not the case in all countries Excise taxes are progressive – also a bit surprising. Table 10. Measures of Tax Progressivity Expenditure per capita Income per capita All allocable taxes Personal income tax Business income tax Excise taxes Fees: other VAT Fees: educational Fees: agricultural Gini coefficient (GX) 0.390 0.408 Concentration Ratio (CT,X) 0.461 0.986 0.686 0.504 0.459 0.443 0.354 -0.018 Property tax 0.632 Property tax: own residence 0.619 Property tax: other than residence 0.751 Property tax with VND100m threshold 0.776 Source: Based on Vietnam Household Living Standards Survey 2006. Kakwani measure (CT,X – GX) 0.071 0.597 0.296 0.114 0.069 0.054 -0.036 -0.408 0.242 0.229 0.361 0.386 Regional effects Personal Income Tax Property Tax Expenditure incidence Marginal full incidence Policy reforms Higher tax rates in south Highest rate in South-Central Coast (sampling error?) Urban/rural gap in burden is surprisingly small Table 12. Structure of Current and Proposed Personal Income Taxes Coverage Rates & Base Current tax Wages, salaries, bonuses, housing allowances. For Vietnamese Income p.a., VND m Tax rate, % New tax Wages, salaries, bonuses, housing allowances, business income, interest, dividends, capital gains, prizes. Taxable income p.a., VND m 0 – 60 60 – 120 120 – 216 216 – 384 384 – 624 624 – 960 >960 Tax rate, % 0 – 60 0 5 60 – 180 10 10 180 – 300 20 15 300 – 480 30 20 >480 40 25 For foreigners 30 0 – 96 0 35 96 – 240 10 240 – 600 20 Personal deduction: VND 48 m 600 – 960 30 Deduction/dependent: VND 19.2 m > 960 40 Sources: IMF (2007); Shukla (2006); Law on Personal Income Tax /2007/QH12. 1 (poor) 2 Expenditure per capita deciles 4 5 6 7 3 8 9 10 (rich) All % hh paying thousands of VND p.a. Household expenditure per capita 2,000 2,938 3,640 4,324 5,077 5,981 7,149 8,811 11,593 22,681 7,417 Total tax paid of which: taxes on household enterprises personal income tax Total new tax paid on income 156 252 372 458 557 709 984 1,151 1,679 3,146 946 100.0 35 163 - 116 - 184 1 651 61 121 6 15.4 0.2 1 13 190 21 1.0 Total tax paid of which: taxes on household enterprises personal income tax Total new tax paid on income 7.8 8.6 10.2 10.6 11.0 11.9 13.8 13.1 14.5 13.9 13.4 0.1 - 0.1 - 0.3 - 0.3 - 0.6 - 0.6 - 2.3 - 1.3 - 1.6 0.0 2.9 0.3 1.6 0.1 - - - - - - 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.8 0.3 3 - 3 - 12 - 12 - 30 - - 8 as percentage of expenditure Notes. Revenue from value-added tax, excise taxes, and personal income tax, are estimated based on spending and income patterns. Based on the VHLSS survey of 2006. All figures are in prices of 2006. Method: strip out business income tax and PIT, and apply rules of new tax Revenue: from VND127k to VND21k per person. New tax highly progressive. But: excludes foreigners; very small sample size for PIT and for large household enterprises. Done by General Dept. of Taxation in 2005, using tax rolls Survey, asking about income, spending 15,500: 3,200 foreign, 7,200 PIT, 5,100 business income tax 11,535 responses (74%); low in HCMC, among foreigners. Results re-weighted. Anything equivalent in Thailand? Vietnamese Taxpayer income of which: Wages and salaries Enterprise Business Finance and capital Transfers Other Memo items: Total household income Household current spending Household asset purchases Personal income tax/taxpayer Estimate, 2005 Estimate, 2009, old rules Memo: % growth Estimate, 2009, new rules Personal income tax revenue Estimate, 2005 Memo: Actual PIT revenue, 2005 Estimate, 2009, old rules Estimate, 2009, new rules Foreigners Household enterprises thousands of VND per year Full sample 195,003 631,835 244,158 302,514 71,263 498 37,474 79,732 98 5,938 620,939 810 1,548 8,190 5 342 43,753 327 191,095 7,022 227 1,734 177,172 507 80,459 40,869 121 3,386 370,619 79,273 255,995 671,127 116,266 38,100 266,619 39,741 59,914 399,276 74,014 145,971 239,751 527,604 120% 392,175 74,315 136,219 83% 162,330 77,792 175,319 125% 153,426 4,504 15,907 253% 39,057 628 2,217 5,443 14,849 4,200 32,677 24,290 % foreign 7,336 22,812 65% 13,446 16,024 48,340 45,756 68% 53% Based on 2009 NB. PIT very elastic Total revenue: -5% ▪ Foreigners: down by a quarter ▪ Vietnamese: tax payments up Reconcile with VHLSS data High-income individuals would pay more Not-so-high income individuals would pay less, and not be in the tax net as much Difficult to merge the two; in progress. Keep: taxes foreigners, adds equity. Enforcement could be better. Perhaps limit top rate to top CIT. Adjust brackets for inflation (as in US). VHLSS has limited data on property: Residence; non-agric. real estate Assume tax would not apply to agricultural property, or to movable property. 1% of capital value; arbitrary 1 (poor) 2 Expenditure per capita deciles 4 5 6 7 3 8 9 10 (rich) All % hh paying thousands of VND p.a. Household expenditure per capita 2,000 2,938 3,640 4,324 5,077 5,981 7,149 8,811 11,593 22,681 7,417 Total tax paid of which: taxes on residence taxes on other property Total tax paid with VND100m threshhold per household 50 82 119 168 210 277 384 545 1,028 2,944 580 97.9 49 1 80 2 113 5 157 10 200 10 257 20 357 26 500 46 922 106 2,587 358 522 58 97.5 8.9 1 4 12 44 335 798 2,677 424 35.8 Total tax paid of which: taxes on residence taxes on other property Total tax paid with VND100m threshhold per household 2.5 2.8 3.3 3.9 4.1 4.6 5.4 6.2 8.9 13.0 7.8 2.4 0.1 2.7 0.1 3.1 0.1 3.6 0.2 3.9 0.2 4.3 0.3 5.0 0.4 5.7 0.5 8.0 0.9 11.4 1.6 7.0 0.8 0.1 0.1 0.3 1.0 1.2 1.8 2.8 3.8 6.9 11.8 5.7 62 109 197 as percentage of expenditure Notes. Revenue from value-added tax, excise taxes, and personal income tax, are estimated based on spending and income patterns. Based on the VHLSS survey of 2006. All figures are in prices of 2006. 1 (poor) Income per capita 2,370 2 3,511 3 4,387 4 Income per capita deciles 5 6 7 5,279 6,268 7,508 9,076 8 9 11,118 14,660 10 (rich) All 29,343 9,351 % hh paying Highly progressive 1% is steep; 7.8% of expenditure, so politically infeasible at this level. Cash flow concerns Based on bubble prices? Introduction of tax would reduce base Excludes corporate ownership Tax paid Expenditure per capita Tax as % of expenditure Tax paid with threshhold '000 VND Region 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Urban Rural Overall Tax as % of expenditure # of households sampled '000 VND 791 8,241 9.6 599.6 7.3 305 5,772 5.3 172.6 3.0 244 4,393 5.5 140.8 3.2 248 5,053 4.9 119.5 2.4 387 6,766 5.7 238.1 3.5 312 5,955 5.2 190.4 3.2 Note: The1,422 regions are: 1: Red River Delta, 2: Northeast, 3: Northwest, 4: North Central Coast, 5: South Central Coast, 6: 11,852 12.0 1,224.0 10.3 Central Highlands, 7: Southeast, 8: Mekong River Delta. 277 6,698 4.1 135.7 2.0 1,944 1,317 429 1,014 852 582 1,188 1,863 1,425 272 12,394 5,602 11.5 4.9 1,211.6 136.2 9.8 2.4 2,307 6,882 580 7,417 7.8 423.6 5.7 9,189 Applied to education, health, targeted social programs Step 1: Measure unit subsidies Step 2: Identify coverage Step 3: Present results May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 51 In 2000 ▪ 98.8% of children 7-10 were at school ▪ 94% of 14-year-olds were at school ▪ 13% of pupils/students were at private schools Costs ▪ ▪ ▪ ▪ Pre-K: S/. 583 per child per year K & primary: S/. 386 Secondary: S/. 624 Tertiary: S/.2,506 Assigned based on attendance May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 52 Cost per pupil, S/. 583 386 624 2,506 Categories Pre-kindergarten Kindergarten & primary Secondary Tertiary Spending Spending, 2003, m soles Spending, 2000, m soles Spending as % of total tax revenue, 2000 Actual spending as % of estimated spending Distributional effects, 2000 Gini coefficient Quasi-Gini coefficient, tax/capita RS1 measure (>0 = progressive) RS2 measure (>0 = progressive) Kakwani measure (<0 = progressive) Expend/cap 0.470 0.102 0.01282 0.01234 -0.369 A D D D D D D D D D D 5,921 4,740 20.6 69 Inc/cap 0.535 0.090 0.01305 0.01271 -0.444 L A R Note: RS1 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measure of disproportionality and RS2 is the Reyno Source: Based on ENNIV-2000. More complete results are shown in Appendix 1. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 53 00 Sorted by expenditure/capita per pupil, S/. 583 386 624 506 21 40 20.6 69 Inc/cap 0.535 0.090 0.01305 0.01271 -0.444 All Peru (2000) Spending/ Expend, % 3.6 Decile 1 (poorest) Decile 2 Decile 3 Decile 4 Decile 5 Decile 6 Decile 7 Decile 8 Decile 9 Decile 10 (richest) 15.6 9.8 7.6 7.0 5.4 4.8 4.0 3.5 2.9 1.3 Lima/Callao Amazon (4 depts) Rest of Peru 2.2 4.5 4.8 Spending/ Income, % 3.0 % of spending 100.0 Sorted by inc/cap Spending/ Income, % 3.0 11.4 6.0 5.8 5.0 4.2 3.7 3.4 2.8 2.7 1.2 7.9 8.1 8.3 9.5 9.0 9.8 10.1 11.0 12.7 13.7 34.7 13.5 8.3 6.2 4.7 4.4 3.6 3.0 2.2 1.0 n/a n/a n/a 27.2 15.7 57.1 1.8 3.9 4.0 and RS2 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measures of redistributive capacity. “progressive but not well-targeted” Appendix 1. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 54 Cost of procedures Used ENNIV-2000 reported data on cost at private facilities Adjusted downwards substantially to be consistent with government spending ▪ Cost/consultation S/. 0.75/minute ▪ Cost of hospitalization S/. 75/night ▪ Cost of an analysis S/. 6.2/item May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 56 Consultation, S/. per minute Hospitalization, S/. per day Analysis, S/. per person Cost per pupil, S/. 1.5 150 12.5 Spending Spending, 2003, m soles Spending, 2000, m soles, net of refunds Spending as % of total tax revenue, 2000 Actual spending as % of estimated spending 1,922 8.4 48 Categories Distributional effects, 2000 Gini coefficient Quasi-Gini coefficient, tax/capita RS1 measure (>0 = progressive) RS2 measure (>0 = progressive) Kakwani measure (<0 = progressive) Expend/cap 0.470 0.137 0.00480 0.00371 -0.334 Inc/cap 0.535 0.006 0.00641 0.00546 -0.529 Note: RS1 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measure of disproportionality and RS2 is the R Source: Based on ENNIV-2000. More complete results are shown in Appendix 1. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 57 Sorted by expenditure/capita r pupil, /. All Peru (2000) 4 c/cap 535 006 00641 00546 529 Spending/ expend 1.5 Decile 1 (poorest) Decile 2 Decile 3 Decile 4 Decile 5 Decile 6 Decile 7 Decile 8 Decile 9 Decile 10 (richest) 5.6 3.4 3.5 2.1 2.5 1.5 1.9 1.6 1.3 0.6 Lima/Callao Amazon (4 depts) Rest of Peru 0.8 2.4 1.9 Sorted by inc/cap Spending/ income 1.2 Spending/ income 1.2 % of spending 100.0 4.1 2.1 2.7 1.5 1.9 1.2 1.6 1.3 1.2 0.5 6.9 6.9 9.4 6.9 10.1 7.6 11.7 12.6 14.0 13.9 17.9 7.3 3.1 3.2 1.7 1.9 1.0 1.2 1.0 0.3 23.3 21.2 55.5 0.6 2.1 1.6 n/a n/a n/a RS2 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measures of redistributive capacity. pendix 1. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 58 Table 17. “Social subsidies,” 2000 School meals (“desayuno escolar”) Milk (“vaso de leche”) Food support (“comedor popular”) Mother’s groups (“club de madres”) Family food basket (“canasta familiar (panfar)”) Food for work (“alimento por trabajo”) Direct food support (“donación directa de alimentos”) Child nutrition (“papilla u otro alimento para menores”) School uniforms School books and materials Source: Based on ENNIV-2000. Mean amount received per household, S/. p.a. 23.58 34.31 23.14 1.48 1.05 1.67 0.90 1.94 4.25 14.13 Allocated based on reported usage May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 59 Cost per pupil, S/. Categories Major items: School meals Milk Food support 23.58 34.31 23.14 Spending Spending, 2003, m soles Spending, 2000, m soles, net of refunds Spending as % of total tax revenue, 2000 Actual spending as % of estimated spending Distributional effects, 2000 Gini coefficient Quasi-Gini coefficient, tax/capita RS1 measure (>0 = progressive) RS2 measure (>0 = progressive) Kakwani measure (<0 = progressive) Expend/cap 0.470 -0.217 0.01854 0.01504 -0.688 3,646 15.9 256 Inc/cap 0.535 -0.191 0.01651 0.01438 -0.725 Note: RS1 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measure of disproportionality and RS2 is the R Source: Based on ENNIV-2000. More complete results are shown in Appendix 1. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 60 Sorted by expenditure/capita pupil, All Peru (2000) /cap 535 191 01651 01438 725 Spending/ expend 2.8 Decile 1 (poorest) Decile 2 Decile 3 Decile 4 Decile 5 Decile 6 Decile 7 Decile 8 Decile 9 Decile 10 (richest) 20.5 14.0 9.1 7.2 5.2 4.4 2.8 1.7 0.7 0.2 Lima/Callao Amazon (4 depts) Rest of Peru 1.9 3.7 3.3 Spending/ Income 2.3 % of spending 100.0 Sorted by inc/cap Spending/ income 2.3 15.0 8.7 7.0 5.1 4.1 3.4 2.4 1.4 0.6 0.2 13.5 15.1 12.9 12.6 11.3 11.6 9.2 7.1 3.8 2.8 44.6 19.0 9.3 5.8 4.6 3.4 2.3 1.6 1.0 0.1 n/a n/a n/a 31.0 16.9 52.1 1.6 3.2 2.8 RS2 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measures of redistributive capacity. endix 1. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 61 System seems progressive overall But ▪ Some taxes not included (e.g. CIT) ▪ Not all spending can be included ▪ Rely on our incidence assumptions May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 62 All Peru (2000) Tax/ expend 3.7 Tax/ income 3.1 % of tax revenue 100.0 Sorted by inc/cap Tax/ income 3.1 Decile 1 (poorest) Decile 2 Decile 3 Decile 4 Decile 5 Decile 6 Decile 7 Decile 8 Decile 9 Decile 10 (richest) -34.3 -19.1 -11.1 -6.5 -3.4 -0.5 1.7 3.7 6.4 11.5 -25.1 -11.9 -8.5 -4.6 -2.6 -0.4 1.4 3.0 6.0 10.5 -17.1 -15.7 -11.9 -8.6 -5.5 -0.9 4.1 11.6 27.6 116.4 -60.9 -23.8 -8.1 -4.1 -0.5 0.0 1.9 3.2 4.5 9.1 Lima/Callao Amazon (4 depts) Rest of Peru 6.8 0.0 1.5 82.5 0.0 17.5 5.6 0.0 1.3 Sorted by expenditure/capita es ap 5 8 053 413 4 n/a n/a n/a S2 is the Reynolds-Smolensky measures of redistributive capacity. JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru dix 1. May 11, 2011 Page 63 Table 22. Revenue and Progressivity Measures for Taxes and Spending, 2003 Reynolds-Smolensky measures Social subsidies Educational spending Gasoline excise tax Health spending Personal income tax Vehicle excise tax Alcohol excise tax Cigarette excise tax Soda excise tax VAT Memo: All taxes Social spending Tax net of spending May 11, 2011 Revenue or spending, S/. millions 3,646 4,740 2,145 1,922 2,117 240 817 106 141 9,551 15,116 10,308 4,808 Disproportionalit y (RS1) 0.01854 0.01282 0.00626 0.00480 0.00257 0.00075 0.00036 0.00000 -0.00011 -0.00116 Redistributive capacity (RS2) 0.01504 0.01234 0.00582 0.00371 0.00217 0.00075 0.00032 0.00000 -0.00011 -0.00125 0.00971 0.03451 0.04755 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru 0.00831 0.02975 0.04036 Kakwani measure of progressivity -0.688 -0.369 0.378 -0.334 0.157 0.412 0.057 -0.003 -0.105 -0.015 V. progressive Progressive Progressive Progressive Progressive 0.075 -0.475 1.254 Page 64 Addresses question: If a tax were raised, and spending increased as a result, what would effect be on incidence? Step 1: Estimate effect of more tax revenue on spending Step 2: Simulate effect of higher VAT in Peru May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 65 Estimated using regression of form yit . xit i it i.e. spending/GDP (y) is a function of tax revenue/GDP (x) Panel Data: 16 Latin American countries, 1980-2002. “Fixed effects” estimates. May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 66 Table 25. Average and marginal effects of incremental tax revenue % of GDP Tax revenue Government expenditure Of which: Education Health Social security Law and order Interest payments Other 16.0 21.7 % of tax revenue 100.0 135.4 Sample size 283 283 Marginal effect 100.0 109.4 3.0 2.0 4.9 2.7 2.8 5.5 18.8 12.6 30.8 16.7 17.5 34.4 265 263 251 169 273 163 7.6 7.3 36.2 26.0 -0.2 35.1 p-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.79 0.00 Note: •Low marginal effects for education, health •No marginal effect for interest payments •High marginal effects for social spending May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 67 2000: assume VAT from 18% to 19% Of extra revenue: ▪ Education takes 7.6% ▪ Health takes 7.3% ▪ Social subsidies take 28.4% ▪ Remaining spending not allocable May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 68 May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 69 A higher VAT need not hurt the poor Result is robust to whether we use expenditure/cap or income/cap to sort households May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 70 Greater disaggregation of spending Sensitivity to assumptions about incidence Source of purchases/evasion Better treatment of transport Use income tax data Add social security pensions May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 71 Confidence intervals (bootstrapping?) Create integrated “calculators”; and do it in-house Need better access to primary data Adjust for quality/value of benefits Theory: why income/cap results differ so much from expend/cap results ▪ Measurement error (Deaton)/permanent income May 11, 2011 JH: Tax & Expenditure Incidence in Peru Page 72 7. Nine Current Issues of Tax Policy Having set out the key features of each main tax, we now turn to an analysis of several current issues of tax policy, one at a time. We are then ready, in the final section, to discuss a number of complete tax reform strategies. Issue 1: How High a VAT? Given the government’s need for more revenue, it is widely accepted that the VAT rate will need to rise. The issue is: by how much? A good place to start is with an analysis of an increase in the VAT from 10% to 12%, which is the smallest increase under serious consideration and is generally accepted to be quite feasible. The impact is set out below: overall tax revenue would rise by 3.9%, equivalent to 0.65% of GDP; and the increase in the tax burden would be relatively larger for more affluent households. We have assumed that as the VAT rate rises, people purchase fewer goods that are subject to the VAT; in part this is because they face a budget constraint, so a rise in the VAT rate from 10% to 12% would, if spending is held constant, raise revenue by 17.9% and not by 20%. In addition, faced with a higher VAT rate, buyers would tend to substitute items that are not subject to the VAT. We use a “revenue loss parameter” of 0.8, which means that a 20% increase in the VAT rate would be accompanied by a 16% (i.e. 0.8 times 20%) rise in revenue (and we allow for an additional response for motor fuel and tobacco). Even this may be too low; Agha and Haughton (1996) estimate, based on data from OECD countries, that every percentage point increase in the VAT rate is associated with a 2.7% fall in compliance, which would imply a revenue loss parameter of about 0.7. An increase in the VAT from 10% to 12% would raise little more than a fifth of the revenue that is considered necessary if Lebanon is to escape from its current vicious cycle of debt. This prompts one to ask what would be the effect of an increase in the VAT rate from 10% to 16%. The result would be a LBP510bn rise in revenue, equivalent to 2% of GDP. Again, the burden would fall slightly more on rich than on poor households, although even the latter would find their real expenditure cut by 2.3%. Here too we have taken into account that a 60% rise in the nominal VAT rate would lead to an increase in revenue of substantially less than this. An important question is whether the VAT, introduced just over two years ago, is robust enough to withstand a substantial increase in the rate. This is a clear case where “Tax administration is Exercise 1: Raise Value Added Tax from 10% to 12% Categories Total tax revenue, LBP bn Of which: VAT Fuel excises Tobacco excises Memo: Gini coefficient for all taxes Beirut Suburbs of Beirut Rest of Mt. Lebanon North Lebanon South Lebanon Nabatieh Beka'a Valley Old 4,502 1,361 819 185 0.474 Change in tax/expenditure LBP/cap p.a. % change -71 -0.95% -59 -0.98% -70 -1.01% -40 -1.03% -37 -1.02% -40 -1.02% -36 -0.94% New 4,679 1,555 804 182 0.472 All Lebanon Poorest quintile Poor-mid quintile Middle quintile Mid-upper quintile Upper quintile % change +3.9 +14.3 -1.8 -1.8 Revenue Loss Parameter 0.8 Change in tax/expenditure LBP/cap p.a. % change -0.99% -51 -14 -24 -35 -52 -130 -0.81% -0.85% -0.88% -0.94% -1.11% Exercise 2: Raise Value Added Tax from 10% to 16% Categories Total tax revenue, LBP bn Of which: VAT Fuel excises Tobacco excises Memo: Gini coefficient for all taxes Beirut Suburbs of Beirut Rest of Mt. Lebanon North Lebanon South Lebanon Nabatieh Beka'a Valley Old 4,502 1,361 819 185 0.474 Change in tax/expenditure LBP/cap p.a. % change -205 -2.74% -172 -2.84% -204 -2.92% -116 -2.97% -106 -2.94% -115 -2.94% -105 -2.73% New 5,012 1,923 777 175 0.472 All Lebanon Poorest quintile Poor-mid quintile Middle quintile Mid-upper quintile Upper quintile % change +11.3 +41.3 -5.2 -5.2 Revenue Loss Parameter 0.8 Change in tax/expenditure LBP/cap p.a. % change -2.86% -148 -42 -70 -100 -152 -375 -2.34% -2.46% -2.56% -2.71% -3.19% from the capacity and evolution of tax administration. Of the 15,400 registered VAT payers, roughly 1,000 are audited every quarter, almost double the proportion of most other jurisdictions, and a reflection of the newness of the tax. On the other hand the VAT department is well trained and adequately staffed, and could probably make a VAT of 16% work without too much leakage, particularly as three fifths of the revenues are collected on imports. A broader question is how far one can push a VAT. Agha and Haughton have constructed an interesting graph, reproduced here, that shows that once the VAT rate exceeds about 15%, the pressure to shrink the base becomes very strong. The implication is that the revenue-maximizing point is then reached quite quickly, and appears to be in the region of 7-8% of GDP; all the countries in the sample whose VAT raised more than 7% of GDP are ranged along the frontier in this diagram.. Our simulations, detailed above, show that a VAT of 16% would raise about 7.0% of GDP in revenue, which is as far as one can reasonably expect to go. 2. A Revenue-Neutral Reform, Emphasizing Equity An alternative revenue-neutral reform would keep the VAT at 10%, but improve the efficiency of taxes on the income side. The wage and salary tax, and the tax on proprietors’ income, would be unified with a 10% basic rate, rising to 20% on income above LBP60 million; and with a personal tax deduction of 1.5 million. The corporation income tax would rise to 20%, while the capital gains and inheritance taxes would be abolished. A property tax levied at 0.5% of the value of property above LBP120m would replace the current graduated built property tax. Total revenue would rise fractionally, but the tax system would become more progressive, with the tax Gini rising from 0.474 to 0.480. Further details are provided in the table. 3. The Prime Minister’s Proposal of 2003 Although it is no longer actively under consideration, the Prime Minister proposed, in 2003, a radical set of tax changes that would shift the weight of taxation away from income and onto expenditure. Specifically he suggested raising the VAT from 10% to 16% and the corporation income tax from 15% to 20%; at the same time several taxes would be abolished, including those on wages and salaries, built property, and inheritance, as well as some minor excises, and educational fees. We estimate that the plan would have raised tax revenue by 5.8% in 2003, an increase of LBP263bn. Although the plan would have considerably simplified tax administration, it had two drawbacks. First, it did not raise enough additional revenue to be convincing to the Paris II donors, who wanted (and still want) to see a more substantial effort to achieve fiscal balance, and would not have favored the elimination, even temporarily, of taxes on personal income. Second, the proposal would have fallen most heavily on the poor, who spend on consumption (and so would be hit by the higher VAT) but are less likely to pay taxes on wages or capital income (and so would not benefit from the reduction in those taxes. Exercise 2: A Revenue-neutral equity-enhancing tax reform Categories Total tax revenue, LBP bn Of which: Wage and salary tax Sole proprietorships Corporation profits Dividends & capital gains Inheritance tax Built property tax Property registration fees Other taxes and stamp duties Memo: Gini coefficient for all taxes Old 4,502 173 119 295 51 37 82 203 305 0.474 Change in real expenditure LBP/cap p.a. % change -44 -0.59% -40 -0.66% -49 -0.70% -11 -0.29% -9 -0.25% -9 -0.24% -17 -0.43% New 4,534 184 107 393 0 0 201 122 289 0.480 Change, LBP bn 32 11 -12 98 -51 -37 119 -81 -16 % change +0.7% +6.3% -9.7% +33.3% -100.0% -100.0% +146.0% -40.0% -5.2% Revenue Loss Parameter 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 Change in real expenditure LBP/cap p.a. % change -0.52% -27 All Lebanon Beirut Suburbs of Beirut Rest of Mt. Lebanon Poorest quintile -1 -0.06% North Lebanon Poor-mid quintile -3 -0.10% South Lebanon Middle quintile -4 -0.09% Nabatieh Mid-upper quintile -15 -0.26% Beka'a Valley Upper quintile -113 -0.96% Components of tax proposal: Simplify tax on wages and salaries, and on the self-employed: 10% basic rate, rising to 20% on income above LBP60 million. Remove: tax on dividends and capital gains; inheritance tax; minor excises (alcoholic & non-alcoholic beverages, entertainment tax, 5% sales tax on small hotels); fees related to education (examination fees, registration fees for schools and University of Lebanon). Raise corporation income tax to 20%. Raise Built property tax to flat 0.5% of value, but cut property registration fees from 5% to 3%. Exercise 3: Prime Minister’s Tax Reform Package floated in 2003 Categories Total tax revenue, LBP bn Of which: Wage and salary tax Sole proprietorships Corporation profits Inheritance Built property tax VAT Fuel excises Tobacco excises Other taxes and stamp duties Memo: Gini coefficient for all taxes Old 4,502 173 119 295 37 82 1,361 819 185 305 0.474 Change in real expenditure LBP/cap p.a. % change -73 -0.97% -90 -1.48% -107 -1.53% -80 -2.04% -77 -2.14% -87 -2.23% -70 -1.81% New 4,765 0 93 393 0 0 1,923 777 175 278 0.452 Change, LBP bn 263 -173 -26 98 -37 -82 562 -41 -10 -26 % change +5.8% -100.0% -22.0% +33.3% -100.0% -100.0% +41.3% -5.2% -5.2% -8.7% Revenue Loss Parameter 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 0.8 Elasticity = -0.2 Elasticity = -0.2 1.0 Change in real expenditure LBP/cap p.a. % change -1.63% -84 All Lebanon Beirut Suburbs of Beirut Rest of Mt. Lebanon Poorest quintile -39 -2.18% North Lebanon Poor-mid quintile -61 -2.15% South Lebanon Middle quintile -82 -2.10% Nabatieh Mid-upper quintile -100 -1.79% Beka'a Valley Upper quintile -136 -1.16% Components of tax proposal: Raise VAT rate from 10% to 16% Raise corporate tax rate from 15% to 20% Remove: tax on wages and salaries; built property tax; inheritance tax; professional tax; minor excises (alcoholic & non-alcoholic beverages, entertainment tax, 5% sales tax on small hotels); fees related to education (examination fees, registration fees for schools and University of Lebanon). jonathan.haughton@suffolk.edu