Governing International Commons: Sharing genetic and other scientific and knowledge resources Tom Dedeurwaerdere Université catholique de Louvain Global Governance Program, European University Institute, Firenze, 16th-19th November 2011 1 Introduction Global commons caught between intellectual property, open access and pooling of shared resources Economic opportunities from shared use and conservation of genetic resources Global seed exchange network (source : Byerlee et al., 2010) Improvement of traditional races (source: Label rouge) Microbial Biocontrol (Source : M. Höfte) Source : slide from Tine De Moor, presentation Utrecht Studium Generale, 16th of May 2011, The way we think about commons is rapidly evolving Common property (pre-1990) Common-pool resources (1990+) Commons (2000+) (reference : slide from Charlotte Hess, NAS symposium, 9 october 2009, also the previous slide on the new commons) • Definition of Commons in « Knowledge as a Commons » (MIT Press, Hess and Ostrom, eds.) : < any resource that is shared by a discrete group of people at any level, whether local or global Introducing the research question • Research question : how to create a better fit between the formal institutional arrangements (law, contracts and policies) and the normative practices and needs of genetic resources commons ? – Examples of « crowding out » of productive norms and practices by focus on monetary values alone : • national ABS rules’ impact on bioprospecting • anticommons effects of patents, … Part 1. Economics of governing genetic resource commons 9 1. Genetic-resources : the last frontier of the global commons No Belgian beer without the commons No Friesian horses without the commons How to deal the wealth of genetic resources with unknown or unlikely commercial potential but high research and high environmental pay-offs ? Global common pools of genetic-resources as an alternative to green gold Microbial commons Animal breed societies Common pool of plant genetic resources Overview First case study : governing rare breed / small herdbook societies as a commons Second case study : governing microbial commons Third case study : governing the global crop commons Case study on animal rare breed / small herdbook societies What kind of commons are the breeding societies ? The animals are owned by the farmers The genetic resources are managed collectively by the members of the breeding society Measures for facilitated access to genetic resources within the pool How to govern the breeding societies ? Question 1 : how to prevent the disappearance of the breed ? Question 2 : How to use traditional breeds for globally sustainable agriculture ? Use and improvement of Indian Zebu in Brasil How to Govern the common breeding pools ? Maximum rent or Sustainable development ? • Limits on genetic exchange with the livestock kept by other social groups • Collective breeding goals : not on the « optimal productive » animal, but a an optimal herd composed of different lineagages (adaptive value, and not just productive value) Case study on microbial commons What kind of commons is the microbial commons ? A commons of natural resources The gene banks do not own the resources : materials held in trust for the humankind Well established boundaries around the common pool : only certified materials for research and identification services How to Govern the microbial commons ? Green gold or Research commons ? Question 1 : supporting the market or the research value ? 1 % of the microbial materials : potential blockbuster commercial application 99 % of the materials : used in the scientific research commons Question 2 : How to promote informal exchange networks ? Distribution forms Accession form Accession form Accession form Case study on the global crop commons 32 Source : Byerlee and Dubin, International Journal of the Commons, 2010 Global seed exchange network (source : Byerlee et al., 2010) 2. Theory of mixed motivations in social production systems 35 Empirical data on voluntary contributions to social funds Reference (for the 2 following slides) : Stephan Meier. 2006. The economics of non-selfish behaviour. Edward Elgar. 36 Decision situation : On paying the compulsory tuition fee, students at university of Zurich are asked every year if they wish to contribute to a social fund (offering low-interest loans to students in financial difficulties) and/or a foreigner fund (support for foreigners). Results : • Between 1998-2002, on average > 69% of the students contributed to at least one fund, > 62% to both funds. • Over the years, students either always contribute or never contribute. • > 75% does not tell friends whether they contributed or not. 37 Framing effect : change in way of asking in 1998 (asking explicitly to contribute, and offer choice) lead to an increase in people contributing to both funds from 44% to 62 % Group identification effect : upon first registration before attending the University 73% contributes at least to one fund, after increases to 76% in the second semester, drops to 61% in the last semester, compared to 63% in the next to last and 64% in the semester before that. Conditional cooperation effect : people presented with information of others being cooperative (by giving the % of contributors) are more likely to contribute, at least if they are in the category of people “doubting” to contribute 38 Interactions between intrinsic / social motivations and monetary incentives Motivational crowding out effect : monetary incentives decreasing the level of provision of public goods (example of blood donation, choice of pollution sites) Cheap talk / face to face communication sometimes more effective than imposing a fine 39 Models of mixed motivations in local and global collective action Common pool resources (Ostrom) < social norms of reciprocity and trust, social sanctions Pooling of exclusive assets (Allarkhaia) < direct reciprocity benefits Voluntary contribution (Benkler) < reputational benefits Voluntary coordination for governing exclusive assets (Sabel) < overcoming information asymmetries, social learning 40 3. Analysing the Genetic-resource commons 41 Research hypothesis for the geneticresource commons Successful governance of genetic-resource commons has to combine design rules of natural resource commons (Ostrom) and digital resource commons (Benkler) 42 Microbial resources Biophysical properties genetic Plant genetic resources High genetic variation Well defined varieties and Relatively within a species and high degree of genetic breeds high mutation rates stability Characteristi Type of users Mix of public and private cs of the Main non-market Contribution to scientific user groups motivations research ethos Conservation of biodiversity Features of Governing bodies the Governance Organization of arrangement distributed collaboration s Forms of exchange Animal resources Global and federations Mostly public sector Food security Contribution to and research regional Secretariat international treaty genetic well defined Mostly private sector Animal health training Conservation of genetic variety of National and local breeding organisations Shared resources Shared resources Shared resources amongst a distributed amongst plant breeders, amongst farmers of a network of microbial centralized collections for same breed collections key species Mix of informal formal Main challenges to the commons- Restrictive based exchange policies in commercial collections and Mainly formal Mix of formal and informal license Broad patents on plant Vertical integration of high genetic resources breeding operations in value transnational companies 43 4. Other social production strategies of knowledge commons Reference (for the 2 following slides) : Benkler, 2006. The Wealth of Networks. Yale University Press. 44 Non-exclusive market strategies • Sharing in house : sharing research results and know-how in a firm < incentive : improvement of the quality of the delivered goods • Sharing with similar organisations : firms where engineers and scientists from different firms attend professional societies, joined information gathering by newspapers. < incentive : making money from early access to information (lead time) • Sharing publicly : bands giving music for free as advertisement for touring (living from performances), open source software developers living from customizing it to particular clients < incentive : attracting clients 45 Non-exclusive non-market strategies • Sharing in house : sharing research results and know-how in a laboratory < incentive : improvement of the quality of the delivered scientific outputs, to attract more government funding for the laboratory • Sharing with similar organisations : early release of a paper to colleagues for comments. < incentive : improving the knowledge • Sharing publicly : give away information for free, give away innovations with high social value < incentive : reputation, status, intrinsic motivations 46 Part 2. Regulation of the global commons (formal and informal rules) 47 1. The historical impetus of open source software licenses 48 Selected IBM revenues 2000-2003 Source : Benkler, 2006. The Wealth of Networks. Yale University Press. 49 2. The need of legal hybrids for governing the genetic resource commons 50 Open Source licenses in software are based on copyright. The proposed open source models in biotechnology are based on patents (Cambia, Humanitarian use licenses); However : innovation in the genetic resource commons is too specific to be protected under copyrights (specific technological purpose) but too incremental to be protected under patents (based on cumulative incremental innovation, no major research leap forward). Therefore need of “legal hybrids” : building innovative license strategies combining both common use principles (so less then patents) and economic incentives for contributing to the shared pools (more than copyrights). 51 Existing contractual tools for building the microbial science commons VIRAL/STANDARD LICENSE IN THE POOL : a genetic resource can be shared amongst all the members of the pool under similar quality management procedures and under the same open access license conditions EX-POST COMPENSATORY LIABILITY OUTSIDE THE POOL : if a recipient wants to use the resource in a commercial application, he has to pay a fixed compensation to the system (compensation which can go totally or in part to the original depositor of the resource or to a global trust fund for example) •Major advantage : no commercial/non-commercial use distinction and incentive to contribute to the pool •Major constraint : need of a tracking of the use of the resource (which might be done through the viral license or a digital database) 3. Empirical evidence on the use and impact of common use licensing 53 Empirical data on the Science Commons in Biomedical research Reference (for the 6 following slides) : Wesley M. Cohen and John P. Walsh. Access – or not – in academic biomedical research. In R. C. Dreyfuss, H. First, D. L. Zimmerman. Working within the Boundaries of Intellectual Property. 2010. 54 Use of patents to deny access to published findings 20% of human genes have at least one patent associated with them, and many have multiple patents. Only 1% of academic researchers report having to delay a project, and non abandoned a project due to others’ patents Only 5% of the academic scientists surveyed regularly check for relevant patents. Suggests unlicensed used of patented technologies. However, as reputation is important for industry, aggressive enforcement of patent rights may undermine the goodwill that is essential to others’ future cooperation. 55 Use of secrecy to withold unpublished findings 7% of academic biomedical researchers acknowledged that, in order to protect the commercial value of an invention or discovery, they delayed publication of their research results for more than one month at least once in the last two years 4 % reported that they, at least once, decided not to publish a result in order to protect the commercial value of their findings. 56 Restricting access through control over materials As reported by those making requests, 19% of recent requests were not fulfilled 8% projects delayed due to inability to get timely access to research materials 28% of all geneticists reported they had difficulty replicating published results and 24% had their own publication significantly delayed 1/9 had to abandon a project each year due to an unfulfilled request for materials or information 57 Reasons for restricted access Industry funding is consistently associated with delayed publication. Greater scientific competition (number of labs competing for publication priority) associated with lower probability for providing access. Idem : for a prior history of commercial activity Being asked to sign an MTA : associated with a greater likelihood of receiving the material or information. 58 Summary of the findings Strength of the sharing practice: average academic researcher in the biomedical field is making 3 or 4 requests per year, about 80% of which are fulfilled. < impressive : knowing that compliance involves costs (for example for copying materials) and the risk of losing competitive advantage < academics might benefit from such sharing, or community norms regarding disclosure or data sharing might play a role (however not considered yet in broad empirical studies) However, studies in physics, mathematics and experimental biology show that secrecy has increased from the 1960s to the 1990s, along with concern over scientific competition. 59 Some implications Possible role of government, science funding bodies and journals’ policies < however often with limited enforcement < can have some impact, but this impact will depend on the balance between incentive effects from appropriability on the one hand and from knowledge exchange on the other Institutionally mediated exchanges might also favour the sharing practice of materials, data and research results < for example the building of shared repositories of high quality materials 60 Case study of common use licenses in the microbial commons Low impact of contractual formalisation on sharing practices Need of viral license approach Total number of new accessions in 2005 in the 119 public culture collections : approximately 10.000 Academic and hospital research collections Own collecting effort From other public culture collections Total number of strains delivered in 2005 by the 119 public culture collections : approximately 120.000 30% 23% 45% Survey amongst 119 public culture collections 20% None of these categories (for example dying industry collections) 58% To academia research collections To private sector 10% To other public culture collections 5% 9% None of these categories (to hospitals and for teaching mainly) Part 3. Analyzing the commons (epistemological limitations and importance of context) 64 Epistemological limitations 65 Semantic limitations of legal models The strong intellectual property paradigm does not fit to all the intended application contexts of the plant improvement cycle. Strong IP paradigm (post-1992 UPOV protection and weak patentability requirements) Fields of application of the paradigm Transgenics Conformity with the expected effects on innovation Area of best fit Controlled Molecular biology research Mass selection hybridization tools (molecular markers, genomic databases) Systematic Partial paradigm breakdown breakdown • Patent tickets • Major steps • Market development • Far from innovation frontier • for in situ agrobiodi• Upstream research versity Pragmatist limitations of the legal models No best choice between the 2 legal paradigms based on scientific/empiric criteria alone Strong IP paradigm (post-1992 UPOV protection and weak patentability requirements) Fields of application of the paradigm Conformity with the expected effects on innovation Transgenics Area of best fit Partially open innovation systems (breeders’ excemption and strong patentability requirements, sui generis regime for landraces) Controlled Molecular biology research Mass selection hybridization tools (molecular markers, genomic databases) Partial paradigm breakdown Area of best fit Semantic and pragmatist limitations of the governance models No best choice between the various governance paradigms based on scientific/empiric criteria alone Existing commons based MODELS Pool (Allarkhaia) MTA Clearing House (Sabel) Reconstruct Open Access ed Commons (Benkler) (Benkler/Ostr om) Based on private ownership yes yes yes No (example preCBD situation) Set up agreement yes no no No Administering entity no Yes yes No Effect Exchange within pool Transparenc y Sharing (in the commons), Liability (outside the commons) Common heritage Evaluation / contextual limitations Full use restricted to members only Competiton for more open license conditions, but no viral licence Reconstructs a global public domain Only applies outside national sovereignity Post-normal science 72 Example of frame conflicts in global genetic resource governance Breeders’ rights (private sector) The Yecoro wheat (right) cultivar, sensitive to salinity, source : US agricultural research Service Farmers’ rights (local communities) Quinoa producing communities of the Southern Bolivian Altiplano, source Damiana Astudillo-Eterno Participatory research in the global genetic resource commons : from Breeding high yielding varieties to sustaining livelihoods Example of Bioversity International : * International non-profit research organization * Role of broker between user communities and international organizations * Building research capacity on needs of user communities (set of questions on livelihoods not addressed systematically in peer reviewed literature) Improvement of traditional races (source: Label rouge) Global seed exchange network (source : Byerlee et al., 2010) Microbial Biocontrol (Source : M. Höfte) 4. Concluding comments Genetic resource commons : in between the digital resource commons (Benkler) and the common pools of natural resources (Ostrom) However the governance principles and legal models of the genetic resource commons also potentially of relevance for other local and global commons : • Cultural commons • Scientific research infrastructures • Digital repositories of publications and pre-publication data 75 Some future activities 1st Global Thematic IASC conference on the knowledge commons • “Governing Pooled Knowledge Resources in a World of Rapid Social and Technological Change. Building Institutions for Sustainable Scientific, Cultural and Genetic Resource Commons” • 12-14th September 2012, Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium • Thank you for you attention … Some References • • • • • • • Designing the Microbial Research Commons, Jerome Reichman, Tom Dedeurwaerdere, Paul Uhlir, manuscript on file with the authors Tom Dedeurwaerdere, Maria Iglesias, Sabine Weiland, Michael Halewood, Use and Exchange of Microbial Genetic Resources Relevant for Food and Agriculture, Report (under review at the Commission on Genetic Ressources) Per Stromberg, Tom Dedeurwaerdere, Unai Pascual, The Contribution of Public Networks to Knowledge Accumulation (under review at Research Policy) www.microbialcommons.org ; june 2008 conference proceedings (special issue forthcoming in the International Journal of the commons, January 2010) Robert Cook-Deegan et Tom Dedeurwaerdere, “The Science Commons in Life Science Research: Structure, Function and Value of Access to Genetic Diversity”, dans International Social Science Journal, vol.188, 2006, pp.299-318. Peter Dawyndt, Tom Dedeurwaerdere et J. Swings, “Explorating and exploiting microbiological commons: contributions of bioinformatics and intellectual property rights in sharing biological information. Introduction to the special issue on the microbiological commons”, dans International Social Science Journal, vol.188, 2006, pp.249-258. Tom Dedeurwaerdere, “The institutional Economics of sharing Biological Information”, dans International Social Science Journal, vol.188, automne 2006, pp.351-368. Acknowledgements • Participants to the expert workshops of 18-19 Feb 2009 et 25-26 March 2009 • Researchers of IAUP V/23, IAUP VI-06, REFGOV : Per Stromberg, Maria-Jose Iglesias, Sabine Weiland • Co-authors of the FAO report : Maria-Jose Iglesias, Michael Halewood and Sabine Weiland • Co-authors on the microbial commons project : Jerry Reichman, Paul Uhlir • Credit for the slides (for the illustrations) :Ahmed Amri, Nina Chanishvili, Nelson Lima, Annick Wilmotte Credits for the illustrations (under creative commons license CC BYNC-ND 2.0 unless otherwise specified) • • • • http://www.flickr.com/photos/platform3/3823892608/sizes/o/in/photostream/ http://www.flickr.com/photos/sheyne/282358087/sizes/m/in/photostream/ http://www.flickr.com/photos/schubi74/4000339895/ http://www.flickr.com/photos/doubleray/3225036640/sizes/o/in/photostream/ (S15) Licence This power point presentation is licensed under a creative commons attribution only, non-commercial use, license (derivative works allowed), license CC BY-NC 2.0 81