Macroeconomics Chamberlin and Yueh Chapter 4 Lecture slides Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Government Spending, Taxation and Debt • • • • Deficits and debt Fiscal policy and national income Keynesian cross model The Ricardian Model: Fiscal Policy with Forward-Looking Consumers Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Learning objectives • Understand the nature of government spending and taxation • Differentiate between government deficits and national debt • Appreciate the implications of fiscal policy • Using the Keynesian cross model • Work through the theory of Ricardian Equivalence Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Government • The macroeconomic perspective is focused on the role the government may play in regulating the economy through their central position in the circular flow of income. • Government spending is an injection into the circular flow of income. • Government policies relating to taxes and spending are known as fiscal policy. • The government through its policies may have scope to influence aggregate demand and the level of income. This scope, though, is open to debate. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Fiscal Policy • Viewed from two perspectives: • The first is the Keynesian view, which makes the case that governments can play a major role in determining the level of national income. • The alternative is the Ricardian view, which argues the level of aggregate demand is essentially neutral to government policy. • The effectiveness of fiscal policy will therefore depend very much on which view of the world persists. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Deficits and Debts • Government spending is an injection, and taxes are a leakage, into the circular flow of income. • The stance of fiscal policy, whether it is expansionary or contractionary, will depend on the difference between the two. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Budget balance • The current government budget balance is the difference between its spending and its receipts. Bt Gt Tt where Bt is the balance at time t; Gt and Tt are the respective levels of government spending and tax revenue, also at time t. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning UK budget surplus/deficit Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Cyclical pattern of budget position • The cyclical path of the budget deficit is accounted for by: • When the economy is in a recession, tax revenues fall and government spending on transfer payments, such as unemployment insurance, tend to rise. This moves the government balance towards deficit. • When the economy is growing strongly, unemployment tends to fall, boosting tax revenues, and reducing the need for government spending on income-related benefits. For this reason, the budget deficit can behave as an automatic stabiliser for the economy. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Structural budget balance • Due to the cyclical nature of the current balance, it is hard to judge the true stance of fiscal policy, that is, whether it is generally expansive or contractionary. • For this purpose, the structural or cyclically adjusted balance, which is also plotted, may be useful. This takes the cyclical movement of the economy into consideration by simply reflecting what the government’s balance would be if the economy were on its trend growth path. In this way, it gives a much clearer indication of the fiscal stance taken by a government. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning National debt/surplus • The government or national debt/surplus is the accumulated total of all its deficits and surpluses. However, this is not all. • If the country is running a net debt, it is funded by borrowing on which interest must be paid. Likewise, if the country is running surpluses, it is effectively a net lender and will receive an interest payments. • Therefore, over time, the dynamics of the national debt are not just accumulated deficits and surpluses from the government’s budget, but also include the associated interest payments involved in servicing the debt/surplus. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning National debt/surplus • The current level of debt is equal to last period’s debt level plus all the interest which is accrued and the current budget balance. Dt 1 r Dt 1 Bt • Therefore, the national debt will evolve as follows: Dt 1 r Dt 1 Gt Tt Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning UK national debt Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Keynesian vs. Ricardian Views • The difference between the Keynesian and the Ricardian views comes down to the type of consumption function. • In the Keynesian model, unsurprisingly the Keynesian consumption function is prominent. People decide how much to consume on the basis of their current disposable income, which is influenced by fiscal policy. • In the Ricardian view, the Permanent Income Hypothesis is central. Consumers are forward-looking and base their decisions on a longer run view of income. Households will only change consumption plans if they believe their permanent income has changed. If it accepted that the government must ultimately balance its books, all deficits must be offset by surpluses. In this case, permanent income, consumption, aggregate demand and the level of national income will all be neutral with respect to fiscal policy. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Keynesian Cross Model • From the circular flow of income, the economy is clearly in equilibrium when income or output is equal to planned expenditures. • In a closed economy (no exports or imports), planned expenditures are just the sum of consumption, investment and government spending. E C I G Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Keynesian Cross Model • Consumption is determined by a simple linear function of disposable income. Disposable income is actual income with the deduction of net taxes, which we assume are administered in a lump sum fashion: • In the Keynesian model, investment, government spending and taxes are considered to be exogenous: C a cY T II G G T T Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Planned expenditure • Aggregate planned expenditure can be found by substituting for these components: E a cY T I G • The slope of this expenditure function is given by the marginal propensity to consume (mpc) or c. This is because consumption only depends on income, so changes in income will affect planned expenditures to the extent that consumption changes. This is in turn determined by the mpc, which usually takes a value between 0 and 1. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Planned expenditure • The intercept of the planned expenditure function is: a I G cT • This represents all planned expenditures which are undertaken independently of income. These include autonomous consumption, investment and government spending. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Planned expenditure function Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Keynesian Cross Model • National income/output equilibrium will be where actual income or output is equal to planned expenditures: Y E • This is a 45 degree line so it has a slope equal to unity; every point on it represents a position where actual income or output is equal to planned expenditures. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Keynesian Cross Model • The equilibrium level of income is determined by where the equilibrium and planned expenditure functions cross: Y a c Y T I G • Rearranging, 1 Y a I G cT 1 c Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Equilibrium in the Keynesian Cross Model • At income levels below Y*, planned expenditures exceed income or output. In this case, firms will find that their stocks are being run down as demand exceeds supply. Firms will increase output, and in doing so, hire more labour so income will also rise. • At income levels above Y*, planned expenditures at clearly below actual output, in which case firms will begin to build up stocks of unsold goods and inventories. As supply exceeds demand, firms will be encouraged to cut output. Less labour will be hired so income will also fall. It is only at the level of income where there is no pressure on output to change. This is where demand is equal to supply. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Government Spending in the Keynesian Cross Model • Suppose there was an increase in government spending. • Planned expenditures will now be higher at every level of income, so the planned expenditure function will shift upwards. This is seen as a movement from E1 to E2. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Increase in government spending in the Keynesian Cross Model Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Government Spending in the Keynesian Cross Model • What will happen to equilibrium output? – Expenditure initially rises by the change in government spending; this is shown as the vertical distance between E1 and E2. – From the circular flow, income will also rise by this amount. – However, this initial increase in income will lead to an increase in disposable income and therefore consumption, so aggregate expenditure will rise even further. – As expenditure rises, income will also increase further. – This process then repeats itself, higher expenditure generating higher income, higher disposable income, higher consumption and so on. – However, because the marginal propensity to consume is less than one, the increase in expenditure each time gets smaller and smaller, so income will eventually converge to a new value rather than keep rising in an unbounded way. – This process is shown by the path of arrows. The total change in equilibrium income is shown as a movement from Y1* to Y2*. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Government spending multiplier • This total change in income is a multiple of the initial change in government spending. It is the change in government spending, plus all the subsequent changes in consumption brought about by increasing income. Therefore, the total change in income can be written as: Y G cG c G c G ............... 2 3 Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Government spending multiplier • or Y kG • where the multiplier is k 1 c c c ....... 2 3 • As 0<c<1, the value of the multiplier can be found by using the sum to infinity: 1 k 1 c Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Government spending multiplier • Therefore, the total change in income resulting from a change in government spending is: 1 Y G 1 c • It should be intuitively clear that the size of the multiplier increases as the marginal propensity to consume increases. If the mpc is higher, then every increase in income brought about by the initial increase in expenditure will proceed to generate larger further increases in expenditure. As a result, the overall effect on national income will be higher. • So, in conclusion, an increase in government spending will produce a multiplied increase in equilibrium output. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Taxes in the Keynesian Cross Model • Where taxes are levied in a lump sum fashion, an increase in the level of this tax will lead to a downward shift in the expenditure function. The tax rise will lower disposable income resulting in autonomous consumption and thus planned expenditure being lower by an amount equal to cT . This is shown as a movement from E1 to E2. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Increase in tax in the Keynesian Cross Model Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Tax multiplier • The fall in expenditure will have a multiplied effect on the level of national income. Falling consumption leads to lower income, which in turn leads to lower consumption and so on. The overall effect of the tax rise on national income would be: c Y T 1 c • This consists of the initial fall in expenditure and the multiplier. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Tax multiplier • A rise in the marginal propensity to consume will have two effects here. • First, the initial fall in consumption following the tax cut will be larger, as consumption is more responsive to changes in disposable income. • Second, the multiplier will be larger. • In both cases, the negative consequences for equilibrium income will be more severe following a tax rise. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Balanced Budget Multiplier • It is argued that if the government raises government spending and taxes by the same amount, then the effect on income will be zero. • The government is adding to the circular flow of income with one hand, whilst taking an equal amount away from it at the same time with the other. • This, though, is not always true. Tax financed government spending can still have a significant effect on the level of national income. • This is a powerful result; the government can use policy to expand the economy without incurring any additional debt. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Balanced Budget Multiplier • A tax financed increase in government spending implies that: G T • The rise in spending as we have seen will lead to an upward shift in the expenditure function and the rise in taxes a corresponding downward shift. What will be the overall consequence for the equilibrium level of national income? Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Balanced Budget Multiplier • The increase in government spending shifts the expenditure function upwards, whereas the increase in taxes moves it downward. • The equilibrium level of national income would rise as a result, simply because the upward shift in the expenditure function is greater than the downward shift. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Balanced Budget Multiplier • The logic here is fairly simple. • Even though G T , the change in expenditure from an increase in government spending exceeds the fall in expenditure from the rise in taxes. The net change in expenditure is E 1 cG, and this will be positive so as long as the mpc is less than one . Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Balanced Budget Multiplier Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Balanced Budget Multiplier • The only situation where this does not hold true is where the marginal propensity to consume is equal to 1. In this case, there is no saving, so any increase in tax financed government spending will lead to an equal fall in consumption and no change in overall expenditures. • The effect on equilibrium income/output is clearly positive. The economy moves from Y1 to Y3 via Y2. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Balanced Budget Multiplier • The combined effect of the increases in government spending and taxes is: 1 c Y G T 1 c 1 c • Knowing that G T leaves us with: Y G which is the balanced budget multiplier. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Ricardian Model: Fiscal Policy with Forward-Looking Consumers • In the simple Keynesian model, changes in government spending or taxes will only affect consumers to the extent that their disposable income changes. • On the other hand, forward-looking and rational utility maximising consumers must take a much more complicated decision. This is because a government’s current tax and spending policies may influence its future tax and spending policies, and therefore have repercussions for a household’s future disposable income. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Optimal Consumers • A rational consumer will choose consumption to maximise total lifetime utility subject to the constraint: C2 Y2 C1 Y1 1 r 1 r • This constraint simply implies that the present discounted value of consumption cannot exceed the present discounted value of income. • The solution to the maximisation problem is where the indifference curve formed by the consumer’s preferences is tangential to the budget constraint. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Optimal Consumers Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Optimal Consumers • The optimal pattern of consumption is given by: C ,C 1 2 • This will only change if there are changes in the factors that shift or pivot the budget constraint. • Is this something that can be achieved by fiscal policy? Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Government Debt • The government can effectively borrow large sums for a long period of time, but is it subject to any constraints? • Although the government does not have to balance its budget in every period, it is assumed that the government must ultimately balance its books. • That is, at the end of time, the government’s national debt must be zero. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Government Debt • In the two period model, that we have been using, the end of time is effectively at the end of the second period. Therefore, the evolution of the government’s debt must be as follows: 0 1 r G1 T1 G2 T2 • Rewriting, G2 T2 0 G1 T1 1 r • The government’s constraint is that the present discounted value of the sum of deficits and surpluses must sum to zero. This constraint simply means that any deficit or surplus would have to be eventually reversed in present value terms. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Ricardian Equivalence • The forward-looking rational consumer will know this. Therefore, when faced with a change in taxes or government spending, their anticipation would be that the policy will eventually be reversed in present value terms. In that case, they shouldn’t view their lifetime resources as being any different, and therefore there is no need to change consumption. • Under these conditions, fiscal policy will have no effect on the economy – a proposition known as Ricardian Equivalence. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Does the timing of taxes matter for consumption? • The government delivers an immediate tax cut. How should the household respond? • According to the predictions of the Permanent Income Hypothesis, consumption will only change if lifetime resources change. • Consumption will be constrained by the following budget constraint: C2 Y2 T2 C1 Y1 T1 1 r 1 r Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Does the timing of taxes matter for consumption? • In this case, the present discounted value of all consumption cannot exceed the present discounted value of all disposable income. • Ignoring government spending and starting from a position of no debt, the tax cut will then create a deficit of T1 . • Effectively, this is the amount that the government is giving to each household. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Does the timing of taxes matter for consumption? • However, the government must have no deficit at the end of period 2, implying: 0 1 r T1 T2 • The government constraint then states that in present value terms the current tax reduction must be offset in present value terms with a future tax increase. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Does the timing of taxes matter for consumption? T2 1 r T1 • Substituting this result into the budget constraint gives: C2 Y2 1 r T1 C1 Y1 T1 1 r 1 r C2 Y2 C1 Y1 1 r 1 r Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Does the timing of taxes matter for consumption? • The tax policy does not change the intertemporal budget constraint. • As long as the government runs a balanced budget, the timing of taxes is irrelevant and will have no impact on the intertemporal budget constraint, and therefore consumption. • When the government cuts taxes in period 1, a household would experience a rise in their disposable income. Under the auspices of the Keynesian model, consumption would rise. However, the predications of the PIH are all together different. Knowing that future taxes will be higher, households will smooth their consumption by saving the tax cut this period to pay for the higher taxes next period. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Neutrality of Government Spending • Will an increase in government spending have any effect on output? The answer is again no. • The best way to view this is to assume that government spending is just consumption that the government undertakes on behalf of households. • The government is essentially purchasing goods and services and distributing them to households for consumption. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Neutrality of Government Spending • Suppose the government were to increase government spending in period 1 and to finance it by borrowing. In this case, the budget constraint would appear as follows: C1 G1 C2 Y T2 Y1 2 1 r 1 r • As before, the government budget constraint implies that future taxes will have to rise by: T2 1 r G1 Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Neutrality of Government Spending • Substituting in this expression for the change in future taxes, we will once again see that nothing has happened to the intertemporal budget constraint faced by households: C2 Y2 C1 G1 Y1 G1 1 r 1 r • In this case, C1 G1 C1 • So, G1 C1 Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning The Neutrality of Government Spending • An increase in government spending raises household consumption in the first period, but the households know that they will face a higher tax bill in the second period. • As a result, the increase in consumption in the first period will be offset by extra saving. All that has happened is that government consumption has replaced private consumption. Instead of households choosing their own consumption, the government is doing it for them. • As government spending crowds out household spending on a one-to-one basis, there will be no change to aggregate demand. Fiscal policy is once again neutral. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Theoretical Debates on Ricardian Equivalence • In stating the neutrality of fiscal policy, the theory of Ricardian Equivalence argues that the government has little role to play in the macroeconomy. • This summation, though, is only valid if we can be sure that Ricardian Equivalence holds in its entirety. This has led to further debate, and many reasons have subsequently been forwarded arguing the case for a more non-Ricardian view on fiscal policy. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Discounting • Future tax increases will only matter if consumers are sufficiently forward-looking. If households do not place much weight on future utility, they will not worry so much about future tax rises. • One of the most logical reasons why a household might discount the future is because human mortality means there is a positive probability of death. However, a famous counterargument is put forward by Robert Barro. The reason is that we care about the utility of our children and we would save more so that we could increase bequests to our offspring. • This is a controversial debate. Although there is ample evidence that bequests are left, for this to maintain the predictions of Ricardian Equivalence would require each household to be treated as a dynasty. There will also be a large number of possible exceptions to this rule, such as households that have no children. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Borrowing constraints • If households were permanent income consumers, consumption would tend to be tied to current disposable income. The household would ideally like to increase current consumption, but cannot borrow against future income. Therefore, consumption can only change when current income changes. • The government by cutting taxes can increase current disposable income, which would lead to a rise in consumption. Alternatively, the government could purchase goods and services for households, enabling an increase of consumption towards its desired level. • In both cases, fiscal policy will have not neutral but positive consequences for aggregate demand. Effectively, the credit constraints are being circumvented through fiscal policy as the government is just borrowing on behalf on households. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Interest rate effects • Most households are likely to be net borrowers. Changes in the interest rate will thus have income effects that work in the same direction. • Government may be able to borrow at a lower rate of interest than individual households because it can always raise taxes to fund its borrowing, lowering the chances of a default. • Therefore, by funding a cut in taxes or an increase in government spending by borrowing, this reduces the amount that credit constrained consumers need to borrow; the government is really just borrowing on their behalf. However, because the rate of interest the government pays is lower, households are effectively swapping high interest for low interest borrowing. This will be expected to generate a positive income effect, increasing current consumption and aggregate demand. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Global Applications 4.1 • Interest Rate Subsidies • Changes in taxes can have non-Ricardian effects when the government can borrow at a lower interest rate than individual households. • Why is this the case? Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Distortionary taxes • Non-lump sum taxes may create distortions which lead to the failure of Ricardian Equivalence. • Lower taxes might encourage more work, meaning that income rises. Higher taxes may have the opposite effect. • As the budget constraint will shift with changes in income, we can no longer expect consumption to remain unchanged in the face of fiscal policy changes. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning Summary • In this chapter, we have explored the nature of government spending and taxation. • We analysed the differences between government deficits and national debt • Then, we worked through the implications of fiscal policy • Using the Keynesian cross model, we analysed planned and actual expenditure functions. • Finally, we analysed the theory of Ricardian Equivalence with forward-looking consumers. Use with Macroeconomics by Graeme Chamberlin and Linda Yueh ISBN 1-84480-042-1 © 2006 Cengage Learning